Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-995ml Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T06:23:33.927Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

14 - The Truth of the market

from Part V - Conceptual Utopia: the market after the market

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2016

Bertram Lomfeld
Affiliation:
Freie Universität Berlin
Alessandro Somma
Affiliation:
University of Ferrar
Peer Zumbansen
Affiliation:
King's College London
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Reshaping Markets
Economic Governance, the Global Financial Crisis and Liberal Utopia
, pp. 319 - 346
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2016

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Agamben, G. 2011. The Kingdom and the Glory: For a Theological Genealogy of Economy and Government. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Ahlborn, C., Evans, D. S. and Padilla, A. J. 2004. ‘The Antitrust Economics of Tying: A Farewell to Per Se Illegality’, Antitrust Bulletin, 49: 287341.Google Scholar
Alvarez, J. E. 2010. Dispute-Settlement by “Quasi-Judicial” and “Judicial” Bodies. Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aman, A. 2009. ‘Privatization and Democracy: Resources in Administrative Law’, in Minow, M. and Freeman, J. (eds.), Government by Contract: Outsourcing and American Democracy. Cambridge, Harvard University Press, pp. 261–88.Google Scholar
Amato, G. 1992. ‘Il mercato nella Costituzione’, Quaderni costituzionali, 1: 719.Google Scholar
Amato, G. 1997. Antitrust and the Bounds of Power: The Dilemma of Liberal Democracy in the History of the Market. Oxford, Hart Publ.Google Scholar
Arrighi, G. 2007. Adam Smith in Beijing. Lineages of the 21st Century. London; New York, Verso.Google Scholar
Beck, U. 1992. Risk Society: Towards a New Modernity. London, Sage.Google Scholar
Benkler, Y. 2006. The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom. New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Berman, H. J. 1983. Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bork, R. 1978. The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself. New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Brigham, J. 1996. The Constitution of Interests: Beyond the Politics of Rights. New York, New York University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Buchholz, T. G. 1999. New Ideas from Dead Economists: An Introduction to Modern Economic Thought. New York, Plume Book.Google Scholar
Callagher, M. E. 2007. Contagious Capitalism: Globalization and the Politics of Labor in China. Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. and Stringham, E. P. 2008. ‘Privatizing the Adjudication of Disputes’, Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 9(2): 503–28, available at www.bepress.com/til/default/vol9/iss2/art8.Google Scholar
Cassese, S. 2009. I tribunali di Babele. I giudici alla ricerca di un nuovo ordine giuridico globale. Roma, Donzelli.Google Scholar
Cassese, S. 2012. The Global Polity: Global Dimensions of Democracy and the Rule of Law. Sevilla, Global Law Press.Google Scholar
Chen, C. 2011. Foreign Direct Investment in China Location Determinants, Investor Differences and Economic Impacts. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Chiti, E. and Vesperini, G. (eds.) 2015. The Administrative Architecture of Financial Integration Institutional Design, Legal Issues, Perspectives. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Ciocca, P. (ed.) 2003. Le vie della storia nell’economia. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1937. ‘The Nature of the Firm’, Economica, 4: 386405.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. D. 1999. The Strategic Constitution. Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Corcos, G., Irac, D. M., Mion, G. and Verdier, T. 2012. ‘The Determinants of Intra-Firm Trade: Evidence from French Firms’, CEP Discussion Paper, 1119: 134.Google Scholar
Crouch, C. 2011. The Strange Non-Death of Neo-Liberalism. Cambridge, Polity Press.Google Scholar
Cseres, K. J. 2005. Competition Law and Consumer Protection. The Hague, Kluwer.Google Scholar
Cucinotta, A., Pardolesi, R. and Van Der Berger, R. (eds.) 2002. Post-Chicago Developments in Antitrust Law. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Dewey, J. 1916. Democracy and Education: An Introduction to the Philosophy of Education. New York, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Easterbrook, F. H. and Fischel, D. R. 1996. The Economic Structure of Corporate Law. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Eisenberg, M. A. 1998. The Conception That the Corporation Is a Nexus of Contracts, and the Dual Nature of the Firm, 24 J. Corp. L.819–36.Google Scholar
Fama, F. E. 1970. ‘Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work’. Journal of Finance, 25 (2): 383417.Google Scholar
Fama, F. E. 1998. ‘Market Efficiency, Long-Term Returns and Behavioral Finance’. Journal of Financial Economics, 49: 283306.Google Scholar
Feldman, R. J. and Stern, G. H. 2004. Too Big To Fail: The Hazards of Bank Bailouts. Washington D.C., Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Ferrarese, M. R. 1992. Stato e mercato. Il caso degli Stati Uniti. Torino, Giappichelli.Google Scholar
