Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-p2v8j Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2024-06-02T20:10:16.726Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Comment 2.1

from 2 - Innovation in the Informal Economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 October 2016

Erika Kraemer-Mbula
Affiliation:
Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa
Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
Affiliation:
World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), Switzerland and Sciences Po, Paris

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
Hidden Engine of Innovation?
, pp. 88 - 92
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Comment 2.1

  • Colin C. Williams

  • University of Sheffield

This chapter represents the first known attempt to analyze how innovation occurs in the informal economy in developing economies. In this comment, I wish, first, to assert that many of the ideas raised are just as applicable to western economies and, second, to identify the possible future steps required to further understanding of how the informal economy is a source of innovation.

The study of the informal economy has its origins in the developing world and was largely confined to studies of developing economies for many decades (Hart Reference Hart1973). However, a burgeoning literature has recently revealed the persistence of the informal economy in the western world. Although the informal economy accounts for a larger proportion of GDP and a greater proportion of the workforce in the developing world than in the western world (Schneider Reference Schneider2008, Reference Schneider2013; Williams Reference Williams2015), estimates nevertheless suggest that the informal economy is equivalent to about 16 percent of GDP in OECD countries (Schneider and Williams Reference Schneider and Williams2013; Williams Reference Williams2014b) and that about 5 percent of the population annually work in the informal economy (Williams Reference Williams2014a).

In the early literature studying the informal economy in the western world, such endeavor was largely represented as low-paid waged work conducted under “sweatshop-like” conditions (Castells and Portes Reference Castells, Portes, Portes, Castells and Benton1989; Benton Reference Benton1990). Indeed, even discussions of informal self-employment depicted it as “precarious” or “false” self-employment arising as a result of advanced capitalism sub-contracting and outsourcing to the informal economy as a cost-reduction strategy (Gallin Reference Gallin2001; Davis Reference Davis2006). Based on this negative depiction, the policy approach advocated was its eradication (Williams Reference Williams2014a).

Following the turn of the millennium, however, this view and the resultant policy approach have begun to be challenged. Grounded in recognition that the vast majority of informal economic activity in western economies is conducted on an own-account basis (European Commission 2014; Williams Reference Williams2014a), such activity has been re-read as entrepreneurial endeavor and as constituting a “hidden enterprise culture” (Williams Reference Williams2006, Reference Williams2014c). The result has been a new sub-field of entrepreneurship scholarship focused on “informal sector entrepreneurship” that has sought to understand the role played by the informal economy in business start-ups (Williams and Martinez-Perez Reference Williams and Martinez-Perez2014a, Reference Williams and Martinez-Perez2014b): who engages in such endeavor (Small Business Council 2004; Williams Reference Williams2008), what types of activity are conducted (Williams Reference Williams2007; Dellot Reference Dellot2012; Barbour and Llanes Reference Barbour and Llanes2013) and the motives for participating in entrepreneurship in the informal economy (Snyder Reference Snyder2004; Williams Reference Williams2010). One outcome has been a shift in policy approach. Rather than pursue its eradication, much of the literature and many western governments are now seeking to harness this sphere (European Commission 2007; Williams and Nadin Reference Williams and Nadin2013, Reference Williams and Nadin2014; OECD 2014; Williams Reference Williams2014b). The current chapter is part of this shift.

One useful way to understand what is happening is to recognize that in conceptual terms the binary hierarchy between the formal and informal economy is being deconstructed. For Derrida (Reference Derrida1967), western thought is characterized by a hierarchical binary mode of thinking that, first, conceptualizes objects/identities as stable, bounded and constituted via negation (e.g. the formal and informal economy) and, second, reads the resultant binary structures in a hierarchical manner whereby the first term in any dualism (the superordinate) is endowed with positivity (in this case, the formal economy) and the second term, the subordinate (or subservient) “other,” with negativity (the informal economy). The outcome is to establish a relation of opposition and exclusion, rather than similarity and mixture, between the two sides and to overlay onto it a normative narrative of “progress” that privileges the superordinate “us” over the subordinate “other.” This lens is a useful heuristic device for viewing both the way in which the concept of the informal economy has evolved and analyses of it like the one in this chapter. It becomes immediately obvious that much of literature over the past three decades or so in the western world has been contesting the binary hierarchy between formal and informal economy and that this chapter is part of that process.

Conventionally, the informal economy was viewed as a residual and marginal sphere, as separate and discrete from the formal economy, and as a negative phenomenon. All these elements reflect its position as a subordinate other in the formal/informal economy binary hierarchy. The literature on the informal economy in the western world over the past few decades has been deconstructing this conventional binary hierarchical depiction. It has shown that the informal economy is persisting and even growing in the western world, that the formal and informal economies are not discrete and separate realms and that the boundaries are often blurred (for example, formal firms conducting a portion of their trade off the books); and attempts have been made to revalue the “subordinate” status of the informal economy such as by showing how it is a hidden enterprise culture.

