Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-dnltx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T07:33:59.127Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Corruption and Political Development: A Cost-Benefit Analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

J. S. Nye*
Affiliation:
Harvard University

Extract

“Private Vices by the dextrous Management of a skillful Politician may be turned into Publick Benefits.”

—Bernard Mandeville, 1714

Corruption, some say, is endemic in all governments. Yet it has received remarkably little attention from students of government. Not only is the study of corruption prone to moralism, but it involves one of those aspects of government in which the interests of the politician and the political scientist are likely to conflict. It would probably be rather difficult to obtain (by honest means) a visa to a developing country which is to be the subject of a corruption study.

One of the first charges levelled at the previous regime by the leaders of the coup in the less developed country is “corruption.” And generally the charge is accurate. One type of reaction to this among observers is highly moralistic and tends to see corruption as evil. “Throughout the fabric of public life in newly independent States,” we are told in a recent work on the subject, “runs the scarlet thread of bribery and corruption …” which is like a weed suffocating better plