Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T00:59:08.833Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Recent Trends in the Business History of Russia: The Blurry Borders of the Discipline

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 July 2022

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The article analyzes recent trends in the business history of Russia and its interrelations with mainstream business history. The authors explore the extent to which the business history of Russia can contribute to the development of the discipline. To do so, they use an “alternative business history” framework. They argue that Russian business history is a disciplinary hybrid. As such, it can reasonably be considered as an interesting testing ground for business history, which seems to be searching for a new identity among history, economics, and organizational and managerial studies. In addition, Russian business history still has considerable potential for providing new voices and stories and for contributing to international debates and a more nuanced understanding of the relationship between enterprise, state, and society.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © 2022 The President and Fellows of Harvard College

Russia has long occupied a rather marginal place in business history scholarship: its turbulent twentieth-century history, including some sixty years of an administrative command economy and the chaotic transformation of the 1990s, has led scholars to deal with it as a case with few parallels. In the second half of the 1990s, a few scholars suggested incorporating it into a broader comparative framework. In 1995, Thomas Owen offered a comprehensive analysis of Russian corporate capitalism, focusing on the business history audience and including the first post-Soviet years.Footnote 1 Shortly afterward, Alfred Chandler, Franco Amatori, and Takashi Hikino included a chapter on Russia and the Soviet Union in the volume Big Business and the Wealth of Nations, highlighting the contribution that evidence from Russia could make to the study of the evolution of big business.Footnote 2 Nevertheless, many other recent research surveys in the discipline have excluded Russia, and Russian scholars are still poorly integrated into the international business history community. It does not help matters that, except for some brief up-to-date introductory works, there are no comprehensive reviews of works on the business history of Russia, either in English or in Russian. This article provides an overview of recent trends in the field.Footnote 3 It seeks to show how the current debate in Russian business history not only follows the major trends in international business history but also contributes to the current discussions on its methodology.Footnote 4

In this article, we suggest that Russian business history is a disciplinary hybrid rather than a “field in its infancy,” as Martin Kragh defined it.Footnote 5 As such, it may usefully be analyzed as a testing ground for business history, which seems to be searching for a new identity among history, economics, and organizational and managerial studies.Footnote 6 The peculiarities of Russian capitalist development and the institutionalization of social science in contemporary Russia have forced scholars to adopt an interdisciplinary approach and a certain heterodoxy of methods when researching the history of Russian business. This has led to a huge variety of questions and a certain disciplinary fragmentation.

This article is in three parts. The first briefly describes the institutional development of the business history of Russia as an academic discipline; we underline the insularity and fragmentation that led to difficulties in its influencing international debates. In the second part, we present the trending topics based on analysis of the historiography of Russian/Soviet enterprise and entrepreneurship for the last twenty years. In the third part, we look at the business history of Russia through the lens of so-called alternative business history for emerging markets.Footnote 7

Institutional Development of the Business History of Russia

The business history of Russia has been developing within several academic disciplines but never as a discipline with clear borders.Footnote 8 No specialized department or research center focusing on this area has existed either in Russia or abroad.Footnote 9 Nevertheless, enterprise and entrepreneurship are a rather popular research area among historians of Russia, who mainly work under the umbrella of economic history organizations, such as the Center for Economic History at Moscow State University, the Russian Association of Economic History Research (Russian Academy of Science), and a few other regional centers of economic history in Saint Petersburg, Chelyabinsk, Saransk, and Barnaul.

Also, groups of scholars or individual researchers have explored the business history of Russia within departments of Russian history and Russian studies. For example, Boris Anan'ich organized a research group at Saint Petersburg State University studying Russian business (mostly financial) history. Several business historians work at research centers outside of Russia, including the Davis Center for Russian and Eurasian Studies at Harvard University, the Institute for Russian and Eurasian Studies at Uppsala University, the Leibniz Institute for East and Southeast European Studies in Regensburg, the Pan-European Institute at the University of Turku, and the Aleksanteri Institute of the University of Helsinki.

There are no Russian national professional associations and no regular academic forums on the business history of Russia. In the last few years, some international research centers for Russian and eastern European studies have organized conferences on topics related to the business history of Russia, but these initiatives were sporadic, hardly comprising a regular discussion forum.Footnote 10

Nor are there specialized journals on the business history of Russia. Nevertheless, in the last two decades, three economic history journals have regularly published articles on the history of enterprise and entrepreneurship in Russia. Ekonomicheskaia istoriia: Ezhegodnik (Economic History Yearbook), published since 1999 by the Center for Economic History at Lomonosov Moscow State University and the Institute of History of the Russian Academy of Science, is the most business history friendly: roughly 40 percent of the articles it has published are about the history of enterprise, entrepreneurship, and other topics that may well be considered business history. This percentage decreases to roughly 15 percent if we consider the other two Russian economic history journals: Rossiiskii ekonomicheskii zhurnal (Russian journal of economic history), published since 2005 by Ogarev Mordovia State University, and Istoriko-ekonomicheskie issledovaniia (History and economics research), published by Baikal State University in Irkutsk.

Russian business history has another peculiarity: the absence of specialized business archives. The remark by Franco Amatori and Geoffrey Jones that “in many emerging [market] countries there is virtually no tradition of private companies devoting resources to preserving corporate archives and even less of a tradition of allowing access to them by outsiders” is partly true of contemporary Russia.Footnote 11 Nevertheless, state and municipal archives in Russia do hold specialized collections on the histories of enterprises and entrepreneurs. Moreover, several special archival collections outside of Russia hold documents related to the history of foreign enterprises on Russian territory, for example, the Swedish Business History in Russia collection at the Center for Business History, Stockholm, and the Hughesovka Research Archive—a collection of documents in the Glamorgan Archives, Cardiff, about Welsh entrepreneur John Hughes and the New Russia Company Ltd., which he established in the second half of the nineteenth century. So, in terms of access to documents, business historians in Russia are in a more favorable situation than their colleagues in other countries.

Another distinguishing feature of Russian business history is its high level of national isolation compared with its counterparts in other European and North American countries. Russian business historians, with some exceptions, rarely attend the annual meetings of the business history associations—like the European Business History Association (EBHA), Business History Conference (BHC), and Association of Business Historians (ABH)—let alone become their members. As a result, the visibility of Russian business history in the international academic arena tends to be poor. Russian authors rarely try to publish in the important international business history journals such as Business History, Business History Review, and Enterprise & Society. Nonetheless, within the last twenty years, these journals have published fifteen articles on different aspects of the business history of Russia.

The fragmentation and weak institutionalization of the Russian business history research community curb the development of the field as an independent discipline and limit its international visibility.Footnote 12 Moreover, due to disciplinary dispersion, scholars tend tohighlight Russian exceptionalism instead of looking for commonalities between the business history of their country and that of others.

Trending Topics in the Business History of Russia

To identify recent trends in the business history of Russia, we have selected three hundred books and articles in English and Russian published from 2001 to 2020. The sample was composed in several stages. First, we systematically browsed all issues of the specialized journals, such as Business History, Business History Review, Enterprise & Society, Journal of Historical Research in Marketing, Journal of Management History, Ekonomicheskaia istoriia: Ezhegodnik, and Rossiiskii ekonomicheskii zhurnal. Then we added some of the most relevant publications collected during our previous studies on the history of Imperial and Soviet Russian business and from previously composed and published lists (for example, specialized publications and syllabi). Finally, we searched Google Scholar using keywords like “entrepreneurship” (predprinimatel'stvo), “enterprise” (predprijatie), “corporation” (korporacija), and “firm” (firma). We also added the relevant publications referring to the most-cited studies. Then we arranged all the publications according to their citation index in Google Scholar (as of February 27, 2021) and selected the 157 of those that have been cited more than five times (Table 1).Footnote 13

Table 1. A Sample of Publications on Russian Business History with Six or More Citations on Google Scholar (as of February 27, 2021)

Distinguishing between business and economic and social history was a challenging task. As Amatori and Jones have correctly noted, the boundaries and scope of business history “remain the subject of intense debate.”Footnote 14 We therefore applied a rather broad definition of business history, as suggested by Christopher Kobrak and Andrea Schneider, who describe it as a “story and explanation of firms’ evolution in their political, social, technological, and economic contexts.”Footnote 15 While acknowledging the arbitrariness and limits of our selection, we nevertheless believe that we have covered the works with the greatest impact. On this basis, it is possible, we believe, to present a satisfactory picture of Russia's business history today.

