Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-x24gv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-08T16:27:37.243Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Gamson going global? Cabinet proportionality in comparative perspective

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 March 2024

Paul Chaisty
Affiliation:
Department of Politics and International Relations, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
Timothy J. Power*
Affiliation:
Department of Politics and International Relations, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
*
Corresponding author: Timothy J. Power; Email: timothy.power@socsci.ox.ac.uk
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We conduct a global, large-N analysis of proportionality in the partisan distribution of cabinet portfolios. Formulated in the context of postwar Western European parliamentary democracy, Gamson’s Law predicts that parties joining a coalition government will receive cabinet ministries in direct proportion to the seats they are contributing to the coalition on the floor of the legislature. Using a sample of 1551 country-years of coalitional government in 97 countries from 1966 to 2019, and comparing all main constitutional formats (parliamentary, presidential, and semi-presidential), we find that Gamson’s Law does not travel well outside its context of origin. Among the constitutional predictors of cabinet proportionality, we find that pure presidentialism is a major outlier, with an exaggerated form of formateur advantage. Introducing party-system and assembly-level predictors to the debate, we find that party institutionalization tends to increase fairness in portfolio allocation within parliamentary systems only.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of European Consortium for Political Research

Introduction

Our understanding of proportionality in coalition government is imbalanced. The literature on cabinet proportionality—i.e., the fairness of cabinet payoffs to legislative parties participating in coalition governments—has historically been focused on parliamentary systems. In pure parliamentarism, scholars have generally found strong support for ‘Gamson’s Law’ qualified by occasional overrepresentation of small parties (Browne and Franklin, Reference Browne and Franklin1973; Warwick and Druckman, Reference Warwick and Druckman2006; Cox, Reference Cox2021). As the literature broadened to include semi-presidentialism, however, scholars found a larger ‘formateur bonus’ for coalition-proposing parties holding the presidency, conditional on the degree of constitutional powers afforded to the president (Bucur, Reference Bucur2020). In pure presidential systems, the emerging literature on coalitional presidentialism has found a consistently large and disproportionate payoff for the party of the unipersonal executive, who is always the formateur in such systems (Altman, Reference Altman2000; Amorim Neto, Reference Amorim Neto, Morgenstern and Nacif2002; Chaisty et al., Reference Chaisty, Cheeseman and Power2018).

This uneven applicability of Gamson’s Law to semi-presidential and presidential systems is of more than mere mathematical curiosity. Cabinet proportionality clearly matters. As research on presidentialism has shown, the way coalitions are constructed can have direct implications for a range of real-world political and policy challenges. These include coalition discipline in roll-call voting (Amorim Neto, Reference Amorim Neto, Morgenstern and Nacif2002), economic reforms (Mejía-Acosta, Reference Mejía Acosta2009), aggregate government expenditure (Bertholini and Pereira Reference Bertholini and Pereira2017), and even grand corruption (Raile et al., Reference Raile, Pereira, Power, Timothy and Matthew2011).

Despite ample evidence that cabinet composition matters for macropolitical outcomes, the literatures on parliamentarism, semi-presidentialism, and pure presidentialism have largely operated in isolation, making it difficult to assess variation in the extent of cabinet proportionality across constitutional formats. Few studies have addressed the motivations of the key actors (formateurs, parties, and assemblies) in an integrated comparative framework, assuming instead that behavioral incentives within each constitutional format are self-evident. Compounding this problem is that most studies have tended to focus on a single world region, eschewing comparative or large-N analysis.

The literature on cabinet proportionality is therefore in need of several correctives. It requires a theoretical vocabulary that is not restricted to parliamentarism; it needs to look ‘under the bonnet’ of invariant constitutional formats in order to unveil more dynamic party-level and assembly-level influences on proportionality; and it needs to take Gamson’s Law out of its comfort zone in Western Europe—a goal that can only be realized by comparative and large-N research designs. From this starting point, we ask the following questions: what factors shape cabinet proportionality across world regions and across constitutional designs? What characteristics of party systems and/or legislatures might boost or constrain the advantage of the formateur? And more generally, just how well does Gamson’s Law travel? As a preliminary step toward answering these questions, we provide the most comprehensive large-N, cross-national exploration of cabinet proportionality across multiple executive formats and party systems. We do so by expanding the new WhoGov dataset (Nyrup and Bramwell, Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020) to include legislative seats shares of all cabinet-represented parties. This allows us to measure cabinet proportionality in 1551 country-years of competitive politics in 97 countries in the period from 1966 to 2019. The inclusion of country-year observations over the entire period enables us to track variation in cabinet composition between election years—a phenomenon that can be especially significant in presidential systems, given the tendency of presidential formateurs to tinker with cabinet composition on a frequent basis (Chaisty et al., Reference Chaisty, Cheeseman and Power2018: 129). To this dataset, we also add party-system and assembly-level covariates (drawn from the V-Dem and V-Party datasets) to examine the determinants of cabinet proportionality within each broad executive format. Footnote 1

Our key findings are as follows. First, confirming previous studies (e.g., Amorim and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010), we find that presidentialism is the sensational outlier among constitutional types: it offers the least proportionality in portfolio allocation, which is a consequence of the fewest constraints on the formateurs of coalitions (i.e., presidents). Second, parliamentary and semi-presidential systems are more similar when it comes to cabinet proportionality and its determinants, although important differences remain. Third, party institutionalization in a generic sense (a composite of strength of party organizations, links to civil society, party ID among voters, coherence of party platforms and ideologies, etc.) strongly increases proportionality in parliamentary systems, but has no beneficial effects on proportionality in presidential systems, and is highly sensitive to regional effects in semi-presidential systems. Fifth, although existing datasets have only crude measures of portfolio salience (a longstanding deficiency of the literature), we find evidence that formateurs in pure presidentialism are more likely to reserve the most prestigious cabinet posts for their own parties. Sixth and finally, we find that Gamson’s Law does not travel especially well, whether across constitutional types or across world regions. The best fit of this ‘law’ is not just with parliamentary systems, but particularly with European parliamentary systems. Where pure parliamentarism exists outside of Europe, Gamsonian principles are less ingrained. These findings are robust to controls on the level of political democracy.

What do we know about cabinet proportionality and deviations from it?

Any discussion of proportionality invariably begins with William Gamson’s early theory of coalition formation. Footnote 2 According to Gamson (Reference Gamson1961: 376), ‘any participant will expect others to demand from a coalition a share of the payoff proportional to the amount of resources which they contribute to a coalition.’ Starting as an intuitive proposition, this statement was gradually recast as a ‘law’ in the wake of Browne and Franklin’s (Reference Browne and Franklin1973) classic observational study of European portfolio allocation in the 1950s and 1960s. The law-like reappraisal of Gamson turned entirely on Browne and Franklin’s operationalization of ‘resources’ in the quote above, which they measured as the share of legislative seats held (‘contributed’) by each party in the coalition. Within coalition governments in parliamentary systems, they found the correlation between portfolio shares and seat shares to be nearly perfect, a finding that (with various disclaimers attached) has been confirmed empirically time and time again, mainly in the Western European context (e.g., Schofield and Laver, Reference Schofield and Laver1985; Warwick and Druckman, Reference Warwick and Druckman2001). While this relationship may not be a ‘law’ in the strict sense of the term (Indridason, Reference Indridason2015), it has nonetheless been described as ‘perhaps the strongest empirical finding in political science’ (Warwick and Druckman Reference Warwick and Druckman2006: 635).

It is beyond the scope of this paper to review the vast secondary literature on proportionality in portfolio allocation. However, we draw attention to four core elements of this body of research. First, as noted above, Gamson’s Law has strong empirical support in parliamentary democracies, on which virtually all extant scholarship is based. Second, in parliamentary coalition governments, the observed deviations from proportionality have mostly come in the form of the ‘small party bias’, meaning that very small coalition partners tend to do slightly better than one would expect from a linear interpretation of Gamson’s Law (Browne and Franklin, Reference Browne and Franklin1973; Warwick and Druckman, Reference Warwick and Druckman2006). Some have referred to this small-party asterisk on proportionality as ‘modified Gamson’s Law’ (e.g., Cox, Reference Cox2021). Third, in parliamentarism there has been little or no empirical support for the idea of formateur advantage—which makes some sense given what we know about the minor overrepresentation of small parties (this practice already suggests some implicit forbearance by the formateur party).

The fourth and most intriguing aspect of this research program concerns the long-running attempt to uncover solid theoretical foundations for Gamson’s Law (Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason, Reference Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason2013). In the parliamentary literature, formal models of legislative bargaining have not fared well. So-called ‘proposer’ models, or alternating-offer games (e.g., Baron and Ferejohn, Reference Baron and Ferejohn1989; Ansolabehere et al., Reference Ansolabehere, Snyder, Strauss and Ting2005), suggest that the formateur should be advantaged by their take-it-or-leave-it control over the negotiation process. Empirical adaptations of this idea eschew the traditional focus on seat shares in the legislature (the Browne and Franklin interpretation of Gamsonian resources) in favor of ‘bargaining weights’ (the extent to which a given party is pivotal to a winning coalition). Yet using either or both operationalizations, empirical evidence of formateur advantage has generally been found lacking in parliamentarism, even in more recent work that attempts to correct for portfolio salience (Warwick and Druckman Reference Warwick and Druckman2001, Reference Warwick and Druckman2006; Bucur, Reference Bucur2018). Warwick and Druckman (Reference Warwick and Druckman2006) note this disconnect between empirical and theoretical work and name it the ‘portfolio allocation paradox’—in other words, proportionality shouldn’t exist but does.

In the nearly two decades since Warwick and Druckman first posed this paradox, a number of scholars have attempted to resolve it. Several have considered the possibility that Gamson’s Law is nothing more than a social norm of fairness. Footnote 3 In a paired comparison of Sweden and Germany, Bäck et al. (Reference Bäck, Meier and Persson2009) find little support for a social norm in the strict sense of the term, but do find that proportionality ‘serves as a bargaining convention for the actors involved, thus rendering proportional payoffs more likely’. In contrast, Cutler et al. (Reference Cutler, de Marchi, Gallop, Hollenbach, Laver and Orlowski2016) argue that there is indeed a proportionality norm in coalition formation, but that it is observed mainly as a conflict-defusing device after the difficult work of policy bargaining has already taken place. Ecker and Meyer (Reference Ecker and Meyer2019) take the policy payoff idea one step further. Matching the content of party manifestos to observed portfolio allocations, they argue that policy fairness is more likely to be achieved when parties already consent to apportionment of cabinet positions that are proportional to party size—in other words, to the terms of Gamson’s Law. Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason (Reference Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason2013) make a different but compatible claim about proportionality: that it is almost always the fastest and cleanest solution to bargaining situations characterized by high levels of complexity and uncertainty. More recently, Martin and Vanberg (Reference Martin and Vanberg2020) have focused on the optics of coalitional negotiations, developing a theory that they call ‘bargaining before an audience’. If parties are worried that their supporters may see them as ineffective negotiators, they may choose to accept proportionality of cabinet posts as a safely defensible outcome—while at the same time pushing hard for concessions on less easily observable issues.

All focusing on parliamentary regimes, these more recent contributions depict Gamson’s Law as something of a heuristic and/or a ‘default’ outcome in the composition of coalition governments: when the starting point is some notion of proportionality, then it is not surprising that the endpoint is something resembling proportionality. If a law is a default scenario and a default scenario is a law, then this circularity may bring us no closer to providing the desired theoretical microfoundations for Gamsonian proportionality.

Three logics of coalition formation: comparing constitutional formats

Scholarship on Gamson’s Law often assumes that there is a single institutional ecosystem for cabinet composition, a bias that may be forgiven given the postwar Western European origins of this literature. At the beginning of the Third Wave of democratization in the late 1970s, well over half of the world’s political democracies were parliamentary systems. However, by 2010 nearly two-thirds of existing democracies had directly elected presidents of some kind (Samuels and Shugart Reference Samuels and Shugart2010: 5). Instauration of new parliamentary democracies with ceremonial or indirectly elected heads of state is now exceedingly rare, while semi-presidential and presidential formats are on the rise across the globe. Theories of cabinet composition need to be updated to reflect this reality. Revising theory requires identification of the relevant actors (in this case, formateurs, political parties, and legislative assemblies) and recognizing how their motivations vary across three prominent constitutional types.

In discussing executive formats, we start with noncontroversial assumptions: formateurs should want to exaggerate their natural first-mover advantage, and parties should aim for the best deal they can get. Parties will want to maximize the number of ministers at the cabinet table and will oppose favoritism to other parties. The degree to which parties can influence the formateur will depend, at least in part, on broad constitutional characteristics pertaining to government formation, assembly confidence, and executive discretion.

Parliamentarism is familiar and its principles are depicted in the vast literature cited above (see also Lijphart, Reference Lijphart2012). As the name suggests, parliamentarism rests on the centrality of the elected assembly, of which both formateurs and ministers are working members. The head of state normally invites the leader of the largest party to attempt to form a government. In non-majoritarian configurations of seats (the modal outcome in the parliamentary world), automatic success in government formation is not guaranteed, and therefore the number of potential formateurs is greater than one. Governments generally depend on the support of a majority of the legislature in order to take office and remain in office. Minority governments can also survive, but normally with commitments from key opposition parties not to bring down the government. In both majority and minority scenarios, prime ministers are always subject to confidence motions. When coalition government becomes necessary under this constitutional format, political parties naturally find their bargaining power enhanced. Given that they are central to government formation and government termination, parties must be cultivated carefully. Each party will assess the essential fairness of any power-sharing arrangements, observing who gets what (the original insight of Gamson). Thus it is perhaps not surprising that when formateurs propose a coalition, they tend to treat their allies proportionally when allocating ministerial portfolios.

Presidential democracy works very differently (Linz, Reference Linz, Juan and Valenzuela1994). Elections for the head of government (president) and for the legislature are independent of each other, meaning that the executive and legislature have ‘separate origin and separate survival’ (Shugart and Carey, Reference Shugart and Carey1992). In contrast to parliamentary systems, the number of potential formateurs is consistently one, since only the directly elected president can exercise this role. The president does not require political support in the legislative assembly in order to take office, and once inaugurated enjoys a fixed term. In presidential systems, the absence of a vote of no confidence means that the head of government (president) is far less dependent on the support of coalition partners than is the equivalent figure (prime minister) in parliamentary systems (Silva, Reference Silva2023: 938). The incentive for the president to be ‘fair’ in portfolio allocation is consequently diminished. Moreover, presidential systems generally lack a requirement that ministers be members of the legislature. This means that nonpartisan or ‘technocratic’ ministers are quite common, and such individuals may often be awarded portfolios of high prestige and/or of great personal interest to the president (Altman, Reference Altman2000; Chaisty et al., Reference Chaisty, Cheeseman and Power2018). Finally, the president is by no means the ‘first among equals’ that is supposedly the case for prime ministers operating under collective responsibility. Rather, the president is a unipersonal executive who is directly elected in a nationwide constituency, and who individually composes and directs the cabinet, leading to an elevated level of discretion in portfolio allocation.

Semi-presidentialism is a mixed constitutional type that blends characteristics of both presidentialism and parliamentarism (Duverger, Reference Duverger1980; Schleiter and Morgan-Jones, Reference Schleiter and Morgan-Jones2009; Elgie, Reference Elgie2011). The requirement of parliamentary confidence means that the legislature is the relevant locus of coalition formation, thus enhancing the centrality of political parties. The prime minister is always important, but there is also a directly elected president with considerable constitutional powers, and whose popular legitimacy is consistent with some role in policymaking. The identity of the de facto formateur may vary. When coalitions are necessary and the president dominates the party proposing an interparty alliance for government formation, the president is likely to be the leading architect of the future government, thus elevating presidential discretion over portfolio allocation. This scenario of political alignment is closer to pure presidentialism, with its higher expectation of a ‘formateur bonus’. However, whenever the results of legislative elections require that the president appoint a prime minister from a different or even an opposition party (‘cohabitation’), the role of the president in cabinet composition is weak or nonexistent.Footnote 4 This scenario is much closer to parliamentarism, maximizing the negotiating potential of political parties and moving the system closer to a Gamsonian world. Thus, the relevance of Gamson’s Law to semi-presidentialism depends on who is the effective formateur, i.e., whether the system is ‘leaning presidential’ or ‘leaning parliamentary’. Empirically, the former scenario is far more common in the real world of semi-presidentialism.Footnote 5

Unpacking these three constitutional logics leads us to follow previous studies (e.g., Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010) and propose a rather straightforward hypothesis about the binary comparison between presidentialism and parliamentarism:

HYPOTHESIS 1: Cabinet proportionality is likely to be lower in presidential systems than in parliamentary systems.

We further expect that semi-presidential systems will stand in an intermediate position between pure presidentialism and pure parliamentarism. We note that some prior studies have assumed that the only institutional variable that really matters in shaping cabinet proportionality is the vote of no confidence, and therefore code parliamentary and semi-presidential systems (which share this feature) as belonging to a single category. Footnote 6 However, to maintain a wide theoretical lens (and also to leverage the considerable cross-system variation in a large-N dataset), we continue to distinguish among our three constitutional formats in the analyses reported below, and hence we hypothesize:

HYPOTHESIS 2: Cabinet proportionality in semi-presidential systems is likely to be lower than in parliamentary systems, but higher than in presidential systems.

Beyond constitutions: party-system and assembly-level predictors of proportionality

Key differences among presidentialism, semi-presidentialism, and parliamentarism are undoubtedly central to explaining variation in cabinet proportionality. Yet these predictors of proportionality are based entirely on intrinsic features of broad constitutional formats. Recently, a new wave of scholarship has begun to drill down below the level of the constitution to identify within-format factors that shape cabinet proportionality. For example, scholars of semi-presidentialism have identified a wide range of second-order institutional prerogatives afforded to the head of state (Kang, Reference Kang2009; Savage, Reference Savage2018; Bucur, Reference Bucur2020). These institutional levers affect the degree to which the formateur will need the cooperation of parties in parliament to pass legislation, and consequently, the degree to which the formateur will feel compelled to be fair to these parties. In parallel, scholars of presidentialism such as Silva (Reference Silva2023) have shown that cabinet proportionality is inversely related to the degree of legislative power held by presidents, which can vary immensely across presidential constitutions (Doyle and Elgie Reference Doyle and Elgie2016). These newer studies focus less on broad differences between constitutional types, and more on the ‘interior design’ of specific institutional settings.

Inspired by this newer work that looks ‘under the bonnet’, we also want to explore party-system and legislature-level predictors of cabinet proportionality, i.e., factors that vary not only across but also within constitutional formats. These factors, if correctly identified, should exert broadly similar effects on formateurs regardless of the constitutional rules under which they live. To take a simple example, party discipline exhibits cross-national variation that is independent of constitutional type. Formateurs in any system, when presented with parties with tight and predictable discipline on the floor, would see greater value in cultivating them by recruiting their representatives to the cabinet.

On the significance of party-system variables, we are influenced by Kellam’s (Reference Kellam2015: 515) recent work on presidentialism, in which she shows that particularistic parties are ‘relatively cheap coalition partners for presidents in policy terms’ and their representation in parliament makes it easier for formateurs to change the composition of their legislative coalition throughout their term of office. Conversely, programmatic parties will be motivated to capture the levers of policy that are afforded by ministerial portfolios.

Adapting Kellam’s logic, we can expect that more cohesive and programmatic party systems will force the formateur to ‘behave better’, i.e., to be more ‘fair’ in assigning cabinet posts to coalition parties on a proportional basis. We also hypothesize that formateurs will be more likely to treat parties fairly if they believe these parties can command significant support in civil society, for example by demonstrating capacity for social mobilization. Here we are inspired by the recent work of Martínez (Reference Martínez2021) on the relationship between party institutionalization and presidential interruptions in Latin America. Footnote 7 Bringing together three dimensions of party system development, we therefore hypothesize that:

HYPOTHESIS 3: Cabinet proportionality is likely to increase in line with the legislative cohesion (HYPOTHESIS 3a), programmaticity (HYPOTHESIS 3b) and institutionalization (HYPOTHESIS 3c) of party systems.

Variation in the distribution of power between executives and assemblies is also found to have an impact on cabinet proportionality in recent research. Both Bucur (Reference Bucur2020) on semi-presidentialism and Silva (Reference Silva2023) on presidentialism have highlighted the role of executive dominance over the legislature in shaping the applicability of Gamson’s Law. The less presidents need the support of parties to pass legislation, the less they will practice proportionality in portfolio allocation. While highly creative and with strong empirical results, both analyses are largely restricted to a single constitutional type or world region Footnote 8 and are difficult to test comparatively given limitations in existing measures of executive power both longitudinally and across different executive formats.

Nonetheless, we can generalize this idea with existing measures of legislative power. Assemblies with greater capacity to monitor and sanction the behavior of the executive would be expected to raise the probability that formateurs will practice proportionality in the composition of cabinets. In line with existing research (e.g., Martínez-Gallardo, Reference Martínez-Gallardo2012; Camerlo and Pérez-Liñán, Reference Camerlo and Pérez-Liñán2015), we would expect formateurs to be more likely to distribute cabinet seats proportionally if the advice and consent of the assembly are required for the investiture of ministers. Footnote 9 Also, the more the power base of the chief executive is determined by the confidence of the legislature, the more we should expect formateurs to compose their cabinets on a fair and proportional basis. Hence, taking together three aspects of legislative influence over politics, we hypothesize that:

HYPOTHESIS 4: Cabinet proportionality is likely to increase in line with the assembly’s powers of executive oversight (HYPOTHESIS 4a) and ministerial confirmation (HYPOTHESIS 4b) and also with the degree to which the executive’s power base is determined by legislative confidence (HYPOTHESIS 4c).

We therefore have identified at least six different party-system and assembly-level variables that might affect the portability of Gamson’s Law across broad constitutional formats. These include party-system characteristics such as party programmaticity, party cohesion on the floor, and the institutionalization of parties in society. They also include variables shaping the executive-legislative relationship such as the power of the assembly to oversee and constrain the executive; the assembly’s power to confirm ministerial appointments by the head of state; and a measure for the extent to which the political standing of the executive rests on legislative support. Party-system and assembly-level predictors of cabinet proportionality can only be captured in a large-N design that covers all three main constitutional types.

Data and results

To estimate the extent to which different executive formats affect cabinet proportionality and why, we analyze cabinet composition data compiled by WhoGov (Nyrup and Bramwell, Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020). The WhoGov dataset contains over 8,000 country-years of information on cabinet members across 177 countries for the period 1966 to 2019. We augment this dataset with legislative seat shares of cabinet-represented parties. Footnote 10

We confine our analysis to competitive polities, which we define broadly as political systems with a positive score (1–10) on the Polity IV scale. Footnote 11 Given our research question, we also limit the analysis to governments formed by cross-party coalitions. The exclusion of single-party cabinets removes approximately one-third of the cases of competitive polities from the WhoGov dataset. Furthermore, we dropped cases of coalitions that had incomplete cabinet party data. This amounts to approximately 400 cases. We include these data for robustness checks only. We are left with a final sample of 1551 country-years of competitive politics in 97 countries in the period from 1966 to 2019. Table 1 lists the countries covered by the analysis.

Table 1 Sample summary of cases by region and country, 1966–2019

Table 2 classifies our cases by constitutional format. Parliamentary country-years comprise the largest percentage of this sample: 45% of all observations, compared to 31% in the semi-presidential category and 24% in pure presidentialism. Consistent with theoretical expectations about prime ministers in parliamentary systems, these data show that parliamentary coalitions tend to include more parties than is the case in either semi-presidential or presidential regimes—suggesting greater limitation of the formateur’s discretion in parliamentary systems. While the relative share of two-party coalitions is similar across all constitutional formats, coalitions of three or more parties are preponderant in parliamentary systems.

Table 2 Frequencies of party coalitions across different executive formats (percentages in parentheses)

These data form the focus of our analysis, which proceeds in two stages. First, we estimate the extent to which cabinet proportionality is achieved across the broad constitutional formats. This entails the analysis of a Gamsonian measure of fairness ranging from zero to one: it measures the extent to which the formateur distributes cabinet portfolios among coalition parties proportionally to their seat shares within the coalition’s legislative contingent. Footnote 12 We also estimate whether the formateur is compelled to share prestigious cabinet posts by calculating the degree to which the formateur’s party or nonpartisans are underrepresented relative to the share of seats held by the formateur’s party within the legislature. Data for these highly salient posts are taken from WhoGov, which uses Krook and O’Brien’s (Reference Krook and O’Brien2012) typology of four policy areas assumed to enjoy universal prestige. The names of the ministerial portfolios naturally vary across countries, but the four easily recognizable categories are: (1) Defence/Military/National Security; (2) Foreign Relations; (3) Interior/Home Affairs; and (4) Finance/Budget/Treasury. Footnote 13

In the second stage of our study, we seek to account for the observed variation within each executive format using our party-system and assembly-level predictors. This involves analysis of party-level and institutional (legislature-specific) factors that feature in system-level studies of cabinet composition. To estimate their effects on cabinet proportionality, we consider a range of V-Dem variables. They include party-system covariates that measure the magnitude of programmatic partisan cohesion, Footnote 14 linkages with voters, Footnote 15 and the institutionalization of parties in terms of the wider society. Footnote 16 They also include legislative factors that affect executive power: the power of the assembly to oversee and constrain the executive; Footnote 17 the assembly’s power to confirm ministerial appointments by the head of state; Footnote 18 and a measure for the extent to which the political authority of the executive rests on the support of the legislature. Footnote 19

Cross-format results

We begin with a simple visual inspection of the data, comparing observed cabinet allocations in presidentialism, parliamentarism, and semi-presidentialism to the relationship posited by Gamson’s Law. Gamsonian proportionality is represented by the diagonal line in each of the three panels in Fig. 1, which shows the relationship between the share of cabinet posts held by the formateur’s party and the share of coalition seats controlled by this party across our three broad constitutional formats.Footnote 20 The panels provide strong visual support for HYPOTHESIS 1 (cabinet proportionality should be lower in presidential systems than in parliamentary systems) and HYPOTHESIS 2 (proportionality in semi-presidential systems should be lower than in parliamentary systems but higher than in presidential systems). As can be seen in panel (a) of Fig. 1, country-year observations in parliamentary systems behave largely according to expectation and are arrayed close to the Gamsonian line, with a linear association of 0.742; semi-presidential observations (panel b) exhibit greater dispersion with a correlation between seat shares and cabinet shares of 0.618; meanwhile, pure presidential observations (panel c) are more scattered with a coefficient of 0.598. Footnote 21 Globally, the linear association for parliamentary systems (0.742) is much lower than one finds in the large body of research on postwar European parliamentary systems.

Figure 1. Formateur portfolio shares in three constitutional formats vs Gamsonian line.

Notes: Total N = 1551. Correlation for parliamentary systems only: r = 0.742, N = 697. Correlation for semi-presidential systems only: r = 0.618, N = 478. Correlation for presidential systems only: r = 0.598, N = 376. All associations significant at p < 0.01. Diagonal line represents perfect Gamsonian proportionality (r = 1.00).

The exceptional levels of disproportionality in presidential systems are also illustrated by the greater proportion of country-year cases above the Gamsonian line. Observations above the line indicate the relative size of the formateur bonus: here, the proportion of cabinet posts awarded to the formateur party exceeds its contribution to coalition seats on the floor. The results provide clear support for HYPOTHESIS 1 and HYPOTHESIS 2. In panel (a), observations above the line are 35.7% for parliamentarism, in panel (b) 43.7% for semi-presidentialism, and an astounding 82.4% for pure presidentialism (panel c). Presidential formateurs are thus more than twice as likely as prime ministers to exaggerate their party’s share of the cabinet.

As can be seen in Table 3, our inclusion of parliamentary systems in transitional and developing democracies outside of Europe results in much weaker correlations, which are nonsignificant in some regional clusters. Moreover, the result for parliamentary systems in Europe is lower than typically assumed (it is 0.90 or higher in many post-Browne and Franklin studies), and this may also be a consequence of the eastward expansion of political democracy since the 1990s.

