Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-sxzjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T22:04:06.462Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2009

Robert Thomson
Affiliation:
Universiteit Utrecht, The Netherlands
Frans N. Stokman
Affiliation:
Rijksuniversiteit Groningen, The Netherlands
Christopher H. Achen
Affiliation:
Princeton University, New Jersey
Thomas König
Affiliation:
German University of Administrative Sciences, Speyer, Germany
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abelson, R. P. and Tukey, J. W. 1959. ‘Efficient conversion of non-metric information into metric information’, Proceedings of the Social Statistics Section of the American Sociological Association, 226–230. Reprinted in Tufte, E. R. 1970. The Quantitative Analysis of Social Problems. Reading, Massachusetts: Addison-Wesley, pp. 407–417Google Scholar
Achen, C. H. 1999. ‘Measurement puzzles in decision-making models’, Paper presented at a meeting on decision-making in the European Union, Enschede, the Netherlands
Achen, C. H. and Snidal, D. 1989. ‘Rational deterrence theory and comparative case studies’, World Politics 41: 143–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agence Europe 2000. ‘Common definition of honey is subject of policy agreement (with opposition from Spain)’, Europe Daily Bulletins No. 7726, 27 May 2000
Albert, H. 1965 ‘Modell-Platonismus. Der neoklassische Stil des ökonomischen Denkens in kritischer Beleuchtung’, in Topitsch, E. (ed.) Logik der Sozialwissenschaften. Köln/Berlin, Kiepenheuer and Witsch, pp. 406–434Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Rosenthal, H. 1995. Partisan Politics, Divided Government, and the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almond, G. A. 1988. ‘The return to the state’, American Political Science Review 82: 853–874CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arregui, J., Stokman, F. N. and Thomson, R. 2004. ‘Bargaining in the European Union and shifts in actors' policy positions’, European Union Politics 5: 47–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1951 [1963]. Social Choice and Individual Values [1963 2nd ed.]. New York: John WileyGoogle Scholar
Aspinwall, M. D. and Schneider, G. 2000. ‘Same table, separate menu. The institutionalist turn in political science and the study of European integration’, European Journal of Political Research 38: 1–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1970. Conflict of Interest: A Theory of Divergent Goals with Applications to Politics. Markham: ChicagoGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1997. The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-based Models of Competition and Collaboration. Princeton University Press: PrincetonGoogle Scholar
Bailer, S. 2004. ‘Bargaining success in the European Union: the impact of exogenous and endogenous power resources’, European Union Politics 5: 99–124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailer, S. and Schneider, G. 2002. ‘Macht und Einfluss in EU-Verhandlungen: das Integrationsdilemma Deutschlands in vergleichender Perspektive’, in Hegmann, H. and Neumärker, B. (eds.) Die Europäische Union aus Politökonomischer Perspektive. Marburg: Metropolis, pp. 177–203Google Scholar
Bailer-Jones, D. 2003. ‘When scientific models represent’, International Studies in the Philosophy of Science 17: 59–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R., Berglöf, E., Giavazzi, F. and Widgrén, M. 2000. ‘The EU reforms for tomorrow's Europe’, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 2623
Baldwin, R., Berglöf, E., Giavazzi, F. and Widgrén, M. 2001. ‘Nice try – should the Treaty of Nice be ratified, monitoring European integration 11’, London, Centre for Economic Policy Research
Baldwin, R. and Widgrén, M. 2004a. ‘Winners and losers under various dual majority schemes’ in Wiberg, M. (ed.) Reasoned Choices – Essays in Honor of Academy Professor Hannu Nurmi on the Occasion of his 60th Birthday. The Finnish Political Science AsssociationGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Widgrén, M. 2004b. ‘Council voting in the Constitutional Treaty: devil in the details’, Centre for European Policy Research Policy Brief 53
Banfield, E. C. 1961. Political Influence. Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, J. F. 1965. ‘Weighted voting doesn't work’, Rutgers Law Review 19: 317–43Google Scholar
Baron, D. P. 1991. ‘Majoritarian incentives, pork barrel programs, and procedural control’, American Journal of Political Science 35: 57–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, D. P. and Ferejohn, J. A. 1989. ‘Bargaining in legislatures’, American Political Science Review 83: 1181–1206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barr, J. and Passarelli, F. 2004. ‘Who has the power in the EU?’ Dartmouth College and Bocconi University, working paper
Bartels, L. M. 1997. ‘Specification uncertainty and model averaging’, American Journal of Political Science 41: 641–674CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentley, A. F. 1967 [1908]. The Process of Government. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergman, T. 1997. ‘National parliaments and EU affairs committees – notes on empirical variation and competing explanations’, Journal of European Public Policy 4: 272–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berveling, J. 1994. Het Stempel op de Besluitvorming. Macht, Invloed en Besluitvormig op Twee Amsterdamse Beleidsterreinen. Amsterdam: Thesis PublishersGoogle Scholar
Beyers, J. and Dierickx, G. 1997. ‘Nationality and European negotiations. The working groups of the Council of Ministers’, European Journal of International Relations 4: 435–471CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K. 1987a. ‘Nash bargaining theory’, in Binmore, K. and Dasgupta, P. (eds.) The Economics of Bargaining. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 27–46Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1987b. ‘Perfect equilibria in bargaining models’, in Binmore, K. and Dasgupta, P. (eds.) The Economics of Bargaining. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 77–105Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1998. Game Theory and the Social Contract II. Just Playing. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Black, D. 1958. Theories of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Bouwen, R. 1993. ‘Organizational innovation as a social construction: managing meaning in multiple realities’, in Lindenberg, S. and Schreuder, H. (eds.) Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies. Oxford: Pergamon Press, pp. 133–149Google Scholar
Brams, S. J. 1975. Game Theory and Politics. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Brams, S. J. and Affuso, P. 1985. ‘New paradoxes of voting power on the EC Council of Ministers’, Electoral Studies 4: 135–139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, S. J. and Fishburn, P. C. 1983. Approval Voting. Boston: BirkhauserGoogle Scholar
Bräuninger, T., Cornelius, T., König, T. and Schuster, T. 2001. ‘The dynamics of European integration. A constitutional analysis of the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference’, in Schneider, G. and Aspinwall, M. D. (eds.) The Rules of Integration. Institutionalist Approaches to the Study of Europe. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 46–68Google Scholar
Broscheid, A. and Coen, D. 2003. ‘Insider and outsider lobbying of the European Commission’, European Union Politics 4: 165–190CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryce, J. 1893. The American Commonwealth, 2 vols. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B. 1994. ‘Political forecasting: an expected utility model’, in Mesquita, Bueno B. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) 1994. European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 71–104Google Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. 2000. Principles of International Politics. People's Power, Preferences and Perceptions. Washington: CQ PressGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. 2002. Predicting Politics. Columbus: The Ohio State University PressGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. 2004. ‘Decision making models, rigor and new puzzles’, European Union Politics 5: 125–138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B., Newman, D. and Rabushka, A. 1985. Forecasting Political Events: The Future of Hong Kong. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) 1994. European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Butler, C. K. 2004. ‘Compromise and the two-level game. Modeling compromise at the international table’, Conflict Management and Peace Science 21: 159–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, D. R. 1992. ‘The 1992 initiative: causes and consequences’, in Sbragia, A. M. (ed.) Euro-Politics: Institutions and Policymaking in the ‘New’ European Community. Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution, pp. 23–74Google Scholar
Caplin, A. and Nalebuff, B. 1988. ‘On 64%–majority rule’, Econometrica 56: 787–814CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplin, A. and Nalebuff, B. 1991. ‘Aggregation and social choice: a mean voter theorem’, Econometrica 59: 1–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruba, C. J., Gabel, M., Murrah, L., Clough, R., Montegomery, E. and Schambach, R. 2004. ‘Off the record: unrecorded legislative votes, selection bias, and roll-call vote analysis’, unpublished manuscript
Carrubba, C. J. and Volden, C. 2000. ‘Coalitional politics and logrolling in legislative institutions’, American Journal of Political Science 44: 255–271CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chong, D. 1991. Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Clarke, K. A. 2003. ‘Nonparametric model discrimination in international relations’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 47: 72–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1966a. ‘The possibility of a social welfare function’, American Economic Review 56: 1105–1122Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1966b. ‘Foundations for a theory of collective decisions’, American Journal of Sociology 71: 615–627CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Coleman, J. S. 1971. ‘Foundations for a theory of social action’, American Journal of Sociology 76: 615–627Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University.Google Scholar
Corbett, R. 2000. ‘Academic modelling of the codecision procedure: a practitioner's puzzled reaction’, European Union Politics 1: 373–8Google Scholar
Corbett, R. 2001. ‘A response to a reply to a reaction (I hope someone is still interested!)’, European Union Politics 2: 361–4Google Scholar
Council of the European Communities 1990. The Council of the European Community. Luxembourg: Office of Official Publications of the European Communities
Council of the European Union 2000. ‘A-item note: vertical directives on foodstuffs: proposal for a Council directive relating to honey, political agreement’, COREPER Document 8701/00, 24 May 2000
Crombez, C. 1996. ‘Legislative procedures in the European Community’, British Journal of Political Science 26: 199–288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 1997. ‘The co-decision procedure in the European Union’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 22: 97–119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000a. ‘Institutional reform and co-decision in the European Union’, Constitutional Political Economy 11: 41–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000b. ‘Co-decision: ‘towards a bicameral European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 363–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000c. ‘Spatial models of logrolling in the European Union’, European Journal of Political Economy 16: 707–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2001. ‘The Treaty of Amsterdam and the co-decision procedure’, in Schneider, G. and Aspinwall, M. D. (eds.) The Rules of Integration. Institutionalist Approaches to the Study of Europe. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 101–122Google Scholar
Crombez, C. 2002. ‘Information, lobbying and the legislative process in the European Union’, European Union Politics 3: 7–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2003. ‘The democratic deficit in the European Union’, European Union Politics 4: 101–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C., Steunenberg, B. and Corbett, R. 2000. ‘Understanding the EU legislative process: political scientists' and practitioners' perspectives’, European Union Politics 1: 365–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dai, X. 2002. ‘Political regimes and international trade: the democratic difference revisited’, American Political Science Review 96: 159–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, O., Groot, M. and Hinich, M. 1972. ‘Social preference orderings and majority rule’, Econometrica 40: 147–157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gooijer, J. G. 2002. ‘Introduction to forecasting decisions in conflict situations’, International Journal of Forecasting 1: 319–320CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swaan, A. 1973. Coalition Theories and Cabinet Formation. Elsevier Scientific Publishing Company: AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
De Vries, M. 1999. Governing with your Closest Neighbour: An Assessment of Spatial Coalition Formation Theories. Ph.D Thesis. University of Nijmegen
Zwaan, J. W. 1995. The Permanent Representatives Committee: its Role in European Union Decision-making. Amsterdam, New York: ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Dimitrova, A. and Steunenberg, B. 2001. ‘The search for convergence of national policies in the European Union: an impossible quest?European Union Politics. 1: 201–226CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dinan, D. 1999. Ever Closer Union. An Introduction to European Integration. Boulder/London: Lynne RiennerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbins, M., Drüner, D. and Schneider, G. 2004. ‘Kopenhagener Konsequenzen: Gesetzgebung in der EU vor und nach der Erweiterung’, Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 35: 51–68Google Scholar
Dowding, K. 2000. ‘Institutionalist research on the European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 125–144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dowding, K. 2002. ‘Rational choice and institutional change: an overview of current theories’, in Steunenberg, B. (ed.) Widening the European Union: The Politics of Institutional Reform and Change. London: Routledge, pp. 21–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and RowGoogle Scholar
Edwards, G. 1996. ‘National sovereignty vs. integration? The Council of Ministers’, in Richardson, J. (ed.) European Union: Power and Policy-making. London: Routledge, pp. 127–147CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. and Roemer, J. E. 1991. Interpersonal Comparisons of Well–being. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enelow, J. M. and Hinich, M. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Erev, I., Roth, A. E., Slonim, R. L. and Barron, G. 2002. ‘Predictive value and the usefulness of game theoretic models’, International Journal of Forecasting 18: 359–368CrossRefGoogle Scholar
European Commission 1996. ‘Proposal for a Council directive relating to honey’, Official Journal C 231, 9 August 1996, 10
European Commission 2001. General Report on the Activities of the European Union, 2000. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities
Evans, P. B. 1993. ‘Building an integrative approach to international and domestic politics: reflections and projections’, in Evans, P. B., Jacobson, H. K. and Putnam, R. D. (eds.) Double-edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 397–430Google Scholar
Evans, P. B., Jacobson, H. K. and Putnam, R. O. (eds.) 1993. Double-edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Farrell, H. and Héritier, A. 2003. ‘Formal and informal institutions under codecision: continuous constitution-building in Europe’, Governance 16: 577–600Google Scholar
Farrell, H. and Héritier, A., 2004. ‘Interorganizational negotiation and intraorganizational power in shared decision-making: early agreements under codecision and their impact on the European Parliament and Council’, Comparative Political Studies 37: 1184–1212CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1994. ‘Domestic political audiences and the escalation of international disputes’, American Political Science Review 90: 715–735CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feder, S. A. 1987. ‘FACTIONS and Policon: new ways to analyze politics’, Studies in Intelligence 31: 41–57. Originally classified ‘Secret.’ Reprinted in Bradford Westerfield, H. 1995. Inside CIA's Private World. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 274–292
Feld, L., Kirchgässner, G. and Weck-Hannemann, H. 2002. ‘Enlargement and the European budget: budgetary decision making and fiscal constraints’, in Steunenberg, B. (ed.) Widening the European Union: The Politics of Institutional Reform and Change. London: Routledge, pp. 144–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felsenthal, D. and Machover, M. 1998. The Measurement of Voting Power. Theory and Practice, Problems and Paradoxes. Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Felsenthal, D. S. and Machover, M. 2001a. ‘Myths and meanings of voting power’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 13: 81–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felsenthal, D. S. and Machover, M. 2001b. ‘The Treaty of Nice and qualified majority voting’, Social Choice and Welfare 18: 431–464CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, R. J. Jr. 1999. ‘Partially independent central banks, politically responsive governments, and inflation’, American Journal of Political Science 43: 681–706CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E. and Johnsen, E. C. 1990. ‘Social influence and opinion’, Journal of Mathematical Sociology 15: 193–205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E. and Johnsen, E. C. 1997. ‘Social positions in influence networks’, Social Networks 19: 209–222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E. and Johnsen, C. 1999. ‘Social influence networks and opinion change’, Advances in Group Processes 16: 1–29Google Scholar
Friedman, J. W. 1990. Game Theory with Applications to Economics. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Levine, D. K. 1998. The Theory of Learning in Games. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Gabel, M., Hix, S. and Schneider, G. 2002. ‘Who is afraid of cumulative research? Improving data on EU politics’, European Union Politics 3: 481–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. 1995. ‘From the Luxembourg compromise to codecision: decision making in the European Union’, Electoral Studies 50: 289–308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1996. ‘An institutional critique of intergovernmentalism’, International Organization 50: 269–299CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1997. ‘More on the codecision endgame’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 139–143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1999a. ‘Why resist the temptation to apply power indices to the EU?’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 291–308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1999b. ‘More reasons to resist the temptation to apply power indices to the EU’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 331–338CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 2001a. ‘Understanding better the EU legislative process’, European Union Politics 2: 353–361CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 2001b. ‘Even more reasons to resist the temptation to apply power indices to the EU’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 13: 99–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaver, K. M. and Geisel, M. S. 1974. ‘Discriminating among alternative models: Bayesian and non–Bayesian approaches’, in Zarembka, P. (ed.) Frontiers in Econometrics. New York: Academic, pp. 49–77Google Scholar
Gilligan, T. and Krehbiel, K. 1995. ‘The gains from exchange hypothesis of legislative organization’, in Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (eds.) Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grafstein, R. 1992. Institutional Realism. New Haven: Yale University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granger, C. W. J. and Newbold, P. 1986. Forecasting Economic Time Series, 2nd ed. Orlando, Florida: AcademicGoogle Scholar
Greenberg, J. 1979. ‘Consistent majority rule over compact sets of alternatives’, Econometrica 47: 627–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gul, F. 1989. ‘Bargaining foundations of Shapley value’, Econometrica 57: 81–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haas, E. B. 1958. The Uniting of Europe. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Haas, E. B. 1975. The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory. Berkeley: Institute of International StudiesGoogle Scholar
Hall, P. and Taylor, R. 1996. ‘Political science and the three new institutionalisms’, Political Studies 44: 936–957CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, T. H. and Miller, G. J. 1987. ‘The core of the constitution’, American Political Science Review 81: 1155–174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, T. H. and Prins, B. C. 1999. ‘The impact of domestic institutions on international negotiations: a taxonomy of results from a complete-information spatial model’, paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, Georgia, 2–5 September 1999
Harsanyi, J. C. 1963. ‘A simplified bargaining model for the n-person cooperative game’, International Economic Review 4: 194–220CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. 1977. Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, S. and Mas-Colell, A. 1996. ‘Bargaining and value’, Econometrica 64: 357–380CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayes-Renshaw, F. 2001. ‘The Council and enlargement: a challenge or an opportunity?’, Journal of International Relations and Development 4: 9–12Google Scholar
Hayes-Renshaw, F. and Wallace, H. 1995. ‘Executive power in the European Union: the functions and limits of the Council of Ministers’, Journal of European Public Policy 2: 559–582Google Scholar
Hayes-Renshaw, F. and Wallace, H. 1997. The Council of Ministers. Basingstoke: Macmillan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herstein, I. N. and Milnor, J. 1953. ‘An axiomatic approach to measurable utility’, Econometrica 21: 291–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. J. and Munger, M. C. 1994. Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. and Munger, M. C. 1997. Analytical Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. 1998. ‘The study of the European Union II: the ‘New Governance’ agenda and its rival’, Journal of European Public Policy 5: 38–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. 1999. The Political System of the European Union. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. and Lord, C. 1997. Political Parties in the European Union. New York: St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffmann, S. 1966. ‘Obstinate or obsolete? The face of the nation State and the case of Western Europe’, Daedalus, 95: 892–908Google Scholar
Holler, M. J. 1994. ‘Comment’, in Herder-Dorneich, P., Schenk, K. E. and Schmidtchen, D. (eds.) Neue Politische Ökonomie der Reguliering, Dereguliering and Privatisierung (Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, Volume 13). Tübingen: Mohr, pp. 66–71Google Scholar
Holler, M. J. and Widgrén, M. 1999. ‘Why power indices for assessing EU decision-making’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 321–330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. 1993. ‘Admission of European Free Trade Association states to the European Community: effects of voting power in the European Community Council of Ministers’, International Organization 47: 629–643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. 1995. ‘The balance between small and large: effects of a double-majority system on voting power in the European Union’, International Studies Quarterly 39: 351–370CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. 2000. ‘Smaller states and the new voting weights in the Council’, working paper. Clingendael Institute of International Relations: The Hague
Hosli, M. O. and Machover, M. 2004. ‘The Nice Treaty and voting rules in the Council: a reply to Moberg (2002)’, Journal of Common Market Studies 42: 497–521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. and Van Deemen, A. 2002. ‘Effects of enlargement on efficiency and coalition formation in the Council of the European Union’, in Hosli, M. O., Deemen, A. and Widgrén, M. (eds.) Institutional Challenges in the European Union. London: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. and Wolffenbuttel, R. F. 2001. ‘Estimating the vote distribution in the Council of the European Union’, Journal of International Relations and Development 4: 38–54Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1929. ‘Stability in competition’, Economic Journal 39: 41–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J. and Inglehart, R. 1995. ‘Expert interpretations of party space and party locations in 42 societies’, Party Politics 1: 73–111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubschmid, C. and Moser, P. 1997. ‘The cooperation procedure in the EU: why was the European Parliament influential in the decision on car emission standards’, Journal of Comman Market Studies 35: 225–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hug, S. 2002. Voices of Europe. Citizens, Referendums and European Integration. Lanham: Rowman and LittlefieldGoogle Scholar
Hug, S. and Christin, T. 2002. ‘Referendums and citizen support for European integration’, Comparative Political Studies 5: 586–618Google Scholar
Hug, S. and König, T. 2002. ‘In view of ratification: governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference’, International Organization 56: 447–476CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iida, K. 1993. ‘When and how do domestic constraints matter? Two-level games with uncertainty’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 37: 403–426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, H. and Broder, D. 1996. The System. Boston: Little BrownGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Smorodinsky, M. 1975. ‘Other solutions to Nash's bargaining problem’, Econometrica 43: 513–518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kasack, C. 2004. ‘The legislative impact of the European Parliament under the revised co-decision procedure. Environmental, public health and consumer protection policies’, European Union Politics 5: 241–260CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kauppi, H. and Widgrén, M. 2004. ‘What determines EU decision-making: needs, power or both?’, Economic Policy 39, 221–266Google Scholar
Keeney, R. L. and Raiffa, H. 1993. Decisions with Multiple Objectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirman, A. and Widgrén, M. 1995. ‘European economic decision-making policy: Progress or paralysis?’, Economic Policy 21: 421–460CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knoke, D., Pappi, F. U. and Broadbent, J. 1996. Comparing Policy Networks: Labor Politics in the US, Germany, and Japan, Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, K. 2003. ‘The rotating presidency of the European Union as a search for good policies’, European Union Politics 4: 51–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. 1992. Entscheidungen im Politiknetzwerkβ: Der Einflua von Organisationen auf die Arbeits- und Sozialrechtliche Gesetzgebung in den 80er Jahren. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitäts-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. 1997. Europa auf dem Weg zum Mehrebenensystem. Gründe und konsequenzen nationaler und parlamentarischer Integration. Opladen: Westdeutscher VerlagGoogle Scholar
König, T. and Bräuninger, T. 1998. ‘The inclusiveness of European decision rules’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 10: 125–141CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. and Bräuninger, T. 2000. ‘Governing the enlarged European Union: accession scenarios and institutional reform’, Central European Political Science Review 1: 42–62Google Scholar
König, T. and Hug, S. 2000. ‘Ratifying Maastricht, parliamentary votes on international treaties and theoretical solution concepts’, European Union Politics 1: 89–122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. and Pöter, M. 2001. ‘Examining the EU legislative process: the relative importance of agenda and veto power’, European Union Politics 2: 329–351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1988. ‘Spatial models of legislative choice’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 13: 259–319CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1991. Information and Legislative Organization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1998. Pivotal Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreppel, A. 1999. ‘The European Parliament's influence over EU policy outcomes’, Journal of Common Market Studies 37: 521–538CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, J. E. and Ersson, S. 2000. The New Institutional Politics. Performance and Outcomes. London and New York: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
LaPalombara, J. 1960. ‘The utility and limitations of interest group theory in non-American field situations’, Journal of Politics 22: 29–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laruelle, A. 1998. ‘The EU decision making procedures: some insight from non-cooperative game theory’, IRES Discussion Papers, 97/27
Laruelle, A. 2002. ‘The EU decision making procedures: some insight from non-cooperative game theory’, in Hosli, M., Deemen, A. and Widgrén, M. (eds.) Institutional Challenges in the European Union. London: Routledge, pp. 89–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laruelle, A. and Widgrén, M. 1998. ‘Is the allocation of power among EU states fair?’, Public Choice 94: 317–339CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laruelle, A. and Widgrén, M. 2001. ‘Voting power in a sequence of cooperative games’, in Holler, M. and Owen, G. (eds.) Voting Power And Coalition Formation. Dortrecht and Boston: Kluwer Academic PublishersCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M. and Shepsle, K. 1996. Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leech, D. 2002. ‘Designing the voting system for the Council of Ministers of the European Union’, Public Choice 113: 437–464CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leenders, R. Th. A. J. 1995. Structure and Influence. Statistical Models for the Dynamics of Actor Attributes, Network Structure and their Interdependence. Amsterdam: Thesis PublishersGoogle Scholar