Table 1 shows that the most popular topics are the history of entrepreneurship, business and state, technology and innovation, and management. The two topics that have the most extraordinary impact in each period—“informal practices and organized crime” between 2001 and 2010 and “business and the state” between 2010 and 2020—reflect a gradual shift of economic power to the state in contemporary Russia. What the table does not show, but what we noticed from a close reading of the list, is the solid social context provided by most publications. Consequently, in what follows, we review the three main threads of the business history literature of Russia—state intervention in the economy, the evolution of the organizational forms of the enterprise and entrepreneurship, and the social effects of business activities—and, in the next section, we highlight how the Russian context might have led to business responses similar to those in emerging markets.Footnote 16

State Intervention in the Economy: From the Late Empire to the Collapse of the USSR

In the 1960s, Aleksander Gerschenkron argued that in more “backward” countries, such as the Russian Empire, the state takes on the role that had been played by private initiative in earlier industrializing nations, creating the conditions for industrial development by means of fiscal and monetary policy and building transport and communications infrastructure.Footnote 17 This thesis, although heavily criticized, still largely drives business and economic history research today, orienting scholars toward the economic policy that creates the conditions for business.Footnote 18 Recent works suggest reconsidering the role of the state as the engine of Russian economic development, proposing instead to explore, in line with the latest trends in international business history, the role of government as a protagonist that sets the rules of the game.”Footnote 19 The last twenty years have shown a surge in research interest in this area.

Irina Potkina, in her work on legislation on entrepreneurship in Russia, concludes that the government “was constantly looking back at Western Europe, comparing their own actions with what was happening in the West.”Footnote 20 She offers a positive image of the tsarist Russian government as a regulator, compared with the earlier picture drawn by Thomas Owen, who characterized it as strongly restrictive and inhibitory.Footnote 21 Potkina states that “despite certain shortcomings,” the government “facilitated and supported the development of entrepreneurship in the Russian Empire in various sectors of the economy.” The main drawback, in her opinion, was discrimination on a national and religious basis that was due to the government's “flexibility and customized approach” to certain groups of entrepreneurs.Footnote 22

Resilience has also been identified as a characteristic feature of the Russian corporation by Amanda Gregg and Steven Nafziger, who collected and analyzed a data set of charters and balance sheets of all corporations active in Russia in 1914. They argue that Russian corporations “possessed considerable flexibility regarding their selection of organizational structures and financial strategies” even within comparatively rigid imperial corporate law.Footnote 23 Gregg and Nafziger demonstrate how companies adjusted to the system and even developed some of their competitive advantages based on the peculiarities of corporate legislation in Russia. These observations have contributed much to our knowledge about entrepreneurial resilience and adaptability in “non-free” or “partly free” societies.

Scholars have rarely questioned the importance of business establishing a good relationship with the Russian tsarist government. Nikolay Arsentyev argues competently that the model of the relationship between entrepreneurship and the Russian government in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries was typical of countries with strong militaries, for which they needed supplies and services. The state was expected to “create the conditions for efficient development of the private entrepreneurship” in exchange for “service to the state” in the strategic economic sectors, that is, sectors related to state security. Arsentyev convincingly describes that model as “capitalism based on the predatory exploitation of human and natural resources.”Footnote 24

The tsarist government often stuck to the laissez-faire approach to nonstrategic economic sectors, those producing consumer goods. Benjamin Sawyer's case study of the Singer Company in Russia during World War I shows that even a large foreign company could be relatively independent of government.Footnote 25 When, however, the level of xenophobia in Russian society rose because of Russia's entry into the war, the lack of strong supporters among the influential politicians had disastrous consequences for this foreign company.

Overall, recent studies provide sound evidence that in the late Russian Empire the state played roles similar to those of its Western counterparts.Footnote 26 It established the rules of the game, performed a regulatory function, made considerable efforts to develop infrastructure, offered financial incentives, and promoted business opportunities for foreign companies. In strategic industries, the government even invited entrepreneurs personally to expand their businesses to Russia, and it provided government procurement guarantees. Whether government intervention did more harm than good for business is still a matter of debate.

The recent publications do not provide convincing evidence against the strong-state thesis, but they recognize the agency of several other actors.Footnote 27 The discourse has also shifted from evaluating the government's contribution to industrialization to discussing the variety of its roles in economic and business development.

After the Bolshevik Revolution of 1917, the state took control of all the major economic assets and gradually set in place an administrative command economy. In Soviet Russia, the state unquestionably played an exceptionally invasive role in the economy and society and had a monopoly in determining economic priorities. The state's effort to transform enterprises into “obedient agents of centralized plans” and to create loyal management was a long and nonlinear process, not wholly successful.

By the end of the 1950s, David Granick and Joseph Berliner had already clearly sketched out the microeconomics and macroeconomics of the Soviet experiment, identifying points of critical importance in the economic and industrial decision-making processes, the organization of managerial incentives, the supply and distribution system, and the informal practices greasing the wheels of the planned economy.Footnote 28 After 1991, newly available documentation refined this grand picture without, however, altering its main lines.Footnote 29

The Soviet enterprise was, for a long time, an efficient instrument of state policy and successfully pursued the goals that the political hierarchy had set for it: industrial modernization and extensive growth. For this reason, business and economic historians have extensively explored the role of the enterprise in the military and strategic sectors of the Soviet economy, as well as the economics of forced labor and the Gulag.Footnote 30

Scholars found it more challenging to define the nature of the Soviet enterprise, partly a firm, partly an organ of state administration. Alfred Chandler considered the Soviet enterprise to be the negation of the capitalist firm because managers had no power to put into practice three-pronged investment (production, management, and distribution), no chance to learn how to coordinate effectively because they depended on “central planning agencies to coordinate production and distribution and to allocate resources for the future.” He claimed that Soviet managers “never developed hands-on organization knowledge about current facilities, available supplies, and market demand.”Footnote 31 Chandler looked at the Soviet enterprise, the production unit, and the base of the hierarchical pyramid of the command economy as something composed of soulless and colorless party officials.Footnote 32 But he overlooked the strategic decision-making processes at the higher levels of the Soviet administrative apparatus, often the result of conflicts among different bodies and power centers (sectoral ministries, aggregations of enterprises, foreign trade and scientific/academic institutes, and the party's parallel hierarchy). The boundaries of the Soviet enterprise were not well defined, especially in relation to political and administrative power, and the functions of the Soviet enterprise were multiple.

To understand the evolution of the Soviet enterprise properly, business historians would need to study the decision-making processes in their complexity and entirety, reconstructing the command chain from the State Planning Committee (Gosplan) to the unit of production and approaching the Soviet enterprise in its “extended boundaries.”Footnote 33 This is in fact the approach adopted by Andrei Yudanov, Andrei Markevitch, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya, whose works demonstrate how political priorities determined the functions of Soviet enterprises but, at the same time, point to the common matrix and the similarities in terms of organizational structure and economies of scale with large Western corporations.Footnote 34

Researchers have recently shifted their interest from the years of the Stalinist dictatorship and the study of the immutable nature of the administrative command economy to the thirty years that preceded the collapse of the Soviet Union and the examination of the transformation of the economic system.Footnote 35 The Communist Party was omnipresent in the Soviet Union, but its policies toward enterprises were often incoherent and inconsistent. For many years, scholars analyzed the fluid organizational “makeup” of Soviet business as yet another plague preventing the efficiency of the system, incapable of changing its overall operation.Footnote 36 The latest studies suggest that in-depth research on organizational reforms is crucial to understanding the Soviet decline and how the accumulation of systemic inconsistencies undermined it from the inside and paved the way for the current state of the Russian economy.Footnote 37

Another significant research cluster focuses on the relations between the Soviet state and foreign enterprises. Recent studies have shown that, like contemporary Russian governments, the tsarist governments embraced running enterprises to counterbalance the inflow of foreign direct investments, decreasing their dependence on foreign capital and technology and reasserting the power of the state. Russia's attitude toward state-owned enterprises today seems less different from other European countries than used to be generally assumed.Footnote 38

The researchers focusing on the Socialist period underline how the Soviet enterprise and big capitalist corporations grew together, stressing most Soviet leaders’ fascination with Western organizational models. To the debate on “Soviet Americanism” they added new archival evidence and provided more details on how Soviet leaders relied on Western experts’ assistance while designing the exceptionally large-scale factories and infrastructure projects to counter the backwardness of the Russian economy.Footnote 39 An indication of the widespread adaptation of Western managerial theories to Soviet circumstances also comes from an article by Olga Kravets and Özlem Sandikçi that analyzes the marketing practices used in the 1930s by Soviet cosmetics firms.Footnote 40

Finally, the last twenty years have brought several remarkable studies demonstrating how the planned economy's informal structures, such as blat (connections, favors, informal deals), report falsification, and personal networks, played a substantial role in allowing the enterprise to operate while hampering the consolidation of market institutions.Footnote 41 As Andrew Freris has rightly noted, understanding the “unofficial” freedom enjoyed by Soviet enterprises is crucial for understanding post-Soviet capitalism and is the most promising area in research on Soviet business.Footnote 42

Entrepreneurs and Entrepreneurship

For a long time, business historians emphasized the subservience of Russian entrepreneurship to the state. Recent researchers have, conversely, highlighted the crucial role played by entrepreneurs. Most economic and business historians of Imperial Russia have focused on individual entrepreneurs or family firms; few are concerned with entrepreneurial organizations and their efforts to defend their collective interests.Footnote 43 With some exceptions, these studies are anecdotal biographical narratives that seldom place their topic into a broader context or consider current debates in business history.

Fairly recent biographical research by Thomas Owen about Fedor Chizhov, a Slavophile intellectual and businessman, stands out against the background of anecdotes. Owen has conceptualized the biography so that the story of a single person provides a perspective on broader business and social developments in the late Russian Empire. Based on that, Owen reconstructs the conservative current in Russian economic thought, which he calls “Slavophile capitalism.” This current, he writes, consisted of “a peculiar blend of paternalism toward the masses and encouragement of ethnic Russian economic activity.”Footnote 44

Besides considering core groups of Russian entrepreneurs, scholars have recently published useful observations about disadvantaged groups such as ethnic or religious minorities and women entrepreneurs.Footnote 45 There has also been a lengthy discussion on how to explain the overrepresentation of religious or ethnic minorities in certain economic sectors. Danila Raskov and Vadim Kufenko researched textile enterprises in the Moscow region from 1832 to 1890 that were owned by a religious minority, the Old Believers. Their work presents evidence that the success of the Old Believers can be explained by the presence of strong social networks and trust, “which arose from their minority status.” Informal institutions and community business reputations, however, “lost their competitive advantage” with the emergence of modern banking and the arrival of new formal state institutions after the late 1880s, and this led to the decline of the Old Believers’ entrepreneurship.Footnote 46

Foreign entrepreneurship has in the last couple of decades been among the most popular topics in the economic and business history of Russia.Footnote 47 A few important studies describe the hardships that foreign companies met with when operating in Russia.Footnote 48 Archaic corporate law, difficulties in finding reliable local business partners, the labor movement, and often hostile attitudes of tsarist officials and local society were among the main challenges facing foreign companies and individual entrepreneurs.Footnote 49 Though Russian society tended to welcome foreign technologies, which were expected to help the country catch up with the West, it remained highly suspicious of Western institutions and activities it saw as a threat to the integrity of the empire.

Of course, European and American companies operating in other foreign countries also faced economic nationalism, ethnic prejudice, and xenophobia, not only in the Russian Empire. But in Russia, hostility toward foreign entrepreneurs and enterprises was often part of government policy. Scholars are still debating how to describe the business environment there compared with that in other European countries. On the one hand, many foreign companies operated successfully in Russia. On the other hand, they often had to rely on local partners who could help with formal and informal matters. Several case studies demonstrate that when foreign companies became too self-confident and did not establish strong alliances with local partners and the government, they failed.Footnote 50

During the Soviet period from the 1920s onward, although not continuously, foreign enterprises remained a key source for technologies and organizational practices. In the 1960s, Soviet institutions signed several “agreements of technical and scientific cooperation” with foreign enterprises, often backed by the governments of the latter.Footnote 51 The role of the Soviet Union in globalization, including its economic presence both in developing and in Comecon countries, is, however, still a puzzle with many missing pieces; the most important of them concerns the effect of globalization on the dissolution of the Soviet Union.

For many years, scholarly debate about enterprise and entrepreneurship has focused on the business environment rather than the enterprise itself. Few publications got inside the black box of the firm in order to understand how strategy and structure shaped each other, and the Chandlerian framework did not spread among scholars publishing in Russian-speaking journals.Footnote 52 A notable exception is the work of Mikhail Baryshnikov, who applies stakeholder perspective to the analysis of companies operating in Saint Petersburg and Moscow in the early twentieth century.Footnote 53 Baryshnikov explores conflicting interests of company owners, managers, workers, consumers, suppliers, creditors, state authorities, trade unions, and civic organizations and seeks to explain decision making within the firms.

Another example is the study by Amanda Gregg about the advantages of incorporation in Imperial Russia. Gregg analyzed the incorporation of more than four thousand Imperial Russian firms and provides convincing evidence that incorporated enterprises were “larger, more productive, and more mechanized than unincorporated factories.”Footnote 54

Most business historians currently have continued to concentrate on large industrial enterprises; in this respect, there is a continuity of the tradition established in the twentieth century. The service sector, except for financial enterprises, has been a less popular source of research topics.Footnote 55 Recent publications on the history of banks and the stock exchange in Russia have presented a more nuanced picture of the mechanisms for mobilizing equity capital and demonstrated their importance in funding imperial industrialization. These new findings provide solid evidence that businesses operating in the late Russian Empire could rely on multiple financing sources (foreign direct investments, direct loans, the issue of debt securities, new equities). Consequently, companies could use different financing strategies and practices. These findings also provide further evidence against Gerschenkron's thesis about the state being the only crucial investor in Imperial Russian industrialization.

The entrepreneur—as the individual who, to use a standard definition (from Merriam-Webster), “organizes, manages, and assumes the risks of an enterprise”—was a marginal actor in Soviet history, active in limited sectors (agriculture and retail, the second economy) and only in certain periods. Most scholars agree that entrepreneurship existed in the Soviet system, but identification of the entrepreneurial function in the Soviet system has been debated since the 1950s.Footnote 56 Some studies have shed light on how the shortages of the centrally planned economy nudged or even forced Soviet citizens to become entrepreneurs to make a living.Footnote 57 This perspective insists on the compensating function of entrepreneurship in the Soviet system. It rests on many sociological and ethnographic studies of the illegal transactions and practices and of the informal economic networks in Soviet society.Footnote 58

Economic and business history research on Soviet entrepreneurship has focused on the entrepreneurial function of the Communist Party and the entrepreneurial skills of party leaders who made decisions about strategic investments and promoted the creation of entirely new industrial branches and plants.Footnote 59

Many studies describe how Soviet industrial management performed the entrepreneurial function. For a long time, scholars looked at Soviet administrators as part of a soulless bureaucracy subjugated to the authority of the Communist Party; by contrast, they presented the relationship between enterprise directors and political decision makers in terms of the principal-agent concept, stressing managerial opportunism. Recent works draw a more nuanced picture of Soviet industrial management as a non-homogeneous group. Some directors of the largest factories carried enormous political weight and became influential members of the party.Footnote 60 We find numerous examples of high-ranking directors trying to emancipate themselves from party control and acting as “real entrepreneurs for their own sake.”Footnote 61

The recent studies reveal new, important details about the evolution of the skills, values, and expectations of Soviet business elites and technical experts from Stalinist times to the 1990s. Case studies from the civilian nuclear industry and the investigation of the Chernobyl disaster in April 1986 underscore the deference of nuclear specialists to “official channels” and “decisions that they perceived as political, as opposed to rational” but also their loyalty to the Soviet nuclear-power project and its economic and political mission.Footnote 62

Enterprise and Society

Business enterprises in both Russia and the Soviet Union were heavily burdened by social obligations. In the last two decades, social responsibility of business—including different forms of philanthropism, the relationship between enterprises and employees and local communities, and the enterprises’ contribution to the development of public infrastructure—have been among the most popular topics in the business history of Russia.

During imperial and Soviet times, both the state and local communities expected enterprises to develop infrastructure and take care of their workers. Both periods saw the active involvement of enterprises in the development of social infrastructure and a widespread paternalist attitude to employees, as has been amply demonstrated by the results of the international research project “Work Incentives in Russian Industry, 1861–2000: Compensation, Commitment, Coercion.” In the project, Andrei Markevich and Andrei Sokolov have compared labor incentive policies in both pre-Soviet and Soviet times and detected more similarities than expected. Focusing on the Moscow “Hammer and Sickle” Metallurgical Plant, Markevich and Sokolov demonstrate how the management combined encouragement and coercion during the imperial, Soviet, and post-Soviet periods.Footnote 63 The collective volume about labor incentives in two large textile mills in late Imperial Russia also demonstrates the complexity of relations between employers and employees. Besides better wages, employees were also offered a set of welfare programs.Footnote 64

Fairly recent works combining the history of enterprises with labor history have also contributed to what we know about the persistence of informal practices in Russian enterprises. Michael Melancon's book about the 1912 Lena massacre, for example, shows the glaring tolerance of tsarist officials for illegal practices and systematic employers’ abuses when they dealt with strategic production for the state. This was at the root of one of the most infamous instances of anti-worker violence in tsarist Russia. The documents of official investigations and inquiries carried out following such violent conflicts provide historians with excellent material about the uglier sides of Russian industrial capitalism.Footnote 65

Soviet workers have long been at the center of historians’ interest. Recently, however, the study of Soviet monotowns has provided a broader perspective on Soviet labor relations. In his work on Magnitogorsk, Steven Kotkin cogently argues that historians ought to focus not only on the attempt by the Soviet state to control the economy or to “destroy” society but also on the state's attempt to create a new “Soviet” society. In fact, since the 1930s, one of the most efficient weapons the Soviet state used to fight economic and social backwardness was the construction of brand-new industrial plants together with satellite towns. Some of these industrial monotowns remained secret, not accessible to foreigners, and sometimes not even to Soviet citizens, but others became veritable showcases for domestic and foreign consumption, Soviet industrial achievements, and Soviet moral superiority over capitalist society.

In exchange for their loyalty, silence, and consent, the inhabitants of such towns were often offered better living conditions than other Soviet citizens. This was true not only of Soviet nuclear towns, like Pripyat or Ozersk, but also of other industrial cities, such as Tolyatti and the other “Soviet Detroits.”Footnote 66 As if seen under a magnifying glass, their histories show the immensity of the welfare obligations of Soviet enterprises. Ultimately, the Soviet enterprise was the “primary unit of Soviet society and the basis of the social and political power”; it was a “hub that nurtured various forms of informal economy and blat relations” and an instrument of Soviet authoritarian paternalism.Footnote 67

Soviet labor history is also a source of detailed information about particular forms of entrepreneurship. Many businesspeople from the Russian Forbes list claim that they acquired their entrepreneurial skills while working in student construction brigades.Footnote 68 The government started to send these temporary construction crews to remote areas of the Soviet Union in the late 1950s. The job was well paid, and many students earned both money and the skills to start their own businesses in the late 1980s.

The Business History of Russia as an Alternative Business History

Most of the studies on the business and economic history of Russia have been written in the conceptual framework of “modernization,” which Theodor Von Laue aptly described as “a tragic dilemma of a backward country beset with the ambition to rival the model nations of the West.”Footnote 69 The debate on Russian modernization, implicitly or explicitly, compares Russian economic performance with that of the West and points out several peculiarities. One of them is the dominant role of the state, coexisting with significant institutional voids. Another is the “catch-up” character of Russian modernization, an essential part of which was the transfer and adaptation of technologies from abroad. Another peculiarity is that the level of political discontinuity and turbulence was exceptionally high in Russia, even by European standards.Footnote 70

The modernization theory is a powerful tool for explaining economic and business processes in less-developed countries and when comparing their performance with the early industrialized economies. Yet some business historians have initiated an interesting debate about the Western bias of the discipline and stress the need for a more plural and inclusive picture of the global business transformations. Gareth Austin, Carlos Dávila, and Geoffrey Jones suggest looking at the business history of the emerging markets as a “distinctive body of scholarship different from that on the West,” which singles out specific business responses to institutional contexts that are dissimilar from the developed markets.Footnote 71 The authors identify six “distinctive responses” typical of businesses in the emerging markets: “the important role of entrepreneurship, the prominence of immigrants and diaspora among business elites, the importance of illegal entrepreneurship, the role of business groups, the priority given to coping with economic and political instability, and engagement with social responsibility.”Footnote 72

The “alternative paradigm” seems to be a suitable framework for exploring the potential of the business history of Russia to contribute to current debates and even to refine the mainstream of the discipline. Also, applying it to the Russia questions usually asked about the developing countries can help reveal gaps in the research and identify promising new directions.

During the twentieth century, Russian enterprises faced extraordinary institutional and political challenges, which led to specific responses by Russian businesses. Though the periods of the late Russian Empire and Russia's contemporary history meet the definition of an emerging market, the peculiarities of the Soviet economic system suggest a certain caution in applying this framework. Still, recent research in the business history of the Soviet Union clusters around many of the “commonalities” highlighted by Austin, Dávila, and Jones as state intervention, entrepreneurship, social responsibilities. Besides, the alternative business history suggests focusing on how actors reacted to “institutional voids” and “turbulence in the business environment.” This is undoubtedly an approach well suited to the study of the crisis of the Soviet system and the challenges of contemporary Russia.Footnote 73

Placing the Russian experience in a “broader generalization” concerning emerging economies raises concerns that it might mean losing sight of the peculiarities of Russian business and entrepreneurship history. But, and this is a big but, historiography on Russia and the Soviet Union is not an emerging field; its tradition is too well established, and it is an area of expertise too strong, to be seriously challenged by looking at the history of Russian business through a lens that aims to place it in a global perspective. In what follows, we review how the business history of Russia has dealt with each of the six “distinctive responses” identified by Austin, Dávila, and Jones.

As we have seen, the business history of Russia is rediscovering the centrality of entrepreneurs in economic life in the Russian, Soviet, and post-Soviet contexts. But the evolution of the structure of the corporation, the pros and cons of big business, and the advantages of state-ownership over private entrepreneurship are still at the core of the debate. For the history of Russian state-owned enterprises and the entrepreneurial state, the Russian experience has been the benchmark for scholars dealing with the history of state intervention for a long time. Still, the events of the last thirty years, from the crisis of the Communist regime to the rise of Putin, have posed new questions that might well be better framed and answered if placed in a global perspective.

Studies on Russian state-owned enterprises in nonstrategic sectors, such as retail or services, are few and far between. By contrast, works on state-owned companies in the Russian energy sector, including Gazprom, Rosneft, and Lukoil, abound and offer fresh perspectives on monopolization processes and firms’ roles in foreign policy during and after the Cold War.Footnote 74 They also focus on the resources that Russian energy actors (and not only them) had and still have at their disposal to deal with changes in global markets and technology. The “resource-based approach” to transitional firms, popular in the late 1990s, rapidly fell out of fashion. Still, the history of Russian gas and oil companies proves that we need to know more about Russian organizational culture.

The role of foreign entrepreneurs and capital in Russia has been a trendy area of research since 1970, when John McKay published his influential book on foreign entrepreneurs in the Russian Empire.Footnote 75 McKay demonstrated how the trade-off between opportunity and risk shaped the strategies of international companies doing business in Russia. Recently, other scholars have published new case studies on the topic, providing opportunities to compare the business strategies of foreign companies in Russia with those in other countries. Since Imperial Russia was the major consumer of foreign direct investment in the world, research on business history in Russia contributes much to worldwide debate on multinational strategies and developing countries.Footnote 76

Among business historians of Russia, exploring “brain gain” has been more popular than focusing on “brain drain” processes. In this case, the alternative paradigm points out some gaps in the writing of history: business historians of Russia have largely overlooked the entrepreneurial activities of emigrants from Russia.