Table 3 Pearson correlations of the formateur’s share of cabinet posts and coalition seats, parliamentary systems only, by world region

** Correlation is significant at the 0.001 level (two-tailed).

Nonetheless, despite this complexity, basic constitutional differences are still key to understanding the extent of cabinet proportionality. Figure 2 summarizes the average size of cabinet proportionality across all executive formats. In contrast with Fig. 1, which reports data for formateur parties only, these data summarize mean cabinet proportionality for all parties in the coalition.Footnote 22 In line with HYPOTHESIS 1, these results once again depict the strong formateur advantage under the separation of powers. Whereas formateurs in parliamentary and semi-presidential systems are more likely to assign cabinet positions in proportion to the legislative support commanded by their coalition partners, this declines significantly in pure presidentialism. The pairwise comparison of means between presidential cases and the other executive formats is much stronger than between parliamentary and semi-presidential systems (see note in Fig. 2).

Figure 2. Mean cabinet proportionality estimates by executive format.

Note: Pairwise comparisons of means with equal variances: semi-presidential vs parliamentary (contrast −0.062; st. error 0.010; p = 0.000), presidential vs parliamentary (contrast −0.226; st. error 0.011; p = 0.000); presidential vs semi-presidential (contrast −0.164; st. error; p = 0.000).

Similarly, co-partisans of the formateur in presidential systems are much more likely to be overrepresented in prestigious cabinet posts relative to their presence in the assembly (Fig. 3). Once again, the most significant pairwise comparisons are between presidentialism and the other two constitutional types.

Figure 3. Mean representation of formateur contingents in the most prestigious cabinet posts, by executive format.

Notes: These data summarize mean differences between the share of cabinet and legislative seats held by the formateur in each constitutional format. Positive and negative mean values indicate overrepresentation and underrepresentation of the formateur in prestigious cabinet posts. Pairwise comparisons of means with equal variances: semi-presidential vs parliamentary (contrast 0.020; st. error 0.016; p = 0.426), presidential vs parliamentary (contrast 0.147; st. error 0.017; p = 0.000); presidential vs semi-presidential (contrast 0.127; st. error 0.018; p = 0.000).

Why are the constraints on the formateur bonus significantly weaker in presidential systems? Is this only because of intrinsic constitutional features or can it result from other aspects of institutional design? We now proceed to the within-format analysis of the party-system and legislative factors that are theorized to account for variance in Gamson’s Law in constitution-specific studies. What is the relative significance of party-system characteristics and legislative influence?

Within-format results

In this analysis, we first estimate the effects of party and assembly-level predictors in simple bivariate models, and then include the most salient predictor for within-system variation—party-system institutionalization—in multivariate analysis, while controlling for world region and level of political democracy. The panel data used in this analysis present some common challenges. Our dataset is unbalanced due to attrition and missing data and is affected by the problem of autocorrelation, i.e., repeated observations for the same countries that are likely to be positively correlated and thus not independent of each other. To correct these problems, we estimate each model using Generalised Estimating Equations (Ghisletta and Spini, Reference Ghisletta and Spini2004). This statistical method is designed to correct unbalanced panel data and autocorrelation, producing more efficient estimates. We also include robust standard errors to mitigate sensitivity to the correlation structure.

Key results of the analysis are presented visually in Fig. 4. They summarize the average marginal effect of each party-system and assembly-level predictor on our measurements of cabinet proportionality for each broad constitutional format. Footnote 23 Values for variables to the left of the vertical line indicate depressing effects on cabinet fairness, while values to the right are indicative of effects increasing cabinet proportionality. Confidence intervals represented by horizontal lines either side of the point estimate indicate nonsignificance when they overlap the vertical line.

Figure 4. Party-system and assembly-level variables shaping cabinet proportionality (with 95% confidence intervals).

Source: drawn from V-Dem (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022) and authors’ dataset building on Nyrup and Bramwell (Reference Nyrup and Bramwell2020); see text for details.

In general, the results for parliamentary and semi-presidential systems support all variants of HYPOTHESIS 3, namely, that cabinet proportionality is likely to increase in line with the floor-level cohesion (HYPOTHESIS 3a), tendency toward programmaticity (HYPOTHESIS 3b) and overall institutionalization (HYPOTHESIS 3c) of party systems. They show that party-system institutionalization in particular is far more significant in explaining proportionality in parliamentary and semi-presidential systems than in presidential polities.

In Fig. 4, positive values for the marginal effects of party predictors on cabinet proportionality in parliamentary and semi-presidential systems indicate the extent to which they contribute towards Gamsonian ‘fairness.’ This is especially evident for the party-system institutionalization variable. A one-unit increase in party-system institutionalization increases cabinet representativeness by 35 percentage points in parliamentary systems, and by 39 percentage points in semi-presidential systems. A one-unit increase in voting cohesion on the assembly floor also raises the representativeness of cabinets by 14 percentage points in semi-presidential systems and by 9 percentage points in parliamentary systems. Similarly, programmatic parties are significantly more likely to improve the representativeness of cabinets, with a one-unit increase in programmaticity increasing cabinet fairness by 6 percentage points in parliamentarism.

However, no version of our HYPOTHESIS 3 finds support among presidential systems: the average marginal effects of our party-system covariates are either small or nonexistent. The negative results for party cohesiveness, programmaticity and institutionalization in Fig. 4 suggest that these predictors might actually decrease the proportionality of cabinets in pure presidentialism, although these results are not statistically significant.

Assembly-level predictors are less consistently significant. Levels of oversight capacity have a significant impact in raising the proportionality of cabinets in semi-presidential systems only. A one-unit increase in oversight increases Gamsonian proportionality by 35 percentage points. And, in parliamentary systems, proportionality increases in line with the power of assemblies to confirm ministerial appointments.

These findings are robust to alternative specifications including incomplete party data. Footnote 24 We also re-estimated our models with a thinned dataset that includes only ‘consolidated’ democracies—i.e., country-years classified by Polity at point 6 and higher—and observe the same general patterns.

Finally, multivariate tests (see Table 4) confirm the positive effect of party-system institutionalization on cabinet proportionality, but in parliamentary systems only. Even when controlling for regional variation and levels of democratic development in parliamentary systems, party institutionalization is strongly significant in differentiating levels of cabinet proportionality. Interestingly, however, the effect of party institutionalization is vacated in semi-presidential systems. This appears to be largely a consequence of the inclusion of regional controls, which capture weaker party-system development in many regions outside of Europe. This result reaffirms the limited geographic portability of Gamson’s Law, with semi-presidential cabinets in Asia and the former Soviet Union significantly less likely to be representative of coalition parties in the legislature than is the case for European semi-presidential systems.

Table 4 Multivariate regressions of cabinet proportionality on party-system institutionalization, by constitutional format (generalised estimating equations with robust standard errors)

Notes:

a Excluded reference category is Europe; other minor exclusions explained in note (b).

b Not applicable. Regions are excluded when there are no cases or no variation at the country level (e.g., just one country was classified as parliamentary in the Americas regional category: Trinidad and Tobago).

