Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-05T21:14:55.528Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why is there a Home Bias? A Case Study of Wine*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 June 2012

Richard Friberg
Affiliation:
Stockholm School of Economics and CEPR, Stockholm School of Economics, PO Box 6501, SE-113 83 Stockholm,Sweden, email: nerf@hhs.se (corresponding author).
Robert W. Paterson
Affiliation:
Industrial Economics Inc., 2067 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02140–1337. email: (rwp@indecon.com)
Andrew D. Richardson
Affiliation:
Department of Organismic and Evolutionary Biology, Harvard University, 22 Divinity Avenue Cambridge MA 02138. email: arichardson@oeb.harvard.edu

Abstract

Domestic products have a disproportionately high market share on many goods markets. We examine the contribution of preferences to such “home bias”, using detailed data on wine sales in New Hampshire (weekly sales by brand by store for one year). In counterfactual simulations, where we use the same set of products as currently available, the U.S. market share falls from 58 percent to 38 percent if all country-of-origin effects are set equal. Home bias on this market is not explained by higher marginal costs for imports or by lesser store coverage of imported brands. The evidence rather points to higher foreign fixed costs of entry, coupled with a preference for U.S. wines, as the main sources for the high domestic market share. (JEL Classification: F12, F14, L13, L66)

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Association of Wine Economists 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aghion, P. and Bolton, P. (1987). Contracts as a barrier to entry. American Economic Review, 77, 388400.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., McFadden, D. L., Smith, V. L., Boudreaux, D. J., Hahn, R. W., Letiche, J. M. and Litan, R. E. (2004). Regulation of interstate wine shipments. AEI-Brookings joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Brief 04–02.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, J. E. and van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93, 170192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, J. E. and van Wincoop, E. (2004). Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature, 42, 691751.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashenfelter, O. A., Ciccarella, S. and Shatz, H. J. (2007). French wine and the U.S. boycott of 2003: Does politics really affect commerce? Journal of Wine Economics, 2, 5574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bajari, P. and Benkard, C. L. (2005). Demand estimation with heterogenous consumers and unobserved product characteristics: A hedonic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 12391276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, S. (1994). Estimating discrete-choice models of product differentiation. RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 242262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, S., Levinsohn, J. and Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63, 841890.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besedes, T. and Prusa, T. J. (2006). Product differentiation and duration of U.S. import trade. Journal of International Economics, 70, 339358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, P. N., Gundlach, G. T. and Cannon, J. P. (2000). Slotting allowances and fees: Schools of thought and the views of practicing managers. Journal of Marketing, 64, 92108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. (1998). Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 75111.Google Scholar
Broda, C. and Weinstein, D. E. (2006). Globalization and the gains from variety. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 541585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, E. L. (2003). Products and prejudice: Measuring country-of-origin bias in U.S. wine imports. UC Santa Cruz Center for International Economics, Working Paper No. 03–10.Google Scholar
Broude, T. (2005). Taking ‘Trade and Culture’ seriously: Geographical indications and cultural protection in WTO law. BEpress Legal Series Paper 649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruno, H. A. and Vilcassim, N. J. (2008). Structural demand estimation with varying product availability. Management Science, 27, 11261131.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. R. and Lapham, B. (2004). Real exchange rate fluctuations and the dynamics of retail trade industries on the U.S.-Canada border. American Economic Review, 94, 11941206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chavis, L. and Leslie, P. (2009). Consumer boycotts: The impact of the Iraq war on French wine sales in the U.S. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 7, 3767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, C. and Song, M. (2008). Preference for cultural goods: The case of Korea film market. Manuscript, Georgia Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Combris, P., Lecocq, S. and Visser, M. (1997). Estimation of a hedonic price equation for Bordeaux wine: Does quality matter?. The Economic Journal, 107, 390402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conlon, C. and Mortimer, J. (2009). Demand estimation under incomplete product availability. Manuscript, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Cook, P. J. and Moore, M. J. (2000). Alcohol. In Culyer, A. J. and Newhouse, J. P. (ed.), Handbook of Health Economics, 16291673, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Crozet, M., Head, K. and Mayer, T. (2009). Quality sorting and trade: Firm-level evidence for French wine. CEPR Working Paper No. 7295.Google Scholar