Historians of Russia have offered academically rich examples of illegal forms of business, informal practices, and white-collar and organized crime. Informal business practices have taken diverse forms and spread through all economic relations; they have proven extremely tenacious despite institutional and political changes and they remain one of the main challenges to Russian modernization.Footnote 77 Geoffrey Jones, Rachael Comunale, and Kate Lazaroff-Puck, in their case study on the rise and fall of the oligarch Boris Berezovsky, show that in the 1990s the Russian government did not just fail to fight crime but often based its authority on semi-criminal relations.Footnote 78 This was one of the few attempts at bringing Russian oligarchs (crony capitalists who have become central actors in the Russian transformation) back in to the mainstream business history debate on white-collar crime in western Europe, the Mafia, and endemic corruption in Italy, China, and Latin America. Business historians’ interest in these topics is recent, and uncertainties exist in the definitions and methodology of both concepts because of the poor sources.Footnote 79 Literature on “violent entrepreneurship” and the informal economy in Russia would surely contribute to business historians’ understanding both of the effects of endemic corruption on business performance and of the international ramifications of organized crime.Footnote 80

The alternative business history concept presents the creation of business groups as a rational response to institutional voids rather than as a sign of backwardness. This also applies to Russian business groups whose emergence resulted from the transformation of Soviet enterprises into business firms in the 1990s, in a political turbulence when the state was unable to guarantee the rule of law.Footnote 81 In particular, with the second wave of privatization (from 1995 to 1997)—the so-called loans for shares—the state allowed open auctions at which buyers, often the banks running the auctions, purchased assets at a fraction of the fair market price as collateral for granting credits to the Russian federal government. This led to the consolidation of private business groups, often headed by oligarchs. According to contemporary observers, this was an example of “state capture” or “privatization of the state” by Russian big business. Starting from the 2003 “Yukos affair”,Vladimir Putin ended this process, reimposingstate dominance over big business,and renationalizing most of them. The origins of Russian business groups are therefore very recent, their consolidation took place faster than in other emerging and mature economies, and the relations with political elites appear to be peculiar to Russia. For these reasons, stressing historical analogies with business groups in emerging markets requires caution.

Several studies demonstrate that business organizations operating in Russia face institutional voids and discontinuities. Consequently, these firms have adapted their structures and strategies to an unstable institutional environment. As we sought to demonstrate above, this applies to both tsarist Russia and the Soviet Union, although with some features peculiar to only one or the other. The social and political experiment that followed the end of the Soviet Union offers business historians another opportunity to investigate how businesses respond to rapid and unpredictable contextual changes.Footnote 82

And yet considerable gaps remain in business historians’ understanding of the last decade of the Soviet Union and the first decade of the new Russia when enterprises had to deal with the legacy of their past social and political functions. In theory, economic liberalization and privatization should have wiped away any residual socialism, especially political interference in company decision-making.Footnote 83 Nevertheless, legacies of the Socialist past today seem markedly more important in determining the future of Russia than scholars imagined in the 1990s. Mark Beissinger and Steve Kotkin cogently compare Soviet legacies to colonial legacies.Footnote 84 This direction may well be worth elaborating using the alternative paradigm.

Business responses to context were particularly neglected by business and economic historians of the Soviet period, who focused more on the politics and macroeconomics of the Soviet period—the planned economy—than on actors. Nevertheless, Philip Scranton's “key concepts of business history”—action, agency, and structure—apply to the Soviet epoch as well.Footnote 85

Scholars formerly presented Russian and Soviet economic actors as rational but faceless individuals or entities with free access to infinite information. New research instead highlights how the Russian business decision-making process was hardly straightforward, and scholars provide valuable case studies to debates on behavioral management theory and cultural economics. In addition, the representation of an economic actor as homo economicus is now increasingly having to compete with the picture, drawn by cultural historians, of entrepreneurs and managers as emotional, torn, irrational individuals forced to survive and act entrepreneurially, often in a turbulent political context.Footnote 86 Russian and Soviet history is a veritable reservoir of cases for the “historical and narrative turn” in contemporary business history studies.Footnote 87

Digging deep into the agency problem can sometimes help us to gain a better understanding of the mechanisms of monopolization and competition. Although for a long time the received wisdom was that competition does not exist in planned economies, new case studies can contribute much to the discussion about the impact of competition and cooperation within a business organization on the performance of the planned economy in which it operates.Footnote 88 It is now clear that in the Soviet system, it was not only enterprises that competed for resources; so too did ministries and departments representing political groups of influence. The clash of interests between these groups caused ambitious projects to fail. The construction of nationwide computer networks in the 1960s and 1970s, for instance, failed because the different government departments could not come to an agreement on standards.Footnote 89 This example also serves as a useful lesson about difficulties that arise in state-led innovation.

The adoption of radical corporate social responsibility concepts has not really been a choice for Russian enterprises. Instead, it has been an obligation toward their employees and the local community, and it has its roots in tsarist times.Footnote 90

Like the early industrialized economies, factory welfare was a tool used to compete for skilled workers and a way of dealing with the crisis in business-labor relations and also an attempt to forestall labor movements.Footnote 91 At the same time, enterprises in Russia often provided the social infrastructure for their employees and their families and for other local communities. In the eyes of the government, the employer was, or was meant to be, a benevolent master who took care of the moral and material well-being of his workers.Footnote 92 By means of legislation, as well as informal institutions, the government nudged employers to assume social obligations. Philanthropic (often religious-based) motives and expectations of business, typical of moral economies, also played an important role. Their incentives were closer to the model that Austin, Dávila, and Jones describe.

Our review, we hope, shows that the business history of Russia needs to be taken seriously by business historians for a number of reasons: The history of business in Russian has much in common with what Austin, Dávila, and Jones noticed in emerging markets. At the same time, our review shows that the business history of Russia inhabits that blurrily demarcated area between alternative business history and mainstream business history, the history of emerging and early developed markets. As such, it adds to the challenge but also defines them both.

Concluding Remarks

Despite being isolated from the international community, the business history of Russia did not ignore international trends. Its research therefore has a potential opportunity to contribute to the current debates on the subject. Sometimes, however, the community is focused on adapting the latest concepts and theories but less inclined to try to have an impact on these debates. Communication between business historians inside and outside of Russia continues to be a one-way street. We see great potential for increased integration into international discourse. We believe this can be achieved in the following ways.

To research locally but to think globally and to conduct transnational comparative research is the chief way. By focusing exclusively on Russian cases, historians of business in Russia limit their potential impact. Scholars should look beyond Russia's borders.

Decades of political discontinuity in Russia have fragmented the narrative. Most of the research has been on a clearly demarcated period: imperial, Soviet, or post-Soviet. To trace the fundamental social changes in Russian society and to see how that society has diverged or converged with the rest of the world, we need longue durée histories following enterprises’ paths through periods of political disruption.

Although some organizational studies on the history of entrepreneurs and enterprises of Russia have been published, far more research is needed that focuses on organizational structures and business strategies. Studies focusing on the decision-making processes and investigating the “black boxes” of Russian enterprises are still few and far between. Moreover, surprisingly few works directly address the question of why some businesses failed while others succeeded. The performance and competitive advantage of Russian businesses is a topic of great potential.

Footnotes

The authors would especially like to thank Franco Amatori, Leonid Borodkin, Luciano Segreto, Alexey Popov, Irina Nesterova, and two anonymous referees for their constructive criticism of earlier drafts of this article. We also want to thank the editors of this journal for their helpful comments. A grateful thought goes to Aksana Yarashynskaya, who contributed to an earlier version of this paper and did bibliographic research. Valentina Fava acknowledges financial support from the Czech Academy of Sciences, Purkyne Fellowship. Please note: this article was written prior to the Russian invasion of Ukraine in February 2022 and reflects the geopolitical and intellectual atmosphere of that time.

References

1 Owen, Thomas C., Russian Corporate Capitalism from Peter the Great to Perestroika (Oxford, 1995)Google Scholar.

2 Yudanov, Andrei Yu., “USSR: Large Enterprises in the USSR—The Functional Disorder,” in Big Business and the Wealth of Nations, eds. Chandler, Alfred D., Amatori, Franco, and Hikino, Takashi (Cambridge, U.K., 1997), 395432CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 For a first tentative tour d'horizon on this matter, see Valentina Fava and Aksana Yarashynskaya, “The Blurring Borders of Russian Business History: A Survey of Current and Recent Research” (paper presented at the World Economic History Congress, Boston, 29 July–3 Aug. 2018); Fava, “L'impresa (post) socialista come terreno d'incontro tra business history e storia del lavoro,” in Le libertà del lavoro. Stato, diritto e società, ed. Laura Cerasi (Palermo, 2016), 131–55.