Significance levels:

* P < 0.05;

** P < 0.01;

*** P < 0.001.

Conclusion

We advanced the debate on Gamson’s Law by taking it far afield from its Western European origins and examining it within a large sample of political systems from around the world, inspected annually between 1966 and 2019. We further advanced the debate by making a distinction between first-order constitutional drivers of the ‘law’ (i.e., broad executive formats) and some plausible within-system predictors: party-system characteristics and prerogatives of the assembly.

We found that pure presidentialism offers the fewest constraints on formateurs and is the least Gamsonian of constitutional formats. We also found evidence that while the two alternatives to presidentialism—parliamentary and semi-presidential systems—are closer in many respects, they are still different from each other in terms of cabinet proportionality. This questions the approach of previous studies that have collapsed the two categories when studying the formateur bonus in cabinet portfolio allocation. Ariotti and Golder (Reference Ariotti and Golder2018) suggest that the driver of ‘fairness’ in portfolio distribution may be traced to the simple fact that parliamentarism and semi-presidentialism possess the vote of no confidence (meaning that parties can bring down the government) whereas presidentialism does not. Our findings suggest that this constitutional feature cannot entirely explain the differences in levels of cabinet proportionality between the two systems.

Yet the above observations are directed mainly at intrinsic constitutional predictors of cabinet proportionality. Among the party-system and assembly-level predictors that we consider, our analysis suggests that for parliamentary regimes, party-system institutionalization is a promising and consistent predictor of cabinet proportionality. More institutionalized party systems appear to deter formateur advantage across parliamentary systems. This makes intuitive sense. In institutionalized party systems, the leading parties are more likely to be cohesive and disciplined, meaning that they are valuable potential allies for prime ministers; but for the same reasons, these parties are well positioned to defend their interests in initial negotiations with the formateur. However, in semi-presidential systems, this effect appears to be regionally specific. When we control for regional differentiation, the effect of party institutionalization loses statistical significance.

We also find that the structural distinctiveness of presidentialism appears to undermine or even neutralize the bargaining capacity of institutionalized parties: presidentialism is consistently associated with an exaggerated form of formateur bonus. The knock-on effects of the ‘separate origin and survival’ of the executive and legislature under presidentialism, originally posited by Shugart and Carey (Reference Shugart and Carey1992), is a point also stressed in new work by Silva (Reference Silva2023) on formateur advantage under the separation of powers.

While we have not addressed the point at length here, we observe that a major defect in the literature on Gamson’s Law has been its inability to contend with variation in portfolio salience (Warwick and Druckman Reference Warwick and Druckman2001, Reference Warwick and Druckman2006). Although some solutions have recently been proposed (e.g., Bucur, Reference Bucur2018; Zucco et al., Reference Zucco, Batista and Power2019), we need much more work on this topic. Few scholars are likely to accept that all portfolios are of equal value (e.g., the Ministry of Sports is not equivalent to the Ministry of Finance), and therefore it is quite possible that formateurs can ‘game the system’ by composing cabinets that exhibit quantitative proportionality while enshrining qualitative disproportionality in the actual value of portfolios. We are still very far from producing a cross-national dataset that assigns comparable values of portfolio worth across time and space. Nonetheless, here we followed WhoGov in making a simple assumption about the privileged status of four portfolio types, and we were able to compile data on 1551 country years to determine what share of these ‘prestige posts’ are withheld by the formateur. We find early evidence that formateurs in pure presidentialism are far more likely to reserve the most prestigious cabinet posts for their co-partisans than are formateurs in either parliamentary or semi-presidential systems. In other words, we observe that the formateur advantage in presidential systems is not only quantitative but also qualitative.

Finally, we have found rather strong evidence that Gamson’s Law is not globally portable. What has been described as ‘the strongest empirical finding in political science’ appears to be an artifact of parliamentary democracy, particularly of European parliamentary democracy. Where parliamentarism exists outside of Europe (e.g., in Asia, Oceania, and Israel, accounting for a third of our parliamentary country-years) there is evidence of Gamsonian behavior by formateurs, but with less commitment to proportionality than the traditional Western European literature suggested. Thus, further research on Gamson’s Law should invest not only in the theoretical models that have dominated much of the recent literature but also in empirical work that uncovers nonconstitutional predictors of cabinet proportionality across institutional designs.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773924000067.

Footnotes

1 We are grateful to Daniel Barker Flores for assistance in assembling this dataset.

2 Early in more ways than one: Gamson was 26 when he wrote this paper.

3 The norm hypothesis might be the most accurate translation of what Gamson really wrote in 1961. His proposition was not about proportional outcomes per se, but about the starting assumptions made by players about the likely behavior of others: ‘Any participant will expect others to demand from a coalition a share of the payoff proportional to the amount of resources which they contribute to a coalition’ (italics added).

4 Duverger (Reference Duverger1980) famously claimed that semi-presidential systems will tend to mimic either presidential or parliamentary government depending on whether the dual executive (president and prime minister) is controlled by the same party. Writing six years before the first ‘cohabitation’ in France, Duverger expected semi-presidential systems to exhibit ‘alternation’ between presidential and parliamentary phases. Sartori (Reference Sartori1994: 24) agrees, but prefers the term ‘oscillation’.

5 For example, Elgie and McMenamin (Reference Elgie and McMenamin2011) examined 218 electoral periods in 39 semi-presidential countries between 1989 and 2008. They found that cohabitation existed in only 43 of these 218 periods (20% of the sample).

6 See, for example, Ariotti and Golder (Reference Ariotti and Golder2018) on cabinet proportionality in African democracies.

7 Martínez (Reference Martínez2021) posits a curvilinear relationship between party institutionalization and the risk of presidential failure. That is, when parties are weakly or highly institutionalized, the hazard of presidential failure is lower than when parties exhibit intermediate levels of institutionalization. Our adaptation of this idea is exploratory, attempting only to detect any positive relationship between party institutionalization and cabinet proportionality.

8 Interestingly, Bucur’s findings on contemporary European presidential heads of state find parallels in a historical paper by Akirav and Cox (Reference Akirav and Cox2018) on the cabinet-facing role played by the head of state in early constitutional monarchies. Silva (Reference Silva2023) provides strong evidence that in pure presidentialism, the size of the formateur bonus is directly related to what Shugart and Carey (Reference Shugart and Carey1992) called ‘constitutional powers’ of the president.

9 We are grateful to Patricio Navia for suggesting this approach.

10 Following WhoGov, we use cabinet configuration as of the month of July in each year and we code the formateur in the same month.

11 This ranges from ‘open anocracies’—countries that are neither fully democratic nor fully autocratic, but are closer to democracies on all components measured by Polity—to consolidated democracies (Marshall and Cole Reference Marshall and Cole2014: 21).

12 In the presidentialism literature, this measure is often termed ‘cabinet coalescence’, a synonym for Gamsonian proportionality. See for example Amorim Neto (Reference Amorim Neto, Morgenstern and Nacif2002); Chaisty et al. (Reference Chaisty, Cheeseman and Power2018).

13 The variable does not range from 0 to 4 in all cases. In some country-years, there were fewer than four of these positions in existence, and in some cases, there were more than four, for example when a prestige policy area had two different representatives in the cabinet (e.g., separate ministers of Finance and Budget).