Leenders, R. Th. A. J. 2002. ‘Modeling social influence through network autocorrelation: constructing the weight matrix’, Social Networks 24: 21–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewin, L. 1991. Self-interest and Public Interest in Western Politics. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, J. 2000. ‘The methods of community in EU decision-making and administrative rivalry in the council's infrastructure’, Journal of European Public Policy 7: 261–289CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, L. N. 1963. The Political Dynamics of European Economic Integration. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lindblom, C. E. 1965. The Intelligence of Democracy. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Lindenberg, S. 1997. ‘Grounding groups in theory: functional, structural and cognitive interdependencies’, Advances in Group Processes 14: 281–331Google Scholar
Lindenberg, S. 2001. ‘Social rationality versus rational egoism’, in Turner, J. H. (ed.) Handbook of Social Theory. New York: Kluwer Academic and Plenum PublishersGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, S. 1997. ‘Linkage Politics’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41: 38–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowndes, V. 2002. ‘Institutionalism’, in Marsh, D. and Stoker, G. (eds.) Theory and Methods in Political Science. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 90–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manley, J. F. 1970. The Politics of Finance. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 2000. ‘Free to trade: democracies, autocracies and international trade’, American Political Science Review 94: 305–322CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 2002. ‘Replication, realism, and robustness: analyzing political regimes and international trade’, American Political Science Review 96: 167–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. G. and Olsen, J. P. 1984. ‘The new institutionalism: organizational factors in political life’, American Political Science Review 78: 734–749CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. and Olsen, J. 1989. Rediscovering Institutions: the Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Marks, G., Hooghe, L. and Blank, K. 1996. ‘European integration in the 1980s: state-centric vs. multi-level governance’, Journal of Common Market Studies 34: 341–378CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsden, P. V. and Friedkin, N. E. 1993. ‘Network studies of social influence’, Sociological Methods and Research 22: 127–151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, L. 2000. Democratic Commitments-Legislatures and International Cooperation. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D. and Green, J. R. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Mattila, M. and Lane, J. E. 2001. ‘Why unanimity in the Council? A roll call analysis of Council voting’, European Union Politics 2: 31–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mavrogordatos, G. 1984. ‘The Greek party system: a case of limited but polarised pluralism’, West European Politics 7: 156–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. 1976. ‘Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control’, Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–182CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. 1979. ‘General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models’, Econometrica 47: 1085–1112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., Ordeshook, P. and Winer, M. 1978. ‘The competitive solution for N-person games without transferable utility: with an application for committee games’, American Political Science Review 72: 599–615CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mearsheimer, J. J. 1994–95. ‘The false promise of international institutions’. International Security 19: 5–49Google Scholar
Merlo, A. and Wilson, C. 1995. ‘A stochastic model of sequential bargaining with complete information’, Econometrica 63: 371–399CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, H. V. 1997. Interests, Institutions, and Information. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 1996. ‘Trade negotiations, information and domestic politics’, Economics and Politics 8: 145–89Google Scholar
Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 1997. ‘Democratic politics and international trade negotiations. Elections and divided government as constraints on trade liberalization’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41: 117–146CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mo, J. 1995. ‘Domestic institutions and international bargaining: the role of agent veto in two-level games’, American Political Science Review 89: 914–924CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moberg, A. 2002. ‘The Nice Treaty and voting rules in the Council’, Journal of Common Market Studies 40: 259–282CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokken, R. J., Payne, D., Stokman, F. N. and Wasseur, F. W. 2000. ‘Decision context and policy effectuation: EU structural reform in Ireland’, Irish Political Studies 15: 39–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Molm, L. 1996. Coercive Power in Social Exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Moravcsik, A. 1993. ‘Introduction: integration international and domestic theories of international bargaining’, in Evans, P. B., Jacobson, H. K. and Putnam, R. D. (eds.) Double-Edged Diplomacy. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Moravcsik, A. 1998. The Choice for Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Morgan, M. S. and Morrison, M. (eds.) 1999. Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenthau, H. 1948. Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, New York: KnopfGoogle Scholar
Morrison, M. and Morgan, M. S. 1999. ‘Models as mediating instruments’, in Morgan, M. S. and Morrison, M. (eds.) Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 10–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morton, R. B. 1999. Methods and Models: A Guide to the Empirical Analysis of Formal Models in Political Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 1996. ‘The European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter: what are the conditions? A critique of Tsebelis (1994)’, American Political Science Review 90: 834–838CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 1997a. ‘A theory of the conditional influence of the European Parliament in the co-operation procedure’, Public Choice 91: 333–350CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 1997b. ‘The benefits of the conciliation procedure for the European Parliament: comment to George Tsebelis’, Aussenwirtschaft 52: 57–62Google Scholar
Moser, P D., Schneider, G. and Kirchgässner, G. 2000. Decision Rules in the European Union: a Rational Choice Perspective. New York: St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moulin, H. 1988. Axioms of Cooperative Decision Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, A. H. and Winkler, R. L. 1984. ‘Probability forecasting in meteorology’, Journal of the American Statistical Association 79: 489–500Google Scholar
Muthoo, A. 1999. Bargaining Theory With Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2002a. ‘Strategic power in EU decision making procedures’, unpublished manuscript
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2002b. ‘Strategic power revisited’, Munich: CESifo Working Paper No. 736
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2004a. ‘Power measurement as sensitivity analysis – a unified approach’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 16: 517–538CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2004b. ‘The inter-institutional distribution of power in EU codecision’, Munich: CESifo Working Paper No. 1347, Social Choice and Welfare, forthcoming
Nash, J. F. 1950. ‘The bargaining problem’, Econometrica 18: 155–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. F. 1953. ‘Two-person cooperative games’, Econometrica 21: 128–140CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholson, M. 1989. Formal Theories in International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Noury, A. G. 2002. ‘Ideology, nationality and Euro-Parliamentarians’, European Union Politics 3: 33–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nugent, N. 1999. The Government and Politics of the European Union. Durham: Duke University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opp, K. D. 1990. Empirischer Theorienvergleich: Erklärungen sozialen Verhaltens in Problemsituationen. Opladen: Westdeutscher VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Reilly, C. A. 1983. ‘The use of information in organizational decision making: a model and some propositions’, Research in Organizational Behaviour 5: 103–139Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 1986. ‘An agenda for the study of institutions’, Public Choice 48: 3–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owen, G. 1972. ‘Multilinear extensions of games’, Management Science 18: 64–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owen, G. 1995. Game Theory. 3rd edition. San Diego: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Pahre, R. 1997. ‘Endogenous domestic institutions in two-level games and parliamentary oversight of the European Union’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41: 147–174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pahre, R. 2001. ‘Divided government and international cooperation in Austria-Hungary, Sweden-Norway and the European Union’, European Union Politics 2: 131–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pajala, A. 2002. Expected Power and Success in Coalitions and Space: Empirical Voting Power in 17 European Parliaments and the Council of the EU. Doctoral Dissertation. Turku: University of TurkuGoogle Scholar
Pajala, A. and Widgrén, M. 2004. ‘A priori vs. empirical power in the EU Council of Ministers’, European Union Politics 5: 73–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pappi, F. U. and Henning, C. 1998. ‘Policy networks, public policy-making and visualization – policy networks: more than a metaphor?Journal of Theoretical Politics 10: 553–576CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, D. 1999. Policy Making in the European Union. An Analysis of the Impact of the Reform of the Structural Funds in Ireland. Amsterdam: Thesis PublishersGoogle Scholar
Peters, G. 1999. Institutional Theory in Political Science: the ‘New Institutionalism’. London: PinterGoogle Scholar
Peterson, J. and Bomberg, E. 1999. Decision Making in the European Union. London: Macmillan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, C. R. 1967. ‘A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule’, American Economic Review 57: 787–806Google Scholar
Plott, C. R. 1991. ‘Will economics become an experimental science?Southern Economic Journal 57: 901–920CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. D. 1988. ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-level games’, International Organization 42: 427–460CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. D. 1993. ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-level games’ in Putnam, R. D., Evans, P. and Jacobson, H. (eds.) Double-Edged Diplomacy. International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 431–468Google Scholar
Rabinowitz, G. and MacDonald, S. E. 1986. ‘The power of the states in US presidential elections’, American Political Science Review 80: 65–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raftery, A. E. 1995. ‘Bayesian model selection in social research’, Sociological Methodology 25: 111–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raiffa, H. 1953. ‘Arbitration schemes for generalized two-person games’, in Kuhn, H. W. and Tucker, A. (eds.) Contribution to the Theory of Games II: Annals of Mathematics Studies. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 361–387Google Scholar
Raub, W. and Weesie, J. 1990. ‘Reputation and efficiency in social interactions: an example of network effects’, American Journal of Sociology 96: 626–654CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, J. L. and Russet, B. 1996. ‘The future as arbiter of theoretical controversies: predictions, explanations and the end of the cold war’, British Journal of Political Sciences 26: 441–470CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, J. L. and Singer, D. J. 1990. ‘Measuring the concentration of power in the international system’, in Singer, D. J. and Diehl, P. F. (eds.) Measuring the Correlates of War. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Richardson, J. (ed.) 1996. European Union: Power and Policy-making. London: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, W. H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Riker, W. H. 1980. ‘Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions’, American Political Science Review 74: 432–446CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, W. H. and Brams, S. J. 1973. ‘The paradox of vote trading’, American Political Science Review 67: 1235–1247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riley, J. 1988. Liberal Utilitarianism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Robert, C. P. 2001. The Bayesian Choice, 2nd ed. New York: SpringerGoogle Scholar
Rojer, M. 1999. ‘Collective decision-making models applied to labour negotiations in the Netherlands: a comparison between a position exchange model and a conflict model’, Rationality and Society 11: 207–235CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. 1979. Axiomatic Models of Bargaining. Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 1982. ‘Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model’, Econometrica 50: 97–109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 2000. Economics and Language. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, T. C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G. 1994. ‘Getting closer at different speeds: strategic interaction in widening European integration’, in Allan, P. and Schmidt, C. (eds.) Game Theory and International Relations. Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G. 1995. ‘Agenda-setting in European integration: the conflict between voters, governments and supranational institutions’, in Laursen, F. (ed.) The Political Economy of European Integration. Maastricht: European Institute of Public Administration, pp. 31–61Google Scholar
Schneider, G. and Aspinwall, M. D. (eds.) 2001. The Rules of Integration. Institutionalist Approaches to the Study of Europe. Manchester: Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G. and Baltz, K. 2003. ‘The power of specialization: how interest groups influence EU-legislation’, Rivista die Politica Economica XCIII: 253–283Google Scholar
Schneider, G. and Baltz, K. 2005. ‘Domesticated Eurocrats: bureaucratic discretion in the legislative pre-negotiations of the European Union’, Acta Politica, forthcoming
Schneider, G. and Cederman, L. E. 1994. ‘The change of tide in political cooperation: a limited information model of European integration’, International Organization 48: 633–662CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G., Finke, D. and Bailer, S. 2004. ‘Bargaining power: an evaluation of competing models’, University of Konstanz, working paper