4 By “international business history” we mean scholarship presented in the leading international journals in the field, including Business History, Business History Review, and Enterprise & Society, and in specialized book series, like Comparative Perspectives in Business History (Cambridge University Press). By “Russian business history” we mean the Russian-language literature, while “the business history of Russia” refers to all publications related to the topic no matter where it is researched or what language it is written in.

5 Kragh, Martin, “The Soviet Enterprise: What Have We Learned from the Archives?,” Enterprise & Society 14, no. 2 (2013): 384CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 See Friedman, Walter A. and Jones, Geoffrey, “Business History: Time for Debate,” Business History Review 85, no. 1 (2011): 1–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jones, Geoffrey, van Leeuwen, Marco H. D., and Broadberry, Stephen, “The Future of Economic, Business, and Social History,” Scandinavian Economic History Review 60, no. 3 (2012): 225–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Scranton, Philip and Fridenson, Patrick, Reimagining Business History (Baltimore, 2013)Google Scholar; Friedman and Jones, “Debating Methodology in Business History,” Business History Review 91, no. 3 (2017): 225–53; and Friedman, “Recent Trends in Business History Research: Capitalism, Democracy, and Innovation,” Enterprise & Society 18, no. 4 (2017): 748–71.

7 Austin, Gareth, Dávila, Carlos, and Jones, Geoffrey, “The Alternative Business History: Business in Emerging Markets,” Business History Review 91, no. 3 (2017): 537–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 Fava and Yarashynskaya, “Blurring Borders.”

9 The Eastern European Economic History Initiative (WEast), established in 2016, seeks to promote research on the economic history of eastern, central, and southeastern Europe and has recently shown increased interest in the history of business organization in the region. See “Mission,” WEast website, accessed 13 May 2022, http://weast.info/mission.

10 Examples include the conference “The Russian Corporation” held in New Haven, Connecticut, on February 22 and 23, 2019, and the conference “Firms and Social Change in Eastern and South-Eastern Europe: Historical, Political and Economic Perspectives,” held in Regensburg, Germany, on May 23–25, 2019.

11 Amatori, Franco and Jones, Geoffrey, eds., Business History around the World (Cambridge, MA, 2003), 7CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 Irina V. Potkina, Na olimpe delovogo uspekha: Nikol’skaia manufaktura Morozovykh, 1797–1917 [On the Olympus of success: The Morozovs’ textile mills, 1797–1917] (Moscow, 2004), 21. Potkina equates business history with the history of entrepreneurship. Many of her fellow historians share this approach and translate “business history” into Russian as istoriia predprinimatel'stva, that is, “the history of entrepreneurship.”

13 The sample includes books published in the twenty-first century, but the history of Russian enterprise and entrepreneurship was a focus of scholarly work long before 2001. See, for example, McKay, John P., Pioneers for Profit: Foreign Entrepreneurship and Russian Industrialization, 1885–1913 (Chicago, 1970)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Owen, Thomas C., Capitalism and Politics in Russia: A Social History of the Moscow Merchants, 1855–1905 (Cambridge, U.K., 1981)Google Scholar; Rieber, Alfred J., Merchants and Entrepreneurs in Imperial Russia (Chapel Hill, 1982)Google Scholar; Guroff, Gregory and Carstensen, Fred V., Entrepreneurship in Imperial Russia and the Soviet Union (Princeton, 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gatrell, Peter, Government, Industry and Rearmament in Russia, 1900–1914: The Last Argument of Tsarism (Cambridge, U.K., 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Valerii Bovykin, ed., Istoriia predprinimatel'stva v Rossii [A history of entrepreneurship in Russia], 2 vols. (Moscow, 2000).

14 Amatori and Jones, Business History around the World, 1.

15 Kobrak, Christopher and Schneider, Andrea, “Varieties of Business History: Subject and Methods for the Twenty-First Century,” Business History 53, no. 3 (2011): 406CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 We support our observations with exemplary references from our data set and works from the “neighboring” disciplines in order to demonstrate the blurry borders of the business history of Russia.

17 Gerschenkron, Alexander, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays (Cambridge, MA, 1962)Google Scholar.

18 Ol'ga V. Erokhina, Nemetskoe predprinimatel'stvo v khoziaistvennom komplekse Iuga Rossii, 1860–1930-e gg. [German entrepreneurship in the economic system of southern Russia, 1860–1930] (Volgograd, 2011); Nataliia A. Proskuriakova, Ipoteka v Rossiiskoi imperii [Mortgages in the Russian Empire] (Moscow, 2014); Yakovlev, Andrei, “The Evolution of Business-State Interaction in Russia: From State Capture to Business Capture?,” Europe-Asia Studies 58, no. 7 (2006): 1033–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 Iurii A. Petrov, “Rossiia v 1913 godu: ekonomicheskii rost” [Russia in 1913: Economic growth], Nauka i zhizn', no. 7 (2014), http://www.nkj.ru/archive/articles/24628/.

20 Irina V. Potkina, Pravovoe regulirovanie predprinimatel'skoi deiatel'nosti v Rossii, XIX—pervaia chetvert' XX veka [Legislation of entrepreneurial activity in Russia from the nineteenth century to the first quarter of the twentieth] (Moscow, 2009), 275.

21 Owen writes, “Every episode in the history of the Russian corporate law showed the incompatibility between the autocratic political system and the modern corporation.” Owen, Thomas C., The Corporation under Russian Law, 1800–1917: A Study in Tsarist Economic Policy (Cambridge, U.K., 1991), 199CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Potkina, Pravovoe regulirovanie, 277–78.

23 Amanda Gregg and Steven Nafziger, “Capital Structure and Corporate Performance in Late Imperial Russia,” European Review of Economic History 23, no. 4 (2019): 448.

24 Nikolai M. Arsent'ev, “Predprinimatel'stvo i gosudarstvo v istoricheskoi retrospektive rossiiskikh modernizatsii” [Entrepreneurship and the state in the historical retrospective of the Russian modernizations], Ekonomicheskaia istoriia, no. 1 (2010): 18–20.

25 Sawyer, Benjamin, “Manufacturing Germans: Singer Manufacturing Company and American Capitalism in the Russian Imagination during World War I,” Enterprise & Society 17, no. 2 (2016): 301–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 Paul R. Gregory, “The Role of the State in Promoting Economic Development: The Russian Case and Its General Implications,” in Patterns of European Industrialisation: The Nineteenth Century, ed. Richard Sylla and Gianni Toniolo (London, 1992), 64–79; Millward, Robert, The State and Business in the Major Powers: An Economic History, 1815–1939 (London, 2013), 161–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 The new findings confirm the thesis about the limitations of state capitalism in Russia. For example, Radaev argues that the Russian entrepreneurs were pinched between two powerful entities: the strong state, on the one hand, and traditional communities (patriarchal families, rural communities, ethnic or religious groups), on the other. Radaev argues that this bipolarity was present during the entire twentieth century. See Vadim V. Radaev, “Dva kornia rossiiskogo predprinimatel'stva: fragmenty istorii” [Two roots of entrepreneurship in Russia], Mir Rossii: Sotsiologiia. Etnologiia 4, no. 1 (1995): 159–78.

28 Granick, David, Management of the Industrial Firm in the USSR: A Study in Soviet Economic Planning (New York, 1954)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Berliner, Joseph S., Factory and Manager in the USSR (Cambridge, MA, 1957)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

29 Kragh, “Soviet Enterprise”; Joseph S. Berliner, “The Contribution of the Soviet Archives,” in Behind the Façade of Stalin's Command Economy: Evidence from the Soviet State and Party Archives, ed. Paul Gregory (Stanford, CA, 2001), 1–10.