The identification of innovation in the informal economy continues in this tradition. It is part of this broader process of deconstructing the conventional binary hierarchy. This signals the way forward and also the barriers that need to be addressed when seeking to represent the informal economy as a source of innovation. Innovation is itself the superordinate term in an innovation/non-innovation binary hierarchy, and this chapter and the book of which it forms part represent an attempt to break the close association between two superordinate terms (the formal economy and innovation) and two subordinate terms (the informal economy and non-innovation). To do this, however, one cannot simply apply the superordinate term of innovation to the subordinate term of the informal economy. The innovation/non-innovation binary hierarchy itself needs to be deconstructed. This chapter begins to do so by questioning what constitutes innovation, such as when the authors note that there is more adaptation and imitation than original invention in the informal economy. The problem remains that the innovation/non-innovation binary hierarchy is closely associated with many other binary hierarchies such as export production/local production, productive/unproductive, formal/informal skills and external/local markets. To assert that a superordinate term in one binary hierarchy (innovation) is associated with a subordinate term in another binary hierarchy (the informal economy) requires us to question the normative values attached to superordinate and subordinate terms in many other binary hierarchies. This is perhaps the biggest challenge now confronting those asserting that the informal economy is a source of innovation. It requires the re-valuing of many other subordinate terms (for example, local production, local markets, informal skills) and the de-valuing of many superordinate terms (for example, export production, external markets, formal skills). Unless this is done, then perhaps the inevitable outcome will be to show only that the informal economy is lacking in innovation relative to the formal economy.

References

Barbour, A. and Llanes, M. 2013. Supporting People to Legitimise Their Informal Businesses. York, Joseph Rowntree Foundation.Google Scholar
Benton, L. 1990. Invisible Factories: The Informal Economy and Industrial Development in Spain. New York, State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Castells, M. and Portes, A. 1989. “World underneath: the origins, dynamics and effects of the informal economy,” in Portes, A., Castells, M. and Benton, L.A. (eds.) The Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Developing Countries. Baltimore, John Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, M. 2006. Planet of Slums. London, Verso.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dellot, B. 2012. Untapped Enterprise: Learning to Live with the Informal Economy. London, Royal Society of the Arts.Google Scholar
Derrida, J. 1967. Of Grammatology. Baltimore, John Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
European Commission 2007. Stepping Up the Fight against Undeclared Work. Brussels, European Commission.Google Scholar
European Commission 2014. Special Eurobarometer 402: Undeclared Work. Brussels, European Commission.Google Scholar
Gallin, D. 2001. “Propositions on trade unions and informal employment in time of globalization,” Antipode 19(4): 531–49.Google Scholar
Hart, K. 1973. “Informal income opportunities and urban employment in Ghana,” Journal of Modern African Studies 11(1): 6189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD 2014. Policy Brief: Informal Entrepreneurship. Paris, OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Schneider, F. (ed.) 2008. The Hidden Economy. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, F. 2013. “Size and development of the shadow economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD countries from 2003 to 2013: a further decline,” available at www.econ.jku.at/members/Schneider/files/publications/2013/ShadEcEurope31_Jan2013.pdf.Google Scholar
Schneider, F. and Williams, C.C. 2013. The Shadow Economy. London, Institute of Economic Affairs.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Small Business Council 2004. Small Business in the Informal Economy: Making the Transition to the Formal Economy. London, Small Business Council.Google Scholar
Snyder, K.A. 2004. “Routes to the informal economy in New York’s East Village: crisis, economics and identity,” Sociological Perspectives 47: 215–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2006. The Hidden Enterprise Culture: Entrepreneurship in the Underground Economy. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2007. “The nature of entrepreneurship in the informal sector: evidence from England,” Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship 12(2): 239–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2008. “Beyond ideal-type depictions of entrepreneurship: some lessons from the service sector in England,” The Service Industries Journal 28(7/8): 1041–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2010. “Spatial variations in the hidden enterprise culture: some lessons from England,” Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 22(5): 403–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2013. “Evaluating cross-national variations in the extent and nature of informal employment in the European Union,” Industrial Relations Journal 44(5–6): 479–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2014a. Confronting the Shadow Economy: Evaluating Tax Compliance and Behaviour Policies. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2014b. “Out of the shadows: a classification of economies by the size and character of their informal sector,” Work, Employment and Society 28(5): 735–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2014c. Informal Sector Entrepreneurship: A Background Paper. Paris, OECD Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. 2015. “Out of the margins: classifying economies by the prevalence and character of employment in the informal economy,” International Labour Review 154(3): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. and Martinez-Perez, A. 2014a. “Do small business start-ups test-trade in the informal economy? Evidence from a UK small business survey,” International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business 22(1): 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. and Martinez-Perez, A. 2014b. “Is the informal economy an incubator for new enterprise creation? A gender perspective,” International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour and Research 20(1): 419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. and Nadin, S. 2013. “Harnessing the hidden enterprise culture: supporting the formalization of off-the-books business start-ups,” Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development 20(2): 434–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, C.C. and Nadin, S. 2014. “Facilitating the formalisation of entrepreneurs in the informal economy: towards a variegated policy approach,” Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy 3(1): 3348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Comment 2.1
  • Edited by Erika Kraemer-Mbula, Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
  • Book: The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
  • Online publication: 20 October 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316662076.007
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Comment 2.1
  • Edited by Erika Kraemer-Mbula, Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
  • Book: The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
  • Online publication: 20 October 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316662076.007
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Comment 2.1
  • Edited by Erika Kraemer-Mbula, Tshwane University of Technology, South Africa, Sacha Wunsch-Vincent
  • Book: The Informal Economy in Developing Nations
  • Online publication: 20 October 2016
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781316662076.007
Available formats
×