Schneider, G. and Weitsman, P. A. 1996. ‘The punishment trap: integration referendums as popularity contests’, Comparative Political Studies 28: 582–607CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, N. 1978. ‘Instability of simple dynamic games’, Review of Economic Studies 45: 575–594CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scully, R. M. 1997a. ‘The European Parliament and the co-decision procedure: a reassessment’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 58–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scully, R. M. 1997b. ‘The European Parliament and co-decision: a rejoinder to Tsebelis and Garrett’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 93–103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selck, T. J. 2004. ‘On the dimensionality of European Union legislative decision making’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 16: 203–222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selck, T. J. and Steunenberg, B. 2004. ‘Between power and luck: the European Parliament in the EU legislative process’, European Union Politics 5: 25–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapley, L. S. 1953. ‘A value for n-person cooperative games’, in Kuhn, H. and Tucker, A. (eds.) Contributions to the Theory of Games,vol II. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 343–459Google Scholar
Shapley, L. S. 1977. ‘A comparison of power indices and a non-symmetric generalization’, RAND Corporation, Paper P-5872
Shapley, L. S. and Shubik, M. 1954. ‘A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system’, American Political Science Review 48: 787–792CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. 1979. ‘Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models’, American Journal of Political Science 32: 27–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. 1989. ‘Studying institutions: some lessons from the rational choice approach’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 1: 131–147CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1981. ‘Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice’, Public Choice 37: 503–519CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1984. ‘Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda institutions’, American Journal of Political Science 28: 49–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1987. ‘Why are congressional committees powerful?’ American Political Science Review 81: 935–45Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1995. ‘Positive theories of congressional institutions’, in Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (eds.) Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 5–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherrington, P. 1999. The Council of Ministers: Political Authority in the European Union. London and New York: PinterGoogle Scholar
Shubik, M. 1982. Game Theory in the Social Sciences. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Signorino, C. S. 1999. ‘Estimation and strategic interaction in discrete choice models of international conflict’, American Political Science Review 92: 279–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singer, D. J. 1969. ‘The incomplete theorist: insight without evidence’, in Rosenau, J. N. and Knorr, K. (eds.) Contending Approaches to International Politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 63–86Google Scholar
Snidal, D. 1994. ‘The politics of scope: endogenous actors, heterogeneity and institutions’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 6: 449–472CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soetendorp, B. and Hosli, M. O. 2001. ‘The hidden dynamics of EU Council decision making’, Acta Politica 4, 252–287Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1994a. ‘Decision-making under different institutional arrangements: legislation by the European Community’, Journal of Theoretical and Institutional Economics 150: 642–669Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1994b. ‘Regulatory policymaking in a parliamentary setting’ in Herder-Dorneich, P.Schenk, K. E. and Schmidtchen, D. (eds.) Neue Politische Ökonomie der Reguliering, Dereguliering and Privatisierung (Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, Volume 13). Tübingen: Mohr, pp. 36–57Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1997. ‘Codecision and its reform: a comparative analysis of decision making rules in the European Union’, in Steunenberg, B. and Vught, F. A. (eds.) Political Institutions and Public Policy: Perspectives on European Decision Making. Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 205–229CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2000a. ‘Constitutional change in the European Union: parliament's impact on the reform of the codecision procedure’, in Wagenaar, H. (ed.) Government Institutions: Effects, Changes and Normative Foundations. Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 89–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2000b. ‘Seeing what you want to see: the limits of current modelling on the European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 368–373Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2001. ‘Enlargement and institutional reform in the European Union: separate or connected issues?Constitutional Political Economy 12: 349–368CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2002a. ‘Playing different games: the European Parliament and the reform of codecision’, in Steunenberg, B. and Thomassen, J. (eds.) The European Parliament: Moving Toward Democracy in the EU. Boulder: Rowman and Littlefield, pp. 163–83Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2002b. ‘An even wider Union: the effects of enlargement on EU decision-making’, in Steunenberg, B. (ed.) Widening the European Union: The Politics of Institutional Change and Reform. London and New York: Routledge, pp. 97–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. and Dimitrova, A. 1999. Interests, Legitimacy, and Constitutional Choice: the Extension of the Codecision Procedure in Amsterdam. Enschede: University of Twente. MimeoGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B., Koboldt, C. and Schmidtchen, D. 1996. ‘Policymaking, comitology, and the balance of power in the European Union’, International Review of Law and Economics 16: 329–344CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B.Koboldt, C. and Schmidtchen, D. 1997. ‘Beyond comitology: a comparative analysis of implementation procedures with parliamentary involvement’, Aussenwirtschaft 52: 87–112Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B., Schmidtchen, D. and Koboldt, C. 1999. ‘Strategic power in the European Union: evaluating the distribution of power in policy games’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 339–366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigum, B. 1990. Towards a Formal Science of Economics. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Stokman, F. N. 2004. ‘What binds us when with whom? Content and structure in social network analysis’, extended version of keynote at the SUNBELT XXIV International Social Network Conference, Portorož (Slovenia), May 13 2004 (www.oprit.rug.nl/stokman/articles.htm)
Stokman, F. N. 2005. ‘Was verbindet uns wann mit wem? Inhalt und Struktur in der Analyse Sozialer Netzwerke’, Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie (forthcoming)
Stokman, F. N. and Thomson, R. (eds.) 2004. ‘Special issue: winners and losers in the European Union’, European Union Politics 5: 1–138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokman, F. N., Assen, M., Knoop, Jan J. and Oosten, R. 2000. ‘Strategic decision making’, Advances in Group Processes 17: 131–153Google Scholar
Stokman, F. N. and Van den Bos, J. M. M. 1992. ‘A two–stage model of policymaking with an empirical test in the US energy-policy domain’, in Moore, G. and Whitt, Allen J. (eds.) The Political Consequences of Social Networks. Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press, pp. 219–253Google Scholar
Stokman, F. N. and Van Oosten, R. 1994. ‘The exchange of voting positions: an object-oriented model of policy networks’, in Mesquita, Bueno B. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 105–127Google Scholar
Stokman, F. N. and Zeggelink, E. P. H. 1996. ‘Is politics power or policy oriented? A comparative analysis of dynamic access models in policy networks’, Journal of Mathematical Sociology 21: 77–111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sweet, Stone A. and Sandholtz, W. (eds.) 1998. Supranational Governance: The Institutionalization of the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Straffin, P. D. 1977. ‘Homogeneity, independence and power indices’, Public Choice 30: 107–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straffin, P. D 1988. ‘The Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf power indices as probabilities’, in Roth, A. (ed.) The Shapley Value. Essays in Honor of Lloyd Shapley. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stratmann, T. 1997. ‘Logrolling’, in Mueller, D. C. (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Tallberg, J. 2003. ‘The agenda-shaping powers of the EU Council presidency’, Journal of European Public Policy 10: 1–19Google Scholar
Tarar, A. 2001. ‘International bargaining with two-sided domestic constraints’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 320–340CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomson, R., Boerefijn, J. and Stokman, F. N. 2004. ‘Actor alignments in European Union decision-making’. European Journal of Political Research 43: 237–261Google Scholar
Thomson, R., Torenvlied, R. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) 2003. ‘Special issue: models of collective decision-making’, Rationality and Society 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tollison, R. and Willet, T.. 1979. ‘An economic theory of mutually advantageous issue linkage in international organizations’, International Organization 4: 425–449CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1994. ‘The power of the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter’, American Political Science Review 88: 128–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1995. ‘Will Maastricht reduce the ‘democratic deficit’?’ APSA Comparative Politics 6: 4–6Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1996. ‘More on the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter: response to Moser’, American Political Science Review 90: 839–844CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1997. ‘Maastricht and the democratic deficit’, Aussenwirtschaft 52: 29–56Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 1996. ‘Agenda setting power, power indices, and decision making in the European Union’, International Review of Law and Economics 16: 345–361CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 1997a. ‘Agenda setting, vetoes and the European Union's co-decision procedure’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 74–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 1997b. ‘Why power indices cannot explain decisionmaking in the European Union’, in Schmidtchen, D. and Cooter, R. (eds.) Constitutional Law and Economics of the European Union. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 11–31Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 2000. ‘Legislative politics in the European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 5–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 2001. ‘The institutional foundations of intergovernmentalism and supranationalism in the European Union’, International Organization 55: 357–390CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G., Jensen, C., Kalandrakis, A. and Kreppel, A. 2001Legislative procedures in the European Union: an empirical analysis’, British Journal of Political Science 31: 373–399CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Kalandrakis, A. 1999. ‘The european parliament and environmental legislation: the case of chemicals’, European Journal of Political Research 36: 119–154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Money, J. 1997. Bicameralism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. 1959. ‘Some problems of majority voting’, Journal of Political Economy 67: 571–579CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Assen, M. 2001. Essays on Actor Models in Exchange Networks and Social Dilemmas. Amsterdam: Thela ThesisGoogle Scholar
Assen, M., Stokman, F. N. and Oosten, R. C. H. 2003. ‘Conflict measures in cooperative position exchange models of collective decision-making’, Rationality and Society 15: 64–84Google Scholar
Deemen, A. 1997. Coalition Formation and Social Choice, Amsterdam: KluwerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Deemen, A. and Hosli, M. O. 1999. ‘Conflict and cooperation in collective decision-making systems’, working paper
Van den Bogaard, A. 1999. ‘Past measurement and future prediction’, in Morgan, M. S. and Morrison, M. (eds.) Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 282–325CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bos, J. M. M. 1991. Dutch EC Policy Making. A Model-Guided Approach to Coordination and Negotiation. Amsterdam: Thela ThesisGoogle Scholar
Doel, J. and Velthoven, B. 1993. Democracy and Welfare Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hees, M. and Steunenberg, B. 2000. ‘The choices judges make: court rulings, personal values, and legal constraints’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 12: 299–317Google Scholar
Schendelen, R. 2002. Machiavelli in Brussels: The Art of Lobbying the EU. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. H. 2004. ‘Bargaining and conflict resolution’, in Maoz, Z., Mintz, A., Clifton Margan, T., Palmer, G. and Stoll, R. J. (eds.) Multiple Paths to Knowledge in International Relations. Lexington: Lexington Books, pp. 39–72Google Scholar
Wallace, W. 2000. ‘Collective governance’, in Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (eds.) Policy-Making in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 523–542Google Scholar
Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (eds.) 1996. Policy-Making in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (eds.)2000. Policy-Making in the European Union 4th edition. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Ward, H. 2002. ‘Rational choice’, in Marsh, D. and Stoker, G. (eds.) Theory and Methods in Political Science. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 65–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weibull, J. W. 1995. Evolutionary Game Theory. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Weick, K. E. 1979. The Social Psychology of Organizing. Reading: Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Weiler, J. H. H. 1999. The Constitution of Europe. ‘Do the New Clothes Have an Emperor?’ and other essays on European Integration. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Weingast, B. R. and Marshall, W. J. 1988. ‘The industrial organization of congress; or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets’, Journal of Political Economy 96: 132–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Westlake, M. 1994. A Modern Guide to the European Parliament. London: PinterGoogle Scholar
Westlake, M. 1995. The Council of the European Union. London: CatermillGoogle Scholar
Widgrén, M. 1994. ‘Voting power in the EC and the consequences of two different enlargements’, European Economic Review 38: 1153–1170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Widgrén, M. 1995. ‘Probabilistic voting power in the EU Council: the cases of trade policy and social regulation’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97: 345–356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, W. 1885. Congressional Government. Boston: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Zimmer, C., Schneider, G. and Dobbins, M. 2005. ‘The contested Council: conflict dimensions of an intergovernmental EU institution’, Political Studies 53: 403–422CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abelson, R. P. and Tukey, J. W. 1959. ‘Efficient conversion of non-metric information into metric information’, Proceedings of the Social Statistics Section of the American Sociological Association, 226–230. Reprinted in Tufte, E. R. 1970. The Quantitative Analysis of Social Problems. Reading, Massachusetts: Addison-Wesley, pp. 407–417Google Scholar
Achen, C. H. 1999. ‘Measurement puzzles in decision-making models’, Paper presented at a meeting on decision-making in the European Union, Enschede, the Netherlands
Achen, C. H. and Snidal, D. 1989. ‘Rational deterrence theory and comparative case studies’, World Politics 41: 143–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agence Europe 2000. ‘Common definition of honey is subject of policy agreement (with opposition from Spain)’, Europe Daily Bulletins No. 7726, 27 May 2000
Albert, H. 1965 ‘Modell-Platonismus. Der neoklassische Stil des ökonomischen Denkens in kritischer Beleuchtung’, in Topitsch, E. (ed.) Logik der Sozialwissenschaften. Köln/Berlin, Kiepenheuer and Witsch, pp. 406–434Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Rosenthal, H. 1995. Partisan Politics, Divided Government, and the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almond, G. A. 1988. ‘The return to the state’, American Political Science Review 82: 853–874CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arregui, J., Stokman, F. N. and Thomson, R. 2004. ‘Bargaining in the European Union and shifts in actors' policy positions’, European Union Politics 5: 47–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1951 [1963]. Social Choice and Individual Values [1963 2nd ed.]. New York: John WileyGoogle Scholar
Aspinwall, M. D. and Schneider, G. 2000. ‘Same table, separate menu. The institutionalist turn in political science and the study of European integration’, European Journal of Political Research 38: 1–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1970. Conflict of Interest: A Theory of Divergent Goals with Applications to Politics. Markham: ChicagoGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1997. The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-based Models of Competition and Collaboration. Princeton University Press: PrincetonGoogle Scholar
Bailer, S. 2004. ‘Bargaining success in the European Union: the impact of exogenous and endogenous power resources’, European Union Politics 5: 99–124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailer, S. and Schneider, G. 2002. ‘Macht und Einfluss in EU-Verhandlungen: das Integrationsdilemma Deutschlands in vergleichender Perspektive’, in Hegmann, H. and Neumärker, B. (eds.) Die Europäische Union aus Politökonomischer Perspektive. Marburg: Metropolis, pp. 177–203Google Scholar
Bailer-Jones, D. 2003. ‘When scientific models represent’, International Studies in the Philosophy of Science 17: 59–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R., Berglöf, E., Giavazzi, F. and Widgrén, M. 2000. ‘The EU reforms for tomorrow's Europe’, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 2623
Baldwin, R., Berglöf, E., Giavazzi, F. and Widgrén, M. 2001. ‘Nice try – should the Treaty of Nice be ratified, monitoring European integration 11’, London, Centre for Economic Policy Research
Baldwin, R. and Widgrén, M. 2004a. ‘Winners and losers under various dual majority schemes’ in Wiberg, M. (ed.) Reasoned Choices – Essays in Honor of Academy Professor Hannu Nurmi on the Occasion of his 60th Birthday. The Finnish Political Science AsssociationGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Widgrén, M. 2004b. ‘Council voting in the Constitutional Treaty: devil in the details’, Centre for European Policy Research Policy Brief 53
Banfield, E. C. 1961. Political Influence. Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, J. F. 1965. ‘Weighted voting doesn't work’, Rutgers Law Review 19: 317–43Google Scholar
Baron, D. P. 1991. ‘Majoritarian incentives, pork barrel programs, and procedural control’, American Journal of Political Science 35: 57–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, D. P. and Ferejohn, J. A. 1989. ‘Bargaining in legislatures’, American Political Science Review 83: 1181–1206CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barr, J. and Passarelli, F. 2004. ‘Who has the power in the EU?’ Dartmouth College and Bocconi University, working paper
Bartels, L. M. 1997. ‘Specification uncertainty and model averaging’, American Journal of Political Science 41: 641–674CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentley, A. F. 1967 [1908]. The Process of Government. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergman, T. 1997. ‘National parliaments and EU affairs committees – notes on empirical variation and competing explanations’, Journal of European Public Policy 4: 272–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berveling, J. 1994. Het Stempel op de Besluitvorming. Macht, Invloed en Besluitvormig op Twee Amsterdamse Beleidsterreinen. Amsterdam: Thesis PublishersGoogle Scholar
Beyers, J. and Dierickx, G. 1997. ‘Nationality and European negotiations. The working groups of the Council of Ministers’, European Journal of International Relations 4: 435–471CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K. 1987a. ‘Nash bargaining theory’, in Binmore, K. and Dasgupta, P. (eds.) The Economics of Bargaining. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 27–46Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1987b. ‘Perfect equilibria in bargaining models’, in Binmore, K. and Dasgupta, P. (eds.) The Economics of Bargaining. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 77–105Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1998. Game Theory and the Social Contract II. Just Playing. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Black, D. 1958. Theories of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Bouwen, R. 1993. ‘Organizational innovation as a social construction: managing meaning in multiple realities’, in Lindenberg, S. and Schreuder, H. (eds.) Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies. Oxford: Pergamon Press, pp. 133–149Google Scholar
Brams, S. J. 1975. Game Theory and Politics. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Brams, S. J. and Affuso, P. 1985. ‘New paradoxes of voting power on the EC Council of Ministers’, Electoral Studies 4: 135–139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brams, S. J. and Fishburn, P. C. 1983. Approval Voting. Boston: BirkhauserGoogle Scholar
Bräuninger, T., Cornelius, T., König, T. and Schuster, T. 2001. ‘The dynamics of European integration. A constitutional analysis of the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference’, in Schneider, G. and Aspinwall, M. D. (eds.) The Rules of Integration. Institutionalist Approaches to the Study of Europe. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 46–68Google Scholar
Broscheid, A. and Coen, D. 2003. ‘Insider and outsider lobbying of the European Commission’, European Union Politics 4: 165–190CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryce, J. 1893. The American Commonwealth, 2 vols. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, B. 1994. ‘Political forecasting: an expected utility model’, in Mesquita, Bueno B. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) 1994. European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 71–104Google Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. 2000. Principles of International Politics. People's Power, Preferences and Perceptions. Washington: CQ PressGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. 2002. Predicting Politics. Columbus: The Ohio State University PressGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. 2004. ‘Decision making models, rigor and new puzzles’, European Union Politics 5: 125–138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B., Newman, D. and Rabushka, A. 1985. Forecasting Political Events: The Future of Hong Kong. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Mesquita, Bueno B. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) 1994. European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Butler, C. K. 2004. ‘Compromise and the two-level game. Modeling compromise at the international table’, Conflict Management and Peace Science 21: 159–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, D. R. 1992. ‘The 1992 initiative: causes and consequences’, in Sbragia, A. M. (ed.) Euro-Politics: Institutions and Policymaking in the ‘New’ European Community. Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution, pp. 23–74Google Scholar
Caplin, A. and Nalebuff, B. 1988. ‘On 64%–majority rule’, Econometrica 56: 787–814CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplin, A. and Nalebuff, B. 1991. ‘Aggregation and social choice: a mean voter theorem’, Econometrica 59: 1–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruba, C. J., Gabel, M., Murrah, L., Clough, R., Montegomery, E. and Schambach, R. 2004. ‘Off the record: unrecorded legislative votes, selection bias, and roll-call vote analysis’, unpublished manuscript
Carrubba, C. J. and Volden, C. 2000. ‘Coalitional politics and logrolling in legislative institutions’, American Journal of Political Science 44: 255–271CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chong, D. 1991. Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Clarke, K. A. 2003. ‘Nonparametric model discrimination in international relations’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 47: 72–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1966a. ‘The possibility of a social welfare function’, American Economic Review 56: 1105–1122Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1966b. ‘Foundations for a theory of collective decisions’, American Journal of Sociology 71: 615–627CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Coleman, J. S. 1971. ‘Foundations for a theory of social action’, American Journal of Sociology 76: 615–627Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University.Google Scholar
Corbett, R. 2000. ‘Academic modelling of the codecision procedure: a practitioner's puzzled reaction’, European Union Politics 1: 373–8Google Scholar
Corbett, R. 2001. ‘A response to a reply to a reaction (I hope someone is still interested!)’, European Union Politics 2: 361–4Google Scholar
Council of the European Communities 1990. The Council of the European Community. Luxembourg: Office of Official Publications of the European Communities
Council of the European Union 2000. ‘A-item note: vertical directives on foodstuffs: proposal for a Council directive relating to honey, political agreement’, COREPER Document 8701/00, 24 May 2000
Crombez, C. 1996. ‘Legislative procedures in the European Community’, British Journal of Political Science 26: 199–288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 1997. ‘The co-decision procedure in the European Union’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 22: 97–119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000a. ‘Institutional reform and co-decision in the European Union’, Constitutional Political Economy 11: 41–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000b. ‘Co-decision: ‘towards a bicameral European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 363–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000c. ‘Spatial models of logrolling in the European Union’, European Journal of Political Economy 16: 707–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2001. ‘The Treaty of Amsterdam and the co-decision procedure’, in Schneider, G. and Aspinwall, M. D. (eds.) The Rules of Integration. Institutionalist Approaches to the Study of Europe. Manchester: Manchester University Press, pp. 101–122Google Scholar
Crombez, C. 2002. ‘Information, lobbying and the legislative process in the European Union’, European Union Politics 3: 7–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2003. ‘The democratic deficit in the European Union’, European Union Politics 4: 101–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C., Steunenberg, B. and Corbett, R. 2000. ‘Understanding the EU legislative process: political scientists' and practitioners' perspectives’, European Union Politics 1: 365–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dai, X. 2002. ‘Political regimes and international trade: the democratic difference revisited’, American Political Science Review 96: 159–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, O., Groot, M. and Hinich, M. 1972. ‘Social preference orderings and majority rule’, Econometrica 40: 147–157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gooijer, J. G. 2002. ‘Introduction to forecasting decisions in conflict situations’, International Journal of Forecasting 1: 319–320CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swaan, A. 1973. Coalition Theories and Cabinet Formation. Elsevier Scientific Publishing Company: AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
De Vries, M. 1999. Governing with your Closest Neighbour: An Assessment of Spatial Coalition Formation Theories. Ph.D Thesis. University of Nijmegen
Zwaan, J. W. 1995. The Permanent Representatives Committee: its Role in European Union Decision-making. Amsterdam, New York: ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Dimitrova, A. and Steunenberg, B. 2001. ‘The search for convergence of national policies in the European Union: an impossible quest?European Union Politics. 1: 201–226CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dinan, D. 1999. Ever Closer Union. An Introduction to European Integration. Boulder/London: Lynne RiennerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbins, M., Drüner, D. and Schneider, G. 2004. ‘Kopenhagener Konsequenzen: Gesetzgebung in der EU vor und nach der Erweiterung’, Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 35: 51–68Google Scholar
Dowding, K. 2000. ‘Institutionalist research on the European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 125–144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dowding, K. 2002. ‘Rational choice and institutional change: an overview of current theories’, in Steunenberg, B. (ed.) Widening the European Union: The Politics of Institutional Reform and Change. London: Routledge, pp. 21–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and RowGoogle Scholar
Edwards, G. 1996. ‘National sovereignty vs. integration? The Council of Ministers’, in Richardson, J. (ed.) European Union: Power and Policy-making. London: Routledge, pp. 127–147CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. and Roemer, J. E. 1991. Interpersonal Comparisons of Well–being. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enelow, J. M. and Hinich, M. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Erev, I., Roth, A. E., Slonim, R. L. and Barron, G. 2002. ‘Predictive value and the usefulness of game theoretic models’, International Journal of Forecasting 18: 359–368CrossRefGoogle Scholar
European Commission 1996. ‘Proposal for a Council directive relating to honey’, Official Journal C 231, 9 August 1996, 10
European Commission 2001. General Report on the Activities of the European Union, 2000. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities
Evans, P. B. 1993. ‘Building an integrative approach to international and domestic politics: reflections and projections’, in Evans, P. B., Jacobson, H. K. and Putnam, R. D. (eds.) Double-edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 397–430Google Scholar
Evans, P. B., Jacobson, H. K. and Putnam, R. O. (eds.) 1993. Double-edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Farrell, H. and Héritier, A. 2003. ‘Formal and informal institutions under codecision: continuous constitution-building in Europe’, Governance 16: 577–600Google Scholar
Farrell, H. and Héritier, A., 2004. ‘Interorganizational negotiation and intraorganizational power in shared decision-making: early agreements under codecision and their impact on the European Parliament and Council’, Comparative Political Studies 37: 1184–1212CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1994. ‘Domestic political audiences and the escalation of international disputes’, American Political Science Review 90: 715–735CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feder, S. A. 1987. ‘FACTIONS and Policon: new ways to analyze politics’, Studies in Intelligence 31: 41–57. Originally classified ‘Secret.’ Reprinted in Bradford Westerfield, H. 1995. Inside CIA's Private World. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 274–292
Feld, L., Kirchgässner, G. and Weck-Hannemann, H. 2002. ‘Enlargement and the European budget: budgetary decision making and fiscal constraints’, in Steunenberg, B. (ed.) Widening the European Union: The Politics of Institutional Reform and Change. London: Routledge, pp. 144–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felsenthal, D. and Machover, M. 1998. The Measurement of Voting Power. Theory and Practice, Problems and Paradoxes. Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Felsenthal, D. S. and Machover, M. 2001a. ‘Myths and meanings of voting power’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 13: 81–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Felsenthal, D. S. and Machover, M. 2001b. ‘The Treaty of Nice and qualified majority voting’, Social Choice and Welfare 18: 431–464CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, R. J. Jr. 1999. ‘Partially independent central banks, politically responsive governments, and inflation’, American Journal of Political Science 43: 681–706CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E. and Johnsen, E. C. 1990. ‘Social influence and opinion’, Journal of Mathematical Sociology 15: 193–205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E. and Johnsen, E. C. 1997. ‘Social positions in influence networks’, Social Networks 19: 209–222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E. and Johnsen, C. 1999. ‘Social influence networks and opinion change’, Advances in Group Processes 16: 1–29Google Scholar
Friedman, J. W. 1990. Game Theory with Applications to Economics. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Levine, D. K. 1998. The Theory of Learning in Games. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Gabel, M., Hix, S. and Schneider, G. 2002. ‘Who is afraid of cumulative research? Improving data on EU politics’, European Union Politics 3: 481–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. 1995. ‘From the Luxembourg compromise to codecision: decision making in the European Union’, Electoral Studies 50: 289–308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1996. ‘An institutional critique of intergovernmentalism’, International Organization 50: 269–299CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1997. ‘More on the codecision endgame’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 139–143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1999a. ‘Why resist the temptation to apply power indices to the EU?’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 291–308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 1999b. ‘More reasons to resist the temptation to apply power indices to the EU’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 331–338CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 2001a. ‘Understanding better the EU legislative process’, European Union Politics 2: 353–361CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, G. and Tsebelis, G. 2001b. ‘Even more reasons to resist the temptation to apply power indices to the EU’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 13: 99–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaver, K. M. and Geisel, M. S. 1974. ‘Discriminating among alternative models: Bayesian and non–Bayesian approaches’, in Zarembka, P. (ed.) Frontiers in Econometrics. New York: Academic, pp. 49–77Google Scholar
Gilligan, T. and Krehbiel, K. 1995. ‘The gains from exchange hypothesis of legislative organization’, in Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (eds.) Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grafstein, R. 1992. Institutional Realism. New Haven: Yale University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granger, C. W. J. and Newbold, P. 1986. Forecasting Economic Time Series, 2nd ed. Orlando, Florida: AcademicGoogle Scholar
Greenberg, J. 1979. ‘Consistent majority rule over compact sets of alternatives’, Econometrica 47: 627–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gul, F. 1989. ‘Bargaining foundations of Shapley value’, Econometrica 57: 81–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haas, E. B. 1958. The Uniting of Europe. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Haas, E. B. 1975. The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory. Berkeley: Institute of International StudiesGoogle Scholar
Hall, P. and Taylor, R. 1996. ‘Political science and the three new institutionalisms’, Political Studies 44: 936–957CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, T. H. and Miller, G. J. 1987. ‘The core of the constitution’, American Political Science Review 81: 1155–174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammond, T. H. and Prins, B. C. 1999. ‘The impact of domestic institutions on international negotiations: a taxonomy of results from a complete-information spatial model’, paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, Georgia, 2–5 September 1999
Harsanyi, J. C. 1963. ‘A simplified bargaining model for the n-person cooperative game’, International Economic Review 4: 194–220CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. 1977. Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, S. and Mas-Colell, A. 1996. ‘Bargaining and value’, Econometrica 64: 357–380CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayes-Renshaw, F. 2001. ‘The Council and enlargement: a challenge or an opportunity?’, Journal of International Relations and Development 4: 9–12Google Scholar
Hayes-Renshaw, F. and Wallace, H. 1995. ‘Executive power in the European Union: the functions and limits of the Council of Ministers’, Journal of European Public Policy 2: 559–582Google Scholar
Hayes-Renshaw, F. and Wallace, H. 1997. The Council of Ministers. Basingstoke: Macmillan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herstein, I. N. and Milnor, J. 1953. ‘An axiomatic approach to measurable utility’, Econometrica 21: 291–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. J. and Munger, M. C. 1994. Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. and Munger, M. C. 1997. Analytical Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. 1998. ‘The study of the European Union II: the ‘New Governance’ agenda and its rival’, Journal of European Public Policy 5: 38–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. 1999. The Political System of the European Union. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S. and Lord, C. 1997. Political Parties in the European Union. New York: St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffmann, S. 1966. ‘Obstinate or obsolete? The face of the nation State and the case of Western Europe’, Daedalus, 95: 892–908Google Scholar
Holler, M. J. 1994. ‘Comment’, in Herder-Dorneich, P., Schenk, K. E. and Schmidtchen, D. (eds.) Neue Politische Ökonomie der Reguliering, Dereguliering and Privatisierung (Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, Volume 13). Tübingen: Mohr, pp. 66–71Google Scholar
Holler, M. J. and Widgrén, M. 1999. ‘Why power indices for assessing EU decision-making’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 321–330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. 1993. ‘Admission of European Free Trade Association states to the European Community: effects of voting power in the European Community Council of Ministers’, International Organization 47: 629–643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. 1995. ‘The balance between small and large: effects of a double-majority system on voting power in the European Union’, International Studies Quarterly 39: 351–370CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. 2000. ‘Smaller states and the new voting weights in the Council’, working paper. Clingendael Institute of International Relations: The Hague
Hosli, M. O. and Machover, M. 2004. ‘The Nice Treaty and voting rules in the Council: a reply to Moberg (2002)’, Journal of Common Market Studies 42: 497–521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. and Van Deemen, A. 2002. ‘Effects of enlargement on efficiency and coalition formation in the Council of the European Union’, in Hosli, M. O., Deemen, A. and Widgrén, M. (eds.) Institutional Challenges in the European Union. London: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosli, M. O. and Wolffenbuttel, R. F. 2001. ‘Estimating the vote distribution in the Council of the European Union’, Journal of International Relations and Development 4: 38–54Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1929. ‘Stability in competition’, Economic Journal 39: 41–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, J. and Inglehart, R. 1995. ‘Expert interpretations of party space and party locations in 42 societies’, Party Politics 1: 73–111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubschmid, C. and Moser, P. 1997. ‘The cooperation procedure in the EU: why was the European Parliament influential in the decision on car emission standards’, Journal of Comman Market Studies 35: 225–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hug, S. 2002. Voices of Europe. Citizens, Referendums and European Integration. Lanham: Rowman and LittlefieldGoogle Scholar
Hug, S. and Christin, T. 2002. ‘Referendums and citizen support for European integration’, Comparative Political Studies 5: 586–618Google Scholar
Hug, S. and König, T. 2002. ‘In view of ratification: governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference’, International Organization 56: 447–476CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iida, K. 1993. ‘When and how do domestic constraints matter? Two-level games with uncertainty’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 37: 403–426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, H. and Broder, D. 1996. The System. Boston: Little BrownGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Smorodinsky, M. 1975. ‘Other solutions to Nash's bargaining problem’, Econometrica 43: 513–518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kasack, C. 2004. ‘The legislative impact of the European Parliament under the revised co-decision procedure. Environmental, public health and consumer protection policies’, European Union Politics 5: 241–260CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kauppi, H. and Widgrén, M. 2004. ‘What determines EU decision-making: needs, power or both?’, Economic Policy 39, 221–266Google Scholar
Keeney, R. L. and Raiffa, H. 1993. Decisions with Multiple Objectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirman, A. and Widgrén, M. 1995. ‘European economic decision-making policy: Progress or paralysis?’, Economic Policy 21: 421–460CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knoke, D., Pappi, F. U. and Broadbent, J. 1996. Comparing Policy Networks: Labor Politics in the US, Germany, and Japan, Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, K. 2003. ‘The rotating presidency of the European Union as a search for good policies’, European Union Politics 4: 51–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. 1992. Entscheidungen im Politiknetzwerkβ: Der Einflua von Organisationen auf die Arbeits- und Sozialrechtliche Gesetzgebung in den 80er Jahren. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitäts-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. 1997. Europa auf dem Weg zum Mehrebenensystem. Gründe und konsequenzen nationaler und parlamentarischer Integration. Opladen: Westdeutscher VerlagGoogle Scholar
König, T. and Bräuninger, T. 1998. ‘The inclusiveness of European decision rules’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 10: 125–141CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. and Bräuninger, T. 2000. ‘Governing the enlarged European Union: accession scenarios and institutional reform’, Central European Political Science Review 1: 42–62Google Scholar
König, T. and Hug, S. 2000. ‘Ratifying Maastricht, parliamentary votes on international treaties and theoretical solution concepts’, European Union Politics 1: 89–122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T. and Pöter, M. 2001. ‘Examining the EU legislative process: the relative importance of agenda and veto power’, European Union Politics 2: 329–351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1988. ‘Spatial models of legislative choice’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 13: 259–319CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1991. Information and Legislative Organization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. 1998. Pivotal Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreppel, A. 1999. ‘The European Parliament's influence over EU policy outcomes’, Journal of Common Market Studies 37: 521–538CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, J. E. and Ersson, S. 2000. The New Institutional Politics. Performance and Outcomes. London and New York: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
LaPalombara, J. 1960. ‘The utility and limitations of interest group theory in non-American field situations’, Journal of Politics 22: 29–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laruelle, A. 1998. ‘The EU decision making procedures: some insight from non-cooperative game theory’, IRES Discussion Papers, 97/27
Laruelle, A. 2002. ‘The EU decision making procedures: some insight from non-cooperative game theory’, in Hosli, M., Deemen, A. and Widgrén, M. (eds.) Institutional Challenges in the European Union. London: Routledge, pp. 89–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laruelle, A. and Widgrén, M. 1998. ‘Is the allocation of power among EU states fair?’, Public Choice 94: 317–339CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laruelle, A. and Widgrén, M. 2001. ‘Voting power in a sequence of cooperative games’, in Holler, M. and Owen, G. (eds.) Voting Power And Coalition Formation. Dortrecht and Boston: Kluwer Academic PublishersCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M. and Shepsle, K. 1996. Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leech, D. 2002. ‘Designing the voting system for the Council of Ministers of the European Union’, Public Choice 113: 437–464CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leenders, R. Th. A. J. 1995. Structure and Influence. Statistical Models for the Dynamics of Actor Attributes, Network Structure and their Interdependence. Amsterdam: Thesis PublishersGoogle Scholar
Leenders, R. Th. A. J. 2002. ‘Modeling social influence through network autocorrelation: constructing the weight matrix’, Social Networks 24: 21–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewin, L. 1991. Self-interest and Public Interest in Western Politics. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, J. 2000. ‘The methods of community in EU decision-making and administrative rivalry in the council's infrastructure’, Journal of European Public Policy 7: 261–289CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, L. N. 1963. The Political Dynamics of European Economic Integration. Stanford: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lindblom, C. E. 1965. The Intelligence of Democracy. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Lindenberg, S. 1997. ‘Grounding groups in theory: functional, structural and cognitive interdependencies’, Advances in Group Processes 14: 281–331Google Scholar
Lindenberg, S. 2001. ‘Social rationality versus rational egoism’, in Turner, J. H. (ed.) Handbook of Social Theory. New York: Kluwer Academic and Plenum PublishersGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, S. 1997. ‘Linkage Politics’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41: 38–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowndes, V. 2002. ‘Institutionalism’, in Marsh, D. and Stoker, G. (eds.) Theory and Methods in Political Science. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 90–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manley, J. F. 1970. The Politics of Finance. Boston: Little, BrownGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 2000. ‘Free to trade: democracies, autocracies and international trade’, American Political Science Review 94: 305–322CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 2002. ‘Replication, realism, and robustness: analyzing political regimes and international trade’, American Political Science Review 96: 167–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. G. and Olsen, J. P. 1984. ‘The new institutionalism: organizational factors in political life’, American Political Science Review 78: 734–749CrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, J. and Olsen, J. 1989. Rediscovering Institutions: the Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: The Free PressGoogle Scholar
Marks, G., Hooghe, L. and Blank, K. 1996. ‘European integration in the 1980s: state-centric vs. multi-level governance’, Journal of Common Market Studies 34: 341–378CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsden, P. V. and Friedkin, N. E. 1993. ‘Network studies of social influence’, Sociological Methods and Research 22: 127–151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, L. 2000. Democratic Commitments-Legislatures and International Cooperation. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D. and Green, J. R. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Mattila, M. and Lane, J. E. 2001. ‘Why unanimity in the Council? A roll call analysis of Council voting’, European Union Politics 2: 31–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mavrogordatos, G. 1984. ‘The Greek party system: a case of limited but polarised pluralism’, West European Politics 7: 156–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. 1976. ‘Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control’, Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–182CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D. 1979. ‘General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models’, Econometrica 47: 1085–1112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., Ordeshook, P. and Winer, M. 1978. ‘The competitive solution for N-person games without transferable utility: with an application for committee games’, American Political Science Review 72: 599–615CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mearsheimer, J. J. 1994–95. ‘The false promise of international institutions’. International Security 19: 5–49Google Scholar
Merlo, A. and Wilson, C. 1995. ‘A stochastic model of sequential bargaining with complete information’, Econometrica 63: 371–399CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, H. V. 1997. Interests, Institutions, and Information. Princeton: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 1996. ‘Trade negotiations, information and domestic politics’, Economics and Politics 8: 145–89Google Scholar
Milner, H. V. and Rosendorff, P. B. 1997. ‘Democratic politics and international trade negotiations. Elections and divided government as constraints on trade liberalization’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41: 117–146CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mo, J. 1995. ‘Domestic institutions and international bargaining: the role of agent veto in two-level games’, American Political Science Review 89: 914–924CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moberg, A. 2002. ‘The Nice Treaty and voting rules in the Council’, Journal of Common Market Studies 40: 259–282CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokken, R. J., Payne, D., Stokman, F. N. and Wasseur, F. W. 2000. ‘Decision context and policy effectuation: EU structural reform in Ireland’, Irish Political Studies 15: 39–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Molm, L. 1996. Coercive Power in Social Exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Moravcsik, A. 1993. ‘Introduction: integration international and domestic theories of international bargaining’, in Evans, P. B., Jacobson, H. K. and Putnam, R. D. (eds.) Double-Edged Diplomacy. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Moravcsik, A. 1998. The Choice for Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Morgan, M. S. and Morrison, M. (eds.) 1999. Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenthau, H. 1948. Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, New York: KnopfGoogle Scholar
Morrison, M. and Morgan, M. S. 1999. ‘Models as mediating instruments’, in Morgan, M. S. and Morrison, M. (eds.) Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 10–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morton, R. B. 1999. Methods and Models: A Guide to the Empirical Analysis of Formal Models in Political Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 1996. ‘The European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter: what are the conditions? A critique of Tsebelis (1994)’, American Political Science Review 90: 834–838CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 1997a. ‘A theory of the conditional influence of the European Parliament in the co-operation procedure’, Public Choice 91: 333–350CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 1997b. ‘The benefits of the conciliation procedure for the European Parliament: comment to George Tsebelis’, Aussenwirtschaft 52: 57–62Google Scholar
Moser, P D., Schneider, G. and Kirchgässner, G. 2000. Decision Rules in the European Union: a Rational Choice Perspective. New York: St. Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moulin, H. 1988. Axioms of Cooperative Decision Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, A. H. and Winkler, R. L. 1984. ‘Probability forecasting in meteorology’, Journal of the American Statistical Association 79: 489–500Google Scholar
Muthoo, A. 1999. Bargaining Theory With Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2002a. ‘Strategic power in EU decision making procedures’, unpublished manuscript
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2002b. ‘Strategic power revisited’, Munich: CESifo Working Paper No. 736
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2004a. ‘Power measurement as sensitivity analysis – a unified approach’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 16: 517–538CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Napel, S. and Widgrén, M. 2004b. ‘The inter-institutional distribution of power in EU codecision’, Munich: CESifo Working Paper No. 1347, Social Choice and Welfare, forthcoming
Nash, J. F. 1950. ‘The bargaining problem’, Econometrica 18: 155–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. F. 1953. ‘Two-person cooperative games’, Econometrica 21: 128–140CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholson, M. 1989. Formal Theories in International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Noury, A. G. 2002. ‘Ideology, nationality and Euro-Parliamentarians’, European Union Politics 3: 33–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nugent, N. 1999. The Government and Politics of the European Union. Durham: Duke University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opp, K. D. 1990. Empirischer Theorienvergleich: Erklärungen sozialen Verhaltens in Problemsituationen. Opladen: Westdeutscher VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Reilly, C. A. 1983. ‘The use of information in organizational decision making: a model and some propositions’, Research in Organizational Behaviour 5: 103–139Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 1986. ‘An agenda for the study of institutions’, Public Choice 48: 3–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owen, G. 1972. ‘Multilinear extensions of games’, Management Science 18: 64–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owen, G. 1995. Game Theory. 3rd edition. San Diego: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Pahre, R. 1997. ‘Endogenous domestic institutions in two-level games and parliamentary oversight of the European Union’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41: 147–174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pahre, R. 2001. ‘Divided government and international cooperation in Austria-Hungary, Sweden-Norway and the European Union’, European Union Politics 2: 131–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pajala, A. 2002. Expected Power and Success in Coalitions and Space: Empirical Voting Power in 17 European Parliaments and the Council of the EU. Doctoral Dissertation. Turku: University of TurkuGoogle Scholar
Pajala, A. and Widgrén, M. 2004. ‘A priori vs. empirical power in the EU Council of Ministers’, European Union Politics 5: 73–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pappi, F. U. and Henning, C. 1998. ‘Policy networks, public policy-making and visualization – policy networks: more than a metaphor?Journal of Theoretical Politics 10: 553–576CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, D. 1999. Policy Making in the European Union. An Analysis of the Impact of the Reform of the Structural Funds in Ireland. Amsterdam: Thesis PublishersGoogle Scholar
Peters, G. 1999. Institutional Theory in Political Science: the ‘New Institutionalism’. London: PinterGoogle Scholar
Peterson, J. and Bomberg, E. 1999. Decision Making in the European Union. London: Macmillan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, C. R. 1967. ‘A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule’, American Economic Review 57: 787–806Google Scholar
Plott, C. R. 1991. ‘Will economics become an experimental science?Southern Economic Journal 57: 901–920CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. D. 1988. ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-level games’, International Organization 42: 427–460CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, R. D. 1993. ‘Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-level games’ in Putnam, R. D., Evans, P. and Jacobson, H. (eds.) Double-Edged Diplomacy. International Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 431–468Google Scholar
Rabinowitz, G. and MacDonald, S. E. 1986. ‘The power of the states in US presidential elections’, American Political Science Review 80: 65–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raftery, A. E. 1995. ‘Bayesian model selection in social research’, Sociological Methodology 25: 111–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raiffa, H. 1953. ‘Arbitration schemes for generalized two-person games’, in Kuhn, H. W. and Tucker, A. (eds.) Contribution to the Theory of Games II: Annals of Mathematics Studies. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 361–387Google Scholar
Raub, W. and Weesie, J. 1990. ‘Reputation and efficiency in social interactions: an example of network effects’, American Journal of Sociology 96: 626–654CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, J. L. and Russet, B. 1996. ‘The future as arbiter of theoretical controversies: predictions, explanations and the end of the cold war’, British Journal of Political Sciences 26: 441–470CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, J. L. and Singer, D. J. 1990. ‘Measuring the concentration of power in the international system’, in Singer, D. J. and Diehl, P. F. (eds.) Measuring the Correlates of War. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Richardson, J. (ed.) 1996. European Union: Power and Policy-making. London: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, W. H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Riker, W. H. 1980. ‘Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions’, American Political Science Review 74: 432–446CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, W. H. and Brams, S. J. 1973. ‘The paradox of vote trading’, American Political Science Review 67: 1235–1247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riley, J. 1988. Liberal Utilitarianism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Robert, C. P. 2001. The Bayesian Choice, 2nd ed. New York: SpringerGoogle Scholar
Rojer, M. 1999. ‘Collective decision-making models applied to labour negotiations in the Netherlands: a comparison between a position exchange model and a conflict model’, Rationality and Society 11: 207–235CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. 1979. Axiomatic Models of Bargaining. Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 1982. ‘Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model’, Econometrica 50: 97–109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 2000. Economics and Language. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, T. C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G. 1994. ‘Getting closer at different speeds: strategic interaction in widening European integration’, in Allan, P. and Schmidt, C. (eds.) Game Theory and International Relations. Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G. 1995. ‘Agenda-setting in European integration: the conflict between voters, governments and supranational institutions’, in Laursen, F. (ed.) The Political Economy of European Integration. Maastricht: European Institute of Public Administration, pp. 31–61Google Scholar
Schneider, G. and Aspinwall, M. D. (eds.) 2001. The Rules of Integration. Institutionalist Approaches to the Study of Europe. Manchester: Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G. and Baltz, K. 2003. ‘The power of specialization: how interest groups influence EU-legislation’, Rivista die Politica Economica XCIII: 253–283Google Scholar
Schneider, G. and Baltz, K. 2005. ‘Domesticated Eurocrats: bureaucratic discretion in the legislative pre-negotiations of the European Union’, Acta Politica, forthcoming
Schneider, G. and Cederman, L. E. 1994. ‘The change of tide in political cooperation: a limited information model of European integration’, International Organization 48: 633–662CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G., Finke, D. and Bailer, S. 2004. ‘Bargaining power: an evaluation of competing models’, University of Konstanz, working paper
Schneider, G. and Weitsman, P. A. 1996. ‘The punishment trap: integration referendums as popularity contests’, Comparative Political Studies 28: 582–607CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, N. 1978. ‘Instability of simple dynamic games’, Review of Economic Studies 45: 575–594CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scully, R. M. 1997a. ‘The European Parliament and the co-decision procedure: a reassessment’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 58–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scully, R. M. 1997b. ‘The European Parliament and co-decision: a rejoinder to Tsebelis and Garrett’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 93–103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selck, T. J. 2004. ‘On the dimensionality of European Union legislative decision making’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 16: 203–222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selck, T. J. and Steunenberg, B. 2004. ‘Between power and luck: the European Parliament in the EU legislative process’, European Union Politics 5: 25–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapley, L. S. 1953. ‘A value for n-person cooperative games’, in Kuhn, H. and Tucker, A. (eds.) Contributions to the Theory of Games,vol II. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 343–459Google Scholar
Shapley, L. S. 1977. ‘A comparison of power indices and a non-symmetric generalization’, RAND Corporation, Paper P-5872
Shapley, L. S. and Shubik, M. 1954. ‘A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system’, American Political Science Review 48: 787–792CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. 1979. ‘Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models’, American Journal of Political Science 32: 27–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. 1989. ‘Studying institutions: some lessons from the rational choice approach’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 1: 131–147CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1981. ‘Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice’, Public Choice 37: 503–519CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1984. ‘Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda institutions’, American Journal of Political Science 28: 49–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1987. ‘Why are congressional committees powerful?’ American Political Science Review 81: 935–45Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. 1995. ‘Positive theories of congressional institutions’, in Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (eds.) Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 5–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherrington, P. 1999. The Council of Ministers: Political Authority in the European Union. London and New York: PinterGoogle Scholar
Shubik, M. 1982. Game Theory in the Social Sciences. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Signorino, C. S. 1999. ‘Estimation and strategic interaction in discrete choice models of international conflict’, American Political Science Review 92: 279–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singer, D. J. 1969. ‘The incomplete theorist: insight without evidence’, in Rosenau, J. N. and Knorr, K. (eds.) Contending Approaches to International Politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 63–86Google Scholar
Snidal, D. 1994. ‘The politics of scope: endogenous actors, heterogeneity and institutions’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 6: 449–472CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soetendorp, B. and Hosli, M. O. 2001. ‘The hidden dynamics of EU Council decision making’, Acta Politica 4, 252–287Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1994a. ‘Decision-making under different institutional arrangements: legislation by the European Community’, Journal of Theoretical and Institutional Economics 150: 642–669Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1994b. ‘Regulatory policymaking in a parliamentary setting’ in Herder-Dorneich, P.Schenk, K. E. and Schmidtchen, D. (eds.) Neue Politische Ökonomie der Reguliering, Dereguliering and Privatisierung (Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, Volume 13). Tübingen: Mohr, pp. 36–57Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1997. ‘Codecision and its reform: a comparative analysis of decision making rules in the European Union’, in Steunenberg, B. and Vught, F. A. (eds.) Political Institutions and Public Policy: Perspectives on European Decision Making. Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 205–229CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2000a. ‘Constitutional change in the European Union: parliament's impact on the reform of the codecision procedure’, in Wagenaar, H. (ed.) Government Institutions: Effects, Changes and Normative Foundations. Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 89–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2000b. ‘Seeing what you want to see: the limits of current modelling on the European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 368–373Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2001. ‘Enlargement and institutional reform in the European Union: separate or connected issues?Constitutional Political Economy 12: 349–368CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2002a. ‘Playing different games: the European Parliament and the reform of codecision’, in Steunenberg, B. and Thomassen, J. (eds.) The European Parliament: Moving Toward Democracy in the EU. Boulder: Rowman and Littlefield, pp. 163–83Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 2002b. ‘An even wider Union: the effects of enlargement on EU decision-making’, in Steunenberg, B. (ed.) Widening the European Union: The Politics of Institutional Change and Reform. London and New York: Routledge, pp. 97–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B. and Dimitrova, A. 1999. Interests, Legitimacy, and Constitutional Choice: the Extension of the Codecision Procedure in Amsterdam. Enschede: University of Twente. MimeoGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B., Koboldt, C. and Schmidtchen, D. 1996. ‘Policymaking, comitology, and the balance of power in the European Union’, International Review of Law and Economics 16: 329–344CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steunenberg, B.Koboldt, C. and Schmidtchen, D. 1997. ‘Beyond comitology: a comparative analysis of implementation procedures with parliamentary involvement’, Aussenwirtschaft 52: 87–112Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B., Schmidtchen, D. and Koboldt, C. 1999. ‘Strategic power in the European Union: evaluating the distribution of power in policy games’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 11: 339–366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigum, B. 1990. Towards a Formal Science of Economics. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Stokman, F. N. 2004. ‘What binds us when with whom? Content and structure in social network analysis’, extended version of keynote at the SUNBELT XXIV International Social Network Conference, Portorož (Slovenia), May 13 2004 (www.oprit.rug.nl/stokman/articles.htm)
Stokman, F. N. 2005. ‘Was verbindet uns wann mit wem? Inhalt und Struktur in der Analyse Sozialer Netzwerke’, Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie (forthcoming)
Stokman, F. N. and Thomson, R. (eds.) 2004. ‘Special issue: winners and losers in the European Union’, European Union Politics 5: 1–138CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokman, F. N., Assen, M., Knoop, Jan J. and Oosten, R. 2000. ‘Strategic decision making’, Advances in Group Processes 17: 131–153Google Scholar
Stokman, F. N. and Van den Bos, J. M. M. 1992. ‘A two–stage model of policymaking with an empirical test in the US energy-policy domain’, in Moore, G. and Whitt, Allen J. (eds.) The Political Consequences of Social Networks. Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press, pp. 219–253Google Scholar
Stokman, F. N. and Van Oosten, R. 1994. ‘The exchange of voting positions: an object-oriented model of policy networks’, in Mesquita, Bueno B. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) European Community Decision Making: Models, Applications and Comparisons. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 105–127Google Scholar
Stokman, F. N. and Zeggelink, E. P. H. 1996. ‘Is politics power or policy oriented? A comparative analysis of dynamic access models in policy networks’, Journal of Mathematical Sociology 21: 77–111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sweet, Stone A. and Sandholtz, W. (eds.) 1998. Supranational Governance: The Institutionalization of the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Straffin, P. D. 1977. ‘Homogeneity, independence and power indices’, Public Choice 30: 107–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straffin, P. D 1988. ‘The Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf power indices as probabilities’, in Roth, A. (ed.) The Shapley Value. Essays in Honor of Lloyd Shapley. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stratmann, T. 1997. ‘Logrolling’, in Mueller, D. C. (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Tallberg, J. 2003. ‘The agenda-shaping powers of the EU Council presidency’, Journal of European Public Policy 10: 1–19Google Scholar
Tarar, A. 2001. ‘International bargaining with two-sided domestic constraints’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 320–340CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomson, R., Boerefijn, J. and Stokman, F. N. 2004. ‘Actor alignments in European Union decision-making’. European Journal of Political Research 43: 237–261Google Scholar
Thomson, R., Torenvlied, R. and Stokman, F. N. (eds.) 2003. ‘Special issue: models of collective decision-making’, Rationality and Society 15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tollison, R. and Willet, T.. 1979. ‘An economic theory of mutually advantageous issue linkage in international organizations’, International Organization 4: 425–449CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1994. ‘The power of the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter’, American Political Science Review 88: 128–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1995. ‘Will Maastricht reduce the ‘democratic deficit’?’ APSA Comparative Politics 6: 4–6Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1996. ‘More on the European Parliament as a conditional agenda setter: response to Moser’, American Political Science Review 90: 839–844CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1997. ‘Maastricht and the democratic deficit’, Aussenwirtschaft 52: 29–56Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 1996. ‘Agenda setting power, power indices, and decision making in the European Union’, International Review of Law and Economics 16: 345–361CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 1997a. ‘Agenda setting, vetoes and the European Union's co-decision procedure’, Journal of Legislative Studies 3: 74–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 1997b. ‘Why power indices cannot explain decisionmaking in the European Union’, in Schmidtchen, D. and Cooter, R. (eds.) Constitutional Law and Economics of the European Union. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 11–31Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 2000. ‘Legislative politics in the European Union’, European Union Politics 1: 5–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Garrett, G. 2001. ‘The institutional foundations of intergovernmentalism and supranationalism in the European Union’, International Organization 55: 357–390CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G., Jensen, C., Kalandrakis, A. and Kreppel, A. 2001Legislative procedures in the European Union: an empirical analysis’, British Journal of Political Science 31: 373–399CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Kalandrakis, A. 1999. ‘The european parliament and environmental legislation: the case of chemicals’, European Journal of Political Research 36: 119–154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and Money, J. 1997. Bicameralism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. 1959. ‘Some problems of majority voting’, Journal of Political Economy 67: 571–579CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Assen, M. 2001. Essays on Actor Models in Exchange Networks and Social Dilemmas. Amsterdam: Thela ThesisGoogle Scholar
Assen, M., Stokman, F. N. and Oosten, R. C. H. 2003. ‘Conflict measures in cooperative position exchange models of collective decision-making’, Rationality and Society 15: 64–84Google Scholar
Deemen, A. 1997. Coalition Formation and Social Choice, Amsterdam: KluwerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Deemen, A. and Hosli, M. O. 1999. ‘Conflict and cooperation in collective decision-making systems’, working paper
Van den Bogaard, A. 1999. ‘Past measurement and future prediction’, in Morgan, M. S. and Morrison, M. (eds.) Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 282–325CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bos, J. M. M. 1991. Dutch EC Policy Making. A Model-Guided Approach to Coordination and Negotiation. Amsterdam: Thela ThesisGoogle Scholar
Doel, J. and Velthoven, B. 1993. Democracy and Welfare Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hees, M. and Steunenberg, B. 2000. ‘The choices judges make: court rulings, personal values, and legal constraints’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 12: 299–317Google Scholar
Schendelen, R. 2002. Machiavelli in Brussels: The Art of Lobbying the EU. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, R. H. 2004. ‘Bargaining and conflict resolution’, in Maoz, Z., Mintz, A., Clifton Margan, T., Palmer, G. and Stoll, R. J. (eds.) Multiple Paths to Knowledge in International Relations. Lexington: Lexington Books, pp. 39–72Google Scholar
Wallace, W. 2000. ‘Collective governance’, in Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (eds.) Policy-Making in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 523–542Google Scholar
Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (eds.) 1996. Policy-Making in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Wallace, H. and Wallace, W. (eds.)2000. Policy-Making in the European Union 4th edition. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Ward, H. 2002. ‘Rational choice’, in Marsh, D. and Stoker, G. (eds.) Theory and Methods in Political Science. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 65–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weibull, J. W. 1995. Evolutionary Game Theory. Cambridge: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Weick, K. E. 1979. The Social Psychology of Organizing. Reading: Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Weiler, J. H. H. 1999. The Constitution of Europe. ‘Do the New Clothes Have an Emperor?’ and other essays on European Integration. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Weingast, B. R. and Marshall, W. J. 1988. ‘The industrial organization of congress; or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets’, Journal of Political Economy 96: 132–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Westlake, M. 1994. A Modern Guide to the European Parliament. London: PinterGoogle Scholar
Westlake, M. 1995. The Council of the European Union. London: CatermillGoogle Scholar
Widgrén, M. 1994. ‘Voting power in the EC and the consequences of two different enlargements’, European Economic Review 38: 1153–1170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Widgrén, M. 1995. ‘Probabilistic voting power in the EU Council: the cases of trade policy and social regulation’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97: 345–356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, W. 1885. Congressional Government. Boston: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Zimmer, C., Schneider, G. and Dobbins, M. 2005. ‘The contested Council: conflict dimensions of an intergovernmental EU institution’, Political Studies 53: 403–422CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×