14 V-Dem asks ‘Is it normal for members of the legislature to vote with other members of their party on important bills?’ 0: Not really. 1: More often than not. 2: Mostly. 3: Yes, absolutely. (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022: 96).

15 The specific V-Dem question asked: ‘Among the major parties, what is the main or most common form of linkage to their constituents?’ Responses: 0: Clientelistic; 1: Mixed clientelistic and local collective; 2: Local collective; 3: Mixed local collective and policy/programmatic; 4: Policy/programmatic. (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022: 94–95).

16 V-Dem asks ‘To what extent are political parties institutionalized? Party institutionalization refers to various attributes of the political parties in a country, e.g., level and depth of organization, links to civil society, cadres of party activists, party supporters within the electorate, coherence of party platforms and ideologies, party-line voting among representatives within the legislature. A high score on these attributes generally indicates a more institutionalized party system’. The variable is ordered by five categories. (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022: 349).

17 V-Dem asks ‘To what extent are the legislature and government agencies e.g., comptroller general, general prosecutor, or ombudsman capable of questioning, investigating, and exercising oversight over the executive?’ The variable is ordered by three categories in the direction of greater oversight capacity (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022: 349).

18 V-Dem asks ‘In practice, does the head of state have the power to appoint – or is the approval of the head of state necessary for the appointment of – cabinet ministers?’ We recode this as a binary variable, coding as 1 responses that require the approval of the assembly (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022: 121).

19 V-Dem asks: ‘To what extent is the power base of the chief executive determined by the confidence of the legislature?’ (Coppedge et al., Reference Coppedge, Gerring, Knutsen, Lindberg, Teorell, Altman, Bernhard, Cornell, Fish, Gastaldi, Gjerløw, Glynn, Grahn, Hicken, Kinzelbach, Marquardt, McMann, Mechkova, Paxton, Pemstein, von Römer, Seim, Sigman, Skaaning, Staton, Tzelgov, Uberti, Wang, Wig and Ziblatt2022: 292). This is coded in the direction of greater legislative confidence powers.

20 We code the prime minister’s party as the formateur party in parliamentary systems and the president’s party as the formateur party in presidential systems. In semi-presidential systems, the largest party is coded as the formateur party; the exceptions are when the largest party is unable to form (e.g., Finland 1987) or sustain (e.g., Lithuania 2001) a governing coalition, and when constitutional ‘president-parliamentary’ rules give presidents the upper hand in government formation (e.g., Iceland, São Tomé e Príncipe [1990–2002], Ukraine [1996–2006]).

21 This chart includes nonpartisan formateurs, represented by zero values.

22 For a full description of the method used to calculate cabinet proportionality, see Amorim Neto (Reference Amorim Neto, Morgenstern and Nacif2002).

23 The full models are presented in Table A1 in the online appendix.

24 Incomplete cases typically encountered one party for which seat-share data was unavailable. Measurements could be calculated but not with the same level of accuracy, hence their exclusion from the analysis.