Das, S., Roberts, M. and Tybout, J. R. (2007). Market entry costs, producer heterogeneity, and export dynamics. Econometrica, 75, 837873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, J., Kortum, S. and Kramarz, F. (2004). Dissecting trade: Firms, industries, and export destinations. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 94, 150154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, C. L. (2003). The economic significance of national border effects. American Economic Review, 93, 12911312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, R. C. (1994). New product varieties and the measurement of international prices. American Economic Review, 84, 157177.Google Scholar
Francois, P. and van Ypersele, T. (2002). On the protection of cultural goods. Journal of International Economics, 56, 359369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallet, C. A. (2007). The demand for alcohol: A meta-analysis of elasticities. The Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 51, 121135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghironi, F. and Melitz, M. (2007). Trade flow dynamics with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 97, 356361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, P. K. and Verboven, F. (2001). The evolution of price dispersion in the European car market. Review of Economic Studies, 68, 811848.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, P. K. and Verboven, F. (2005). Market integration and convergence to the law of one price: Evidence from the European car market. Journal of International Economics, 65, 4973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, P. K. and Hellerstein, R. (2008). A structural approach to explaining incomplete exchange-rate pass-through and pricing-to-market. American Economic Review, 98, 423429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, R., Almenberg, J., Dreber, A., Emerson, J. W., Herschkowitsch, A. and Katz, J. (2008). Do more expensive wines taste better? Evidence from a large sample of blind tastings. Journal of Wine Economics, 3, 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendel, I. and Nevo, A. (2006), Measuring the Implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior. Econometrica, 74, 16371673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hummels, D. and Klenow, P. (2005). The variety and quality of a nation's Exports, American Economic Review, 95, 704723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konkurrensverket (2006). Övervakning av det svenska detaljhandelsmonopolet för alkoholdrycker – Rapport till Europeiska kommissionen [In Swedish: Supervision of the Swedish retail monopoly for alcohol – report to the European Commission]. Retrieved Aug 5, 2008, from http://www.kkv.se.Google Scholar
Lopez, R. and Matschke, X. (2007). Home bias in U.S. beer consumption. Manuscript, University of Connecticut.Google Scholar
McCallum, J. (1995). National borders matter: Canada-U.S. regional trade patterns. American Economic Review, 85, 615–23.Google Scholar
McFadden, D. L. (2006). Interstate wine shipments and E-commerce. Journal of Wine Economics, 1, 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nerlove, M. (1995). Hedonic price functions and the measurement of preferences: The case of Swedish wine consumers. European Economic Review, 39, 16971716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica, 69, 307342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (2000). The six major puzzles in International Macroeconomics: Is there a common cause? In Bernanke, B. and Rogoff, K. editors, NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Cambridge, MA: NBER.Google Scholar
Plassmann, H., O'Doherty, J., Shiv, B. and Rangel, A. (2008). Marketing actions can modulate neural representations of experienced pleasantness. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 105, 10501054.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rauch, J. E. and Trindade, V. (2005). Neckties in the tropics: A model of international trade and cultural diversity. NBER Working Paper No. 11890.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reibstein, D. J. and Farris, P. W. (1995). Market share and distribution: A generalization, a speculation and some implications. Marketing Science, 14, 190202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reiss, P. C. and Wolak, F. A. (2006). Structural econometric modeling: Rationales and examples from industrial organization. In Heekman, J. J. and Learner, E., editors, Handbook of Econometrics, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
State of New Hampshire (2007). Liquor commission: Management letter for the fiscal year ended June 30 2006. New Hampshire State Liquor Commission: Concord, N.H.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. and Becker, G. S. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. The American Economic Review, 67, 7690.Google Scholar
Systembolaget (2006), Launch Strategy 2006. Retrieved May 5, 2007 from http://www.systembolaget.se.Google Scholar
The International Organisation of Vine and Wine (2004). Situation report for the world vitivinicultural sector in 2004. Retrieved May 4, 2007 from www.oiv.int.Google Scholar
Tybout, J. R. (2003). Plant- and firm-level evidence on the ‘new’ trade theories. In Kwan Choi, E. and Harrigan, J., editors, Handbook of International Trade, Oxford: Basil-Blackwell.Google Scholar
Unesco (2004), A note on the list of cultural goods and services. Paris: Unesco.Google Scholar
Van Wincoop, E. and Warnock, F. E. (2008). Can trade costs in goods explain home bias in assets?. Manuscript, University of Virginia.Google Scholar