30 Harrison, Mark, Guns and Rubles: The Defense Industry in the Stalinist State (New Haven, 2008)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Arsenii Iu. Ermolov, Gosudarstvennoe upravlenie voennoi promyshlennost'iu v 1940-e gody: tankovaia promyshlennost' [The state-controlled military industry in the 1940s: Tank production] (Saint Petersburg, 2013); Paul R. Gregory and Valery Lazarev, eds., The Economics of Forced Labor: The Soviet Gulag (Stanford, 2003); Barenberg, Alan, Gulag Town, Company Town: Forced Labor and Its Legacy in Vorkuta (New Haven, 2014)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Chandler, Alfred D., “Organizational Capabilities and the Economic History of the Industrial Enterprise,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 6, no. 3 (1992): 84–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 Amatori, Franco and Colli, Andrea, Business History: Complexities and Comparisons (London and New York, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33 See also Cohen, Yves, Le Siècle des chefs: Une histoire transnationale du commandement et de l'autorité (1890–1940) (Paris, 2013), chap. 5Google Scholar.

34 Yudanov, “USSR”; Markevich, Andrei and Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina, “M-form Hierarchy with Poorly-Diversified Divisions: A Case of Khrushchev's Reform in Soviet Russia,” Journal of Public Economics 95, no. 11–12 (2011): 1550–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 Yakov Feygin, “Reforming the Cold War State: Economic Thought, Internationalization, and the Politics of Soviet Reform, 1955–1985” (PhD diss., University of Pennsylvania, 2017).

36 Kotkin, Stephen, Magnetic Mountain: Stalinism as a Civilization (Berkeley, 1997), 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

37 Markevich and Zhuravskaya, “M-form Hierarchy”; Hanson, Philip, The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Economy: An Economic History of the USSR, 1945–1991 (London, 2014), 67CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kibita, Nataliya, Soviet Economic Management under Khrushchev: The Sovnarkhoz Reform (London, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

38 Millward, State and Business.

39 Boris M. Shpotov, Amerikanskii biznes i Sovetskii Soiuz v 1920–1930-e gody: Labirinty ekonomicheskogo sotrudnichestva [American business and the Soviet Union in the 1920s and 1930s: The labyrinths of economic cooperation] (Moscow, 2013); Grachev, Mikhail and Rakitsky, Boris, “Historic Horizons of Frederick Taylor's Scientific Management,” Journal of Management History 19, no. 4 (2013): 512–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

40 Kravets, Olga and Sandikçi, Özlem, “Marketing for Socialism: Soviet Cosmetics in the 1930s,” Business History Review 87, no. 3 (2013): 461–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

41 Varese, Federico, The Russian Mafia: Private Protection in a New Market Economy (Oxford, 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rehn, Alf and Taalas, Saara, “‘Znakomstva I Svyazi’ (Acquaintances and Connections)—Blat, the Soviet Union, and Mundane Entrepreneurship,” Entrepreneurship & Regional Development 16, no. 3 (2004): 235–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ledeneva, Alena V., How Russia Really Works: The Informal Practices That Shaped Post-Soviet Politics and Business (Ithaca, 2006)Google Scholar.

42 Freris, Andrew, The Soviet Industrial Enterprise: Theory and Practice (London, 2018)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 Igor' N. Shapkin, “Lobbistskie soiuzy rossiiskogo biznesa: tipy, organizatsionnye printsipy i osnovnye formy deiatel'nosti (vtoraia polovina XIX – nachalo XX veka)” [Lobbying unions of Russian business: Types, organizational principles, activities in the second half of the nineteenth - early twentieth century], Istoriko-ekonomicheskie issledovaniia 16, no. 3 (2015): 559–76.

44 Owen, Thomas C., Dilemmas of Russian Capitalism: Fedor Chizhov and Corporate Enterprise in the Railroad Age (Cambridge, MA, 2005), 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

45 Boris V. Anan'ich, Ditmar Dal'mann, and Iurii A. Petrov, Chastnoe predprinimatel'stvo v dorevoliutsionnoi Rossii: etnokonfessional'naia struktura i regional'noe razvitie, XIX – nachalo XX veka [Private entrepreneurship in prerevolutionary Russia: Ethnic and religious structure and regional development, nineteenth - eatly twentieth century] (Moscow, 2010); Ulianova, Galina, Female Entrepreneurs in Nineteenth-Century Russia (London, 2009)Google Scholar.

46 Raskov, Danila and Kufenko, Vadim, “Religious Minority in Business History: The Case of Old Believers,” Business History 59, no. 6 (2017): 967CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 Valerii I. Bovykin, N. N. Gurushina, and I. A. D'iakonov, Inostrannoe predprinimatel'stvo i zagranichnye investitsii v Rossii: Ocherki [Foreign entrepreneurship and foreign investment in Russia: Essays] (Moscow, 1997).

48 This corresponds to observations made by scholars in the previous decades. See Carstensen, Fred V., American Enterprise in Foreign Markets: Studies of Singer and International Harvester in Imperial Russia (Chapel Hill, 1984)Google Scholar.

49 Owen, Thomas C., “Chukchi Gold: American Enterprise and Russian Xenophobia in the Northeastern Siberia Company,” Pacific Historical Review 77, no. 1 (2008): 49–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar; see also Sawyer, “Manufacturing Germans.”

50 See John P. McKay, “John Cockerill in Southern Russia, 1885–1905: A Study of Aggressive Foreign Entrepreneurship,” Business History Review 41, no. 3 (1967): 243–56; Sawyer, “Manufacturing Germans.”

51 Oscar Sánchez-Sibony, Red Globalization: The Political Economy of the Soviet Cold War from Stalin to Khrushchev (Cambridge, U.K., 2014); Fava, Valentina, “Between Business Interests and Ideological Marketing: The USSR and the Cold War in Fiat Corporate Strategy, 1957–1972,” Journal of Cold War Studies 20, no. 4 (2019): 26–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Irina Yányshev-Nésterova, “Soviet Big Business: The Rise and Fall of the State Corporation Sovrybflot, 1965–1991,” Business History (advance online publication 27 Dec. 2020), https://doi.org/10.1080/00076791.2020.1856079.

52 This was true even despite attempts to present Chandler's main idea to the Russian audience: for example, Boris M. Shpotov, “Teoriia evoliutsii firmy Al'freda D. Chandlera i puti razvitiia promyshlennosti” [Theory of evolution of a firm by Alfred Chandler], in Ekonomicheskaia istoriia: Ezhegodnik 2009, eds. Leonid Borodkin and Iurii Petrov (Moscow, 2009), 21–50.

53 Anton Dmitriev and Andrei Semenov, eds., Ocherki istorii rossiiskikh firm: voprosy sobstvennosti, upravleniia, khoziaistvovaniia [The history of Russian firms: Ownership, administration, operational management] (Saint Petersburg, 2007); Baryshnikov, “Akcionernye kompanii v Rossii v nachale XX veka: balans interesov i institucional'nye ogranichenija” [Joint-stock companies in Russia in the early twentieth century: Balance of interests and institutional constraints], Terra Economicus 8, no. 2 (2010): 95–101.

54 Gregg, Amanda G., “Factory Productivity and the Concession System of Incorporation in Late Imperial Russia, 1894–1908,” American Economic Review 110, no. 2 (2020): 401–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

55 Leonid I. Borodkin and Anna V. Konovalova, Rossiiskii fondovyi rynok v nachale XX veka [The Russian stock market in the early twentieth century] (Moscow, 2010); Sof'ia A. Salomatina, “Investitsionnye operatsii kommercheskikh bankov v dorevoliutsionnoi Rossii: poisk optimal'noi modeli” [Investment operations of commercial banks in prerevolutionary Russia: Searching for the optimal model], Ekonomicheskaia istoriia: Ezhegodnik 2011 (Moscow, 2012), 247–92; Proskuriakova, Ipoteka v Rossiiskoi imperii.

56 Guroff and Carstensen, Entrepreneurship; Gréen, Oksana Shmulyar, Entrepreneurship in Russia: Western Ideas in Russian Translation (Gothenburg, 2009)Google Scholar.

57 Shmulyar Gréen, Entrepreneurship in Russia, 136.

58 Nikula, Jouko and Tchalakov, Ivan, Innovations and Entrepreneurs in Socialist and Post-Socialist Societies (Newcastle upon Tyne, 2014)Google Scholar; Philip Hanson, “Networks, Cronies and Business Plans: Business-State Relations in Russia,” in Russia as a Network State: What Works in Russia When State Institutions Do Not? ed. Vadim Kononenko and Arkady Moshes (London, 2011), 113–39.