References

Akirav, Osnat, and Cox, Gary. “The Formateur’s Bonus in European Constitutional Monarchies, 1901–99.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 48 (2018): 681703.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altman, David.The Politics of Coalition Formation and Survival in Multiparty Presidential Democracies: The Case of Uruguay, 1989–1999.” Party Politics 6 (2000): 259–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amorim Neto, Octavio. “Presidential Cabinets, Electoral Cycles, and Coalition Discipline in Brazil.” In Legislative Politics in Latin America, edited by Morgenstern, Scott and Nacif, Benito. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2002, pp. 4878.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amorim Neto, Octavio, and Samuels, David. “Democratic Regimes and Cabinet Politics: A Global Perspective.” Revista Ibero-Americana de Estudos Legislativos 1 (2010): 1023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, Snyder, James M., Strauss, Aaron B., and Ting, Michael M.. “Voting Weights and Formateur Advantages in the Formation of Coalition Governments.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (2005): 550–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariotti, Margaret, and Golder, Sona. “Partisan Portfolio Allocation in African Democracies.” Comparative Political Studies 51 (2018): 341–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, Hanna, Meier, Henk Erik, and Persson, Thomas. “Party Size and Portfolio Payoffs: the Proportional Allocation of Ministerial Posts in Coalition Governments.” Journal of Legislative Studies 15 (2009): 1034.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P., and Ferejohn, John A.. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83 (1989): 1181–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertholini, Frederico, and Pereira, Carlos. “Pagando o preço de governar: custos de gerência de coalizão no presidencialismo brasileiro.” Revista de Administração Pública 51 (2017): 528–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browne, Eric, and Franklin, Mark. “Aspects of Coalition Payoffs in European Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 67 (1973): 453–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bucur, Cristina.Cabinet Payoffs in Coalition Governments: A Time-Varying Measure of Portfolio Importance.” Party Politics 24 (2018): 154–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bucur, Cristina.Presidents and Cabinet Payoffs in Coalition Governments.” Political Studies Review 18 (2020): 3052.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerlo, Marcelo, and Pérez-Liñán, Aníbal. “The Politics of Minister Retention in Presidential Systems: technocrats, Partisans, and Government Approval.” Comparative Politics 47 (2015): 315–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaisty, Paul, Cheeseman, Nic, and Power, Timothy J.. Coalitional Presidentialism in Comparative Perspective: Minority Presidents in Multiparty Systems. Oxford: Oxford UP, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppedge, Michael, Gerring, John, Knutsen, Carl Henrik, Lindberg, Staffan I., Teorell, Jan, Altman, David, Bernhard, Michael, Cornell, Agnes, Fish, M. Steven, Gastaldi, Lisa, Gjerløw, Haakon, Glynn, Adam, Grahn, Sandra, Hicken, Allen, Kinzelbach, Katrin, Marquardt, Kyle L., McMann, Kelly, Mechkova, Valeriya, Paxton, Pamela, Pemstein, Daniel, von Römer, Johannes, Seim, Brigitte, Sigman, Rachel, Skaaning, Svend-Erik, Staton, Jeffrey, Tzelgov, Eitan, Uberti, Luca, Wang, Yi-ting, Wig, Tore, and Ziblatt, Daniel. 2022. V-Dem Codebook v12. University of Gothenburg: Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W.Nonunitary Parties, Government Formation, and Gamson’s Law.” American Political Science Review 115 (2021): 917–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cutler, Josh, de Marchi, Scott, Gallop, Max, Hollenbach, Florian M., Laver, Michael, and Orlowski, Matthias. “Cabinet Formation and Portfolio Distribution in European Multiparty Systems.” British Journal of Political Science 46 (2016): 3143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, David, and Elgie, Robert. “Maximizing the Reliability of Cross-National Measures of Presidential Power.” British Journal of Political Science 46 (2016): 731–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duverger, Maurice.A New Political System Model: semi-Presidential Government.” European Journal of Political Research 8 (1980): 165–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ecker, Alejandro. and Meyer, Thomas M.. “Fairness and Qualitative Portfolio Allocation in Multiparty Governments.” Public Choice 181 (2019): 309–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elgie, Robert. Semi-Presidentialism: Sub-Types And Democratic Performance. Oxford: Oxford UP, 2011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elgie, Robert, and McMenamin, Iain. “Explaining the Onset of Cohabitation under Semi-Presidentialism.” Political Studies 59 (2011): 616–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falcó-Gimeno, Albert, and Indridason, Indridi H.. “Uncertainty, Complexity, and Gamson’s Law: comparing Coalition Formation in Western Europe.” West European Politics 36 (2013): 221–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gamson, William A.A Theory of Coalition Formation.” American Sociological Review 26 (1961): 373–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghisletta, Paolo, and Spini, Dario. “An Introduction to Generalized Estimating Equations and an Application to Assess Selectivity Effects in a Longitudinal Study on Very Old Individuals.” Journal of Educational and Behavioral Statistics 29 (2004): 421–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Indridason, Indridi H. “Live for Today, Hope for Tomorrow? Rethinking Gamson’s Law.” Unpublished manuscript (2015). <https://indridason.politicaldata.org>..>Google Scholar
Kang, Shin-Goo.The Influence of Presidential Heads of State on Government Formation in European Democracies: empirical Evidence.” European Journal of Political Research 48 (2009): 543–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kellam, Marisa.Parties for Hire: How Particularistic Parties Influence Presidents’ Governing Strategies.” Party Politics 21 (2015): 515–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krook, Mona Lena, and O’Brien, Diana Z.. 2012. “All the President’s Men? The Appointment of Female Cabinet Ministers Worldwide.” Journal of Politics 74 (2012): 840–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries, 2nd ed. New Haven, CT: Yale UP, 2012.Google Scholar
Linz, Juan J.Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: Does It Make a Difference?” In The Failure of Presidential Democracy: The Case of Latin America, edited by Juan, J. Linz and Valenzuela, Arturo. Baltimore, MA: Johns Hopkins UP, 1994, pp. 387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Monty G., and Cole, Benjamin R.. Global Report 2014: Conflict, Governance, and State Fragility. Vienna, VA: Center for Systemic Peace, 2014. <www.systemicpeace.org>.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny W., and Vanberg, Georg. “What You See Is Not Always What You Get: Bargaining before an Audience under Multiparty Government.” American Political Science Review 114 (2020): 1138–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez, Christopher A.Presidential Instability in Latin America: Why Institutionalized Parties Matter.” Government and Opposition 56 (2021): 683704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez-Gallardo, Cecilia.Out of the Cabinet: What Drives Defections from the Government in Presidential Systems?Comparative Political Studies 45 (2012): 6290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mejía Acosta, Andrés. Informal Coalitions and Policymaking in Latin America: Ecuador in Comparative Perspective. London: Routledge, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyrup, Jacob, and Bramwell, Stuart. “Who Governs? A New Global Dataset on Members of Cabinets.” American Political Science Review 114 (2020): 1366–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raile, Eric, Pereira, Carlos, and Power, Timothy J.. “Presidentialism, Coalitions, and Accountability.” In Corruption and Democracy in Brazil: The Struggle for Accountability, edited by Timothy, J. Power and Matthew, M. Taylor. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame P, 2011, pp. 3155.Google Scholar
Samuels, David, and Shugart, Matthew Soberg. Presidents, Parties, and Prime Ministers: How the Separation of Powers Affects Party Organization and Behavior. New York: Cambridge UP, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. Comparative Constitutional Engineering: An Inquiry into Structures, Incentives and Outcomes. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 1994.Google Scholar
Savage, Lee.How and When Do Presidents Influence the Duration of Coalition Bargaining in Semi-Presidential Systems?European Journal of Political Research 57 (2018): 308–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schleiter, Petra, and Morgan-Jones, Edward. “Citizens, Presidents and Assemblies: The Study of Semi-Presidentialism beyond Duverger and Linz.” British Journal of Political Science 39. (2009): 871–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman, and Laver, Michael. 1985. “Bargaining Theory and Portfolio Payoffs in European Coalition Governments 1945–83.” British Journal of Political Science 15 (1985): 143–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, Matthew Soberg, and Carey, John M.. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York: Cambridge UP, 1992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silva, Thiago N.When Do Different Systems of Government Lead to Similar Power-Sharing? The Case of Government Formation.” Political Science Research and Methods 11 (2023): 938–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warwick, Paul V., and Druckman, James. “Portfolio Salience and the Proportionality of Payoffs in Coalition Governments.” British Journal of Political Science 31 (2001): 627–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warwick, Paul V., and Druckman, James. “The Portfolio Allocation Paradox: an Investigation into the Nature of a Very Strong but Puzzling Relationship.” European Journal of Political Research 45 (2006): 635–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zucco, Cesar, Batista, Mariana, and Power, Timothy J.. “Measuring Portfolio Salience Using the Bradley-Terry Model: an Illustration with Data from Brazil.” Research & Politics 6 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1177/2053168019832089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Sample summary of cases by region and country, 1966–2019

Figure 1

Table 2 Frequencies of party coalitions across different executive formats (percentages in parentheses)

Figure 2

Figure 1. Formateur portfolio shares in three constitutional formats vs Gamsonian line.Notes: Total N = 1551. Correlation for parliamentary systems only: r = 0.742, N = 697. Correlation for semi-presidential systems only: r = 0.618, N = 478. Correlation for presidential systems only: r = 0.598, N = 376. All associations significant at p < 0.01. Diagonal line represents perfect Gamsonian proportionality (r = 1.00).

Figure 3

Table 3 Pearson correlations of the formateur’s share of cabinet posts and coalition seats, parliamentary systems only, by world region

Figure 4

Figure 2. Mean cabinet proportionality estimates by executive format.Note: Pairwise comparisons of means with equal variances: semi-presidential vs parliamentary (contrast −0.062; st. error 0.010; p = 0.000), presidential vs parliamentary (contrast −0.226; st. error 0.011; p = 0.000); presidential vs semi-presidential (contrast −0.164; st. error; p = 0.000).

Figure 5

Figure 3. Mean representation of formateur contingents in the most prestigious cabinet posts, by executive format.Notes: These data summarize mean differences between the share of cabinet and legislative seats held by the formateur in each constitutional format. Positive and negative mean values indicate overrepresentation and underrepresentation of the formateur in prestigious cabinet posts. Pairwise comparisons of means with equal variances: semi-presidential vs parliamentary (contrast 0.020; st. error 0.016; p = 0.426), presidential vs parliamentary (contrast 0.147; st. error 0.017; p = 0.000); presidential vs semi-presidential (contrast 0.127; st. error 0.018; p = 0.000).

Figure 6

Figure 4. Party-system and assembly-level variables shaping cabinet proportionality (with 95% confidence intervals).Source: drawn from V-Dem (Coppedge et al., 2022) and authors’ dataset building on Nyrup and Bramwell (2020); see text for details.

Figure 7

Table 4 Multivariate regressions of cabinet proportionality on party-system institutionalization, by constitutional format (generalised estimating equations with robust standard errors)

Supplementary material: File

Chaisty and Power supplementary material

Chaisty and Power supplementary material
Download Chaisty and Power supplementary material(File)
File 14.3 KB