Ferrarese, M. R. 1997. ‘An entrepreneurial conception of law? The American model through Italian Eyes’, in Nelken, D. (ed.), Comparing Legal Cultures. Dartmouth, Brookfield, pp. 157–82.Google Scholar
Ferrarese, M. R. 2000. Le istituzioni della globalizzazione. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Ferrarese, M. R. 2002. Il diritto al presente. Globalizzazione e tempo delle istituzioni. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Ferrarese, M. R. 2009. ‘Soft law: funzioni e definizioni’, in Somma, A. (ed.), Soft Law e hard law nelle società postmoderne. Torino, Giappichelli, pp. 7182.Google Scholar
Ferrarese, M. R. 2010. La governance tra politica e diritto. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Foucault, M. 2004. Securité, territoire, population. Cours au Collège de France. 1977–1978. Paris, Gallimard Seuil.Google Scholar
Foucault, M. 2008. The Birth of Biopolitics:Lectures at the Collège de France on Neo-Liberal Governmentality, 1978–1979. Houndmills, Palgrave, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Friedman, L. M. 1994. Total Justice. New York, Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Galgano, F. 2005. La globalizzazione nello specchio del diritto. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Garapon, A. 2010. La Raison du moindre Etat. Le néolibéralisme et la justice. Paris, Odile Jacob.Google Scholar
Giddens, A. 1990. The Consequences of Modernity. Stanford, Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Glenn, P. 2007. Legal Traditions of the World Sustainable Diversity in Law. 3rdedition, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gunn, J. A. W. 1968. ‘“Interest Will Not Lie”: A Seventeenth-Century Political Maxim’, Journal of the History of Ideas, 29 (4): 551–64.Google Scholar
Guzman, A. T. 2008. How International Law Works: A Rational Choice Theory. Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hacker, A. 2012. ‘Is Algebra Necessary?’, NY Times, September 26.Google Scholar
Hall, P. A. and Soskice, D. (eds.) 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Halper, S. 2010. The Beijing Consensus: How China’s Authoritarian Model Will Dominate the Twenty-first Century. New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1967 [1935]. Prices and Production. 2ndedition, New York, Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1979. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume III. The Political Order of a Free People. Chicago, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Heckscher, E. F. 1955. Mercantilism (Allen, George and Unwin, , revised, 2nd edition, edited by Söderlund, Ernst F.), II vol. London, Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Hennart, J. F. 1986. ‘What Is Internalization?’, Review of World Economy, 122 (4): 791804.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1977. The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph. Princeton, Oxford, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Holsti, K. J. 1992. ‘Governance without Government: Polyarchy in Nineteenth-Century European International Politics’, in Rosenau, J. N. and Czempiel, E.-O. (eds.), Governance without Government: Order and Change in World Politics. Cambridge, Mass., Cambridge University Press, pp. 3057.Google Scholar
Huang, Y. 2008. Capitalism with Chinese Characteristics: Entrepreneurship and the State. Cambridge, Mass., Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hurst, J. W. 1960. Law and Social Process in United States History. New York, Reprint Da Capo Press, 1972.Google Scholar
Joerghes, C., Sand, I.-J. and Teubner, G. 2004. Transnational Governance and Constitutionalism. Oxford, Hart.Google Scholar
Katz, A. 1990. ‘The Strategic Structure of Offer and Acceptance: Game Theory and the Law of Contract Formation’, Michigan Law Review, 89 (2): 215–95.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London, Macmillan; now in The Collecting Writings of J. M. Keynes, vol. 7, Cambridge, Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Krattenmaker, T. G. 1988. ‘Per Se Violations in Antitrust Law: Confusing Offenses with Defenses’, Georgetown Law Journal, 77 (1): 165–80.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 2007. ‘The Natural Instability of Financial Markets’. Working Paper No. 523, New York, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, available at www.levy.org.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 2010. The Natural Instability of Financial Markets. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Kruck, A. 2011. Regulations: Credit Rating Agencies and Global Financial Governance (Transformations of the State). Houndmills, Palgrave, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. 1999. The Return of Depression Economics. New York, W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. 2009. The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008.New York, W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Kurlantzick, J. 2012. ‘The Rise of Innovative State Capitalism’, Businessweek, June 28.Google Scholar