59 Guroff and Carstensen, Entrepreneurship, 284.

60 Sergei A. Bakanov, Ugol'naia promyshlennost' Urala: zhiznennyi tsikl otrasli ot zarozhdeniia do upadka [The coal industry of the Urals: The industry life cycle from emergence to decline] (Chelyabinsk, 2012); Liudmila L. Mokhovikova, Kolesnitsa sud'by avtomobilizatsii Rossii [A history of automobilization in Russia] (Tolyatti, 2017).

61 Nikula and Tchalakov, Innovations and Entrepreneurs, 29.

62 Evgenii T. Artemov, Sovetskii atomnyi proekt v sisteme komandnoi ekonomiki [The Soviet nuclear project in the system of the command economy] (Moscow, 2017); Plokhy, Serhii, Chernobyl: History of a Tragedy (New York, 2018)Google Scholar; Brown, Kate, Manual for Survival: A Chernobyl Guide to the Future (London, 2019)Google Scholar; Schmid, Sonja D., “Organizational Culture and Professional Identities in the Soviet Nuclear Power Industry,” Osiris 23, no. 1 (2008): 110CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

63 Andrei M. Markevich and Andrei K. Sokolov, “Magnitka bliz Sadovogo kol'tsa”: stimuly k rabote na Mosk. z-de “Serp i molot” [Work incentives at the Moscow “Hammer and Sickle” Metallurgical Plant] (Moscow, 2005).

64 Leonid I. Borodkin, Timur Ya. Valetov, Iuliia B. Smirnova and Irina V. Shil'nikova, “Ne rublem edinym”: trudovye stimuly rabochikh-tekstil'shchikov dorevoliutsionnoi Rossii [Labor incentives of textile workers in prerevolutionary Russia] (Moscow, 2010).

65 Melancon, Michael, The Lena Goldfields Massacre and the Crisis of the Late Tsarist State (College Station, TX, 2006)Google Scholar.

66 Sergei V. Zhuravlev and Rudol'f G. Pikhoia, Avtovaz mezhdu proshlym i budushchim: istoriia Volzhskogo avtomobil'nogo zavoda, 1966–2005 [AvtoVAZ between past and future: The history of the Volga Automobile Plant, 1966–2005] (Moscow, 2006); Lennart Samuelson, Tankograd: The Formation of a Soviet Company Town: Cheliabinsk, 1900s–1950s (New York, 2011); Brown, Kate, Plutopia: Nuclear Families, Atomic Cities, and the Great Soviet and American Plutonium Disasters (Oxford, 2013)Google Scholar.

67 Clarke, Simon, The Russian Enterprise in Transition (Brookfield, VT, 1996), 10Google Scholar; Nikula and Tchalakov, Innovations and Entrepreneurs, 10–11.

68 Valerii Igumenov, “Nastroika kapitalizma” [Building up capitalism], Forbes Russia, 3 Jan. 2005, https://www.forbes.ru/forbes/issue/2005-01/19408-nastroika-kapitalizma.

69 Von Laue, Theodore H., “The High Cost and the Gamble of the Witte System: A Chapter in the Industrialization of Russia,” Journal of Economic History 13, no. 4 (1953): 448CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

70 See Aleksandr S. Seniavskii, “Istoricheskii opyt, kotoryi ne vostrebovan sovremennoi rossiiskoi praktikoi” [Historical experience, ignored in modern Russian practice], Ekonomicheskaia istoriia, no. 1 (2011): 28; and other articles in this issue.

71 Austin, Dávila, and Jones, “Alternative Business History,” 539.

72 Austin, Dávila, and Jones, “Alternative Business History,” 544.

73 Austin, Dávila, and Jones, 541–44.

74 Goldman, Marshall I., Petrostate: Putin, Power, and the New Russia (Oxford, 2008)Google Scholar; Gustafson, Thane, Wheel of Fortune: The Battle of Oil and Power in Russia (Cambridge, MA, 2012)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Overland, Indra and Poussenkova, Nina, Russian Oil Companies in an Evolving World: The Challenge of Change (Northampton, 2020)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

75 McKay, Pioneers for Profit.

76 According to McKay, “no other state even came close [to late Imperial Russia] to having a comparably significant infusion of foreign investment.” McKay, John P., “Foreign Enterprise in Russian and Soviet Industry: A Long-Term Perspective,” Business History Review 48, no. 3 (1974): 340CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

77 Leonid I. Borodkin, “Neformal’nye sotsial’nye praktiki rabochikh v gody ‘pozdnego sotsializma’: k istoriografii voprosa” [Informal social practices of the workers in the period of Late Socialism: A histoiography of the issue], in Rabochie i obshchestvenno-politicheskii protsess v Rossii v kontse XIX – XX v.: materialy VI Vseross. nauchn. konf.: in 2 vols. Vol. 1. (Kostroma, 2012); Alena V. Ledeneva, Can Russia Modernise?: Sistema, Power Networks and Informal Governance (Cambridge, U.K., 2013).

78 Geoffrey Jones, Rachael Comunale, and Kate Lazaroff-Puck, “Boris Berezovsky, Vladimir Putin and the Russian Oligarchs” (Harvard Business School Case No. 317-005, Mar. 2017, rev. Dec. 2019).

79 Berghoff, Hartmut and Spiekermann, Uwe, “Shady Business: On the History of White-Collar Crime,” Business History 60, no. 3 (2018): 289–304CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

80 Volkov, Vadim, Violent Entrepreneurs: The Use of Force in the Making of Russian Capitalism (Ithaca, 2002)Google Scholar.

81 Dolgopyatova, Tatiana, Iwasaki, Ichiro, and Yakovlev, Andrei A., Organization and Development of Russian Business: A Firm-Level Analysis (London, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Glazunov, Mikhail, Business in Post-Communist Russia: Privatisation and the Limits of Transformation (London, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sergei Guriev, “Business Groups in Russia,” in The Oxford Handbook of Business Groups, ed. Asli Colpan, Takashi Hikino, and James R. Lincoln (Oxford, 2010), 526–47.

82 Lane, David, The Capitalist Transformation of State Socialism: The Making and Breaking of State Socialist Society, and What Followed (London, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

83 Adachi, Yuko, Building Big Business in Russia: The Impact of Informal Corporate Governance Practices (Abingdon, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

84 Beissinger, Mark and Kotkin, Stephen, Historical Legacies of Communism in Russia and Eastern Europe (Cambridge, U.K., 2014)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Thomas Owen emphasizes continuities between the tsarist and late Soviet periods and suggests some implications that the weak corporate heritage may have for the future of Russian capitalism. Owen, Russian Corporate Capitalism.

85 Scranton, Philip, “Foundations and Futures: Visions of Business Histories,” Enterprise & Society 21, no. 3 (2020): 642CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

86 See “Émotions et enterprises familiales,” special issue, Entreprises et Histoire 91, no. 2 (2018).

87 Hansen, Per H., “Business History: A Cultural and Narrative Approach,” Business History Review 86, no. 4 (2012): 693–717CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lipartito, Kenneth, “Connecting the Cultural and the Material in Business History,” Enterprise & Society 14, no. 4 (2013): 686–704CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

88 Woike, Jan K. and Hafenbrädl, Sebastian, “Rivals without a Cause? Relative Performance Feedback Creates Destructive Competition despite Aligned Incentives,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 33, no. 4 (2020): 523–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

89 Gerovitch, Slava, “InterNyet: Why the Soviet Union Did Not Build a Nationwide Computer Network,” History and Technology 24, no. 4 (2008): 335–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

90 Crowley, Stephen, “Monotowns and the Political Economy of Industrial Restructuring in Russia,” Post-Soviet Affairs 32, no. 5 (2016): 397–422CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

91 Kulikov, Volodymyr, “Necessity or Luxury? Welfare Work in the Company Towns of the Russian Empire,” Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte [Economic History Yearbook] 60, no. 2 (2019): 450CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

92 Kulikov, Volodymyr and Shilnikova, Irina, “Practices against Labor Movement in the Late Russian Empire,” in Corporate Policing, Yellow Unionism, and Strikebreaking, 1890–1930: In Defense of Freedom, ed. Millan, Matteo and Saluppo, Alessandro (Abingdon, 2020), 27Google Scholar.

Figure 0

Table 1. A Sample of Publications on Russian Business History with Six or More Citations on Google Scholar (as of February 27, 2021)