Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-12T18:39:05.568Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Politics Matter: The 1997 Derailment of Fast-Track Trade Authority

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

Karen E. Schnietz*
Affiliation:
Rice University
Timothy Nieman
Affiliation:
Lumina Decision Systems
*
Jones Graduate School of Management, MS 531, Rice University, 6100 South Main Street, Houston, TX 77005–1892, USA. Tel: (713) 285–5388; Fax: (713) 285–5251; E-mail: schnietz@rice.edu

Abstract

In 1997, President Clinton became the first President not awarded fast-track trade negotiating authority since this congressional delegation of trade policymaking authority first began in 1934. Fast-track's failure also represents a case of an unsuccessful business political strategy since business supporters of the measure were easily defeated by labor and environmental opponents, despite the many political ‘privileges’ that business possessed. This case study describes why fast-track is important to the future of US and global trade policy and examines the main reasons for its failure. In doing so, it illustrates theories of pivotal politics, the median voter, collective action, issue framing, international trade's welfare costs and benefits, and international relations that often arise in research and courses on the non-market environment of business, international trade, and international political economy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © V.K. Aggarwal 1999 and published under exclusive license to Cambridge University Press 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bailey, Michael, Weingast, Barry and Goldstein, Judy. 1998. Institutional Roots of American Trade Policy: Politics, Coalitions and International Trade. World Politics 49: 309338.Google Scholar
Baron, David. 1993. Business and Its Environment. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Baron, David. 1995. Integrated Strategy: Market and Nonmarket Components. California Management Review 37: 4765.Google Scholar
Baron, David. 1999. Integrated Market and Nonmarket Strategies in Client and Interest Group Politics. Business and Politics 1: 734.Google Scholar
Clawson, Dan, Neustadtl, Alan and Scott, Denise. 1992. Money Talks: Corporate PACs and Political Influence. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Davidson, Roger and Oleszek, Walter. 1996. Congress and Its Members. 5th edition. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Destler, I. M. 1992. American Trade Politics. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Gilligan, Michael. 1997. Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective Action in American Trade Policy. Michigan: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan. 1988. The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934. International Organization 42: 91119.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert. 1970. Exit, Voice and Loyalty. Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Huntington, Samuel. 1987. American Politics and the Promise of Disharmony. Massachusetts: Belknap.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1999. Pivotal Politics: A Refinement of Nonmarket Analysis for Voting Institutions. Business and Politics 1: 6381.Google Scholar
Lindbloom, Charles. 1977. Politics and Markets. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Lowi, Theodore. 1964. American Business, Public Policy, Case-Studies, and Political Theory. World Politics 16: 677693.Google Scholar
Magee, Stephen. 1978. Three Simple Tests of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem. In Issues in International Economics, edited by Oppenheimer, Peter. United Kingdom: Oriel Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. Connecticut: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
O'Halloran, Sharyn. 1994. Politics, Process and American Trade Policy. Michigan: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Olsen, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Reich, Robert and Donahue, John. 1985. New Deals: The Chrysler Revival. New York: Times Books.Google Scholar
Ruggie, John. 1982. International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Post-war Economic Order. International Organization 36: 379415.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E. 1963. Politics, Pressures, and the Tariff. Connecticut: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Schnietz, Karen. 1999. The Institutional Foundations of US Trade Policy: Revisiting Explanations for the 1934 Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act. Jones Graduate School of Management (Rice University) Working Paper Series No. 1999.6.2.Google Scholar
Schuler, Douglas. 1996. The NAFTA and the Environment: Trade, Diplomacy and Limited Protection. International Trade Journal 10: 353377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stolper, Wolfgang and Samuelson, Paul. 1941. Protection and Real Wages. Review of Economic Studies 9: 5873.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1987. Unemployment, Collective Bargaining, and the Demand for Protection. American Journal of Political Science 31: 729752.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth. 1979. Theory of International Politics. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Weaver, R. Kent. 1986. The Politics of Blame-Avoidance. Journal of Public Policy 6: 371398.Google Scholar
Wilson, James. 1980. The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Yarbrough, Beth and Yarbrough, David. 1997. The World Economy: Trade and Finance. New York: Dryden Press.Google Scholar
Yoffie, David and Bergenstein, Sigrid. 1985. Creating Political Advantage: The Rise of the Corporate Political Entrepreneur. California Management Review 28: 122139.Google Scholar