Langohor, H. M. and Langohor, P. 2008. The Rating Agencies and their Credit Ratings: What They Are, How They Work, and Why They Are Relevant. Chichester, John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Lanz, R. and Miroudot, S. 2011. ‘Intra-Firm Trade: Patterns, Determinants and Policy Implications’, OECD Trade Policy Papers, 114, OECD Publishing, available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kg9p39lrwnn-en.Google Scholar
Lessig, L. 2011. Republic, Lost: How Money Corrupts Congress – and Some Plans to Stop It. New York, Twelve – Hachette Book Group.Google Scholar
Macaulay, S. 1963 . ‘Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study’, American Sociological Review, 28 (1): 5567.Google Scholar
Macchiati, A.L’interesse pubblico nella regolamentazione finanziaria. Lezioni dalla recente crisi e problemi aperti’, Mercati, concorrenza, regole, 11 (2): 223–48.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, R. B. 2000. Trust on Trial: How the Microsoft Case Is Reframing the Rules of Competition. Cambridge, Mass., Perseus Publ.Google Scholar
Macneil, R. I. 1980. The New Social Contract: An Inquiry into Modern Relational Contracts. New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mattei, U. 2013. Controriforme. Torino, Einaudi.Google Scholar
Mattei, U. and Nader, L. 2008. Plunder: When the Rule of Law Is Illegal. Oxford, Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Mayr, O. 1986. Authority, Liberty, and Automatic Political Machinery in Early Modern Europe. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
McNally, C. A. 2011. ‘China’s Changing Guanxi Capitalism: Private Entrepreneurs between Leninist Control and Relentless Accumulation’, Business and Politics, 13 (2), Art. 5: 129.Google Scholar
Milanovic, B. 2011. The Haves and the Have-Nots: A Brief and Idiosyncratic History of Global Inequality. New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Minc, A. 2004. Les Prophètes du bonheur: une histoire personnelle de la pensée économique. Paris, Grasset.Google Scholar
Minow, M. and Freeman, J. (Eds.), 2009. Government by Contract: Outsourcing and American Democracy. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1985. ‘The Financial Instability Hypothesis: A Restatement’, in Arestis, and Skouras, (eds.), Post Keynesian Economic Theory, Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe, pp. 2455.Google Scholar
Muir-Watt, H. 2008. ‘Economie de la justice et arbitrage international’, Revue de l’Arbitrage, 3: 389417.Google Scholar
Napolitano, G. 2012. ‘La crisi del debito sovrano ed il rafforzamento della governance economica europea’, in Napolitano, G.(ed.), Uscire dalla crisi. Politiche pubbliche e trasformazioni istituzionali. Bologna, Il Mulino, pp. 383424.Google Scholar
Osborne, D. and Gaebler, T. 1992. Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Is Transforming the Public Sector. New York, Addison-Wesley Publ. Co.Google Scholar
Ost, F. 1999. Le temps du droit. Paris, Odile Jacob.Google Scholar
Ouchi, W. G. 1980. ‘Markets, Bureaucracies and Clans’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 129–41.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl. 1978. Three Worlds. The Tanner Lecture on Human Values delivered at the University of Michigan on April 7, 1978.Google Scholar
Porter, M. 1989. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York, Free Press.Google Scholar
Posner, E. A. 2000. Law and Social Norms. Boston, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Posner, E. A. (ed.) 2007. Social Norms, Non-Legal Sanctions, and the Law. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Posner, R. A. 1978. Antitrust Law. Chicago, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Posner, R. A. 2009. A Failure of Capitalism. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Prodi, P. 2009. Settimo non rubare. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Prodi, P. and Rossi, G. 2010. Non rubare. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Rapp, R. 2009. Bubbles, Booms and Busts: The Rise and Fall of Financial Assets. South Pasadena, Springer.Google Scholar
Rappaport, A. 2011. Saving Capitalism from Short-Termism: How to Build Long-Term Value and Take Back Our Financial Future. New York, Mc Graw Hill Companies.Google Scholar
Reich, R. B. 2008. Supercapitalism: The Transformation of Business, Democracy, and Everyday Life. New York, Random House.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1966. The New Mercantilism: An Inaugural Lecture. Cambridge University Press, in Robinson, J. 1973, Collected Economic Papers, vol. 4, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, pp. 113.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. 2013. Mercantilism Reconsidered, Project Syndicate, July 10.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. 2013. The New Mercantilist Challenge, Project Syndicate, January 9.Google Scholar
Rognoni, G. 2012. Credit Rating Agencies: A Look into Conflicts of Interest. LAP Lambert Academic Publishing.Google Scholar
Rosenau, J. N. and Czempiel, E.-O. (eds.) 1992. Governance without Government: Order and Change in World Politics. Cambridge, Mass., Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rossi, G. 2003. Il conflitto epidemico. Milano, Adelphi.Google Scholar
Rossi, G. 2006. Il gioco delle regole. Milano, Adelphi.Google Scholar
Rossi, G. 2008. Il mercato d’azzardo. Milano, Adelphi.Google Scholar
Rossi, G. 2009. ‘Crisi del capitalismo e nuove regole’, Rivista delle società, 54 (5): 929–46.Google Scholar
Sassen, S. 2003. ‘Globalization or Denationalization?’, Review of International Political Economy, 10 (1): 122.Google Scholar
Sassen, S. 2006. Territory, Authority, Rights: From Medieval to Global Assemblages. Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sassen, S. 2007. A Sociology of Globalization. New York, W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Sau, L. 2009. ‘Instability and Crisis in Financial Complex Systems’, Working Paper prepared for the Workshop on Current Crisis, University College of London (UCL), October 23.Google Scholar
Schmitt, C. 1996 [1927]. The Concept of the Political. New Brunswick, N.J., Rutgers University Press.Google Scholar
Schmitt, C. 1997. Land and Sea. Washington D.C., Plutarch Press.Google Scholar
Schwartz, W. F. and Sykes, A. O. 2002. ‘The Economic Structure of Renegotiation and Dispute Resolution in the World Trade Organization’, Journal of Legal Studies, 31: 179204.Google Scholar
Shany, Y. 2003. The Competing Jurisdictions of International Courts and Tribunals. Oxford, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, M. and Stone Sweet, A. 2002. On Law, Politics, and Judicialization. Oxford, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shelton, D. L. (Ed). 2000. Commitment and Compliance: The Role of Non-binding Norms in the International Legal System. Oxford, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. 2005. Irrational Exuberance. 2ndedition. Stanford, Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. 2012. Finance and the Good Society. Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. [1776] 2007. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Metalibri, digital edition.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1983. Reason in Human Affairs. Stanford, Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Somma, A. 2013. ‘Legal Change and Sovereign Debt Crisis: The Clash between Capitalism and Democracy in the Western Legal Tradition’, in Paulus, C. (ed.), Do We Need an Orderly Work-Out Scheme for Insolvent Sovereign? Munich, C.H. Beck, pp. 163–82.Google Scholar
Stanger, A. 1986. One Nation Under Contract: The Outsourcing of American Power and the Future of Foreign Policy. New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. 2012. The Price of Inequality: How Inequality Endangers Our Future. New York, W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Stone Sweet, A. 2002. ‘Judicialization and the Construction of Governance’, in Shapiro, M. and Stone Sweet, A., On Law, Politics, and Judicialization. Oxford, New York, Oxford University Press, pp. 5589.Google Scholar
Strange, S. 1996. The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Strange, S. 1986. Casino Capitalism. New York, Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Streeck, W. 2013. Tempo guadagnato La crisi rinviata del capitalismo democratico. Milano, Feltrinelli.Google Scholar
Tate, C. N. and Vallinder, T. 1995. The Global Expansion of Judicial Power. New York, New York University Press.Google Scholar
Tocqueville, A. de, (1835). Democracy in America, e-book available at www.gutenberg.org, within the Gutenberg Project.Google Scholar
Uzunidis, D. 2011. ‘Principles of the New Mercantilism and the Crisis of the Global Economy’, Cahiers du Lab.RII – Documents de travail, 236: 121.Google Scholar
Vella, F. 2011. Capitalismo e finanza. Il futuro tra rischio e fiducia. Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Vella, F. 2012. ‘Il rating: alla ricerca di una terza via’, Analisi giuridica dell’economia, 2: 323–34.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1978 [1921/22]. Economy and Society. 2 volumes, Roth, G. and Wittich, C. (eds.), Berkeley, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Williams, D. Q. C. 2003. ‘Globalization and Governance: The Prospects for Democracy’, Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies, 10 (1): 157–72.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York, The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1979. ‘Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations’, Journal of Law and Economics, 22: 233–61.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York, The Free Press.Google Scholar
Zamboni, M. 2008. ‘From “Evolutionary Theory and Law” to a “Legal Evolutionary Theory” – Part I/II’, German Law Journal, 9: 515–46.Google Scholar
Zumbansen, P. 2002. ‘Piercing the Legal Veil: Commercial Arbitration and Transnational Law’, European Law Journal, 8 (3): 400–32.Google Scholar
Zumbansen, P. 2007. ‘The Law of Society: Governance through Contract’, Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies, 14 (2): 191233.Google Scholar
Zumbansen, P. 2008. ‘Global Forces of Corporate Change and European Path-Dependencies’, American Journal of Comparative Law, 56 (2): 517–23.Google Scholar
Zumbansen, P. and Calliess, G. P. (eds.). 2011. Law, Economics and Evolutionary Theory. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Zumbansen, P. 2013. ‘Lochner Disembedded: The Anxieties of Law in a Global Context’, Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies, 20 (1): 2969. Available at www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ijgls/vol20/iss1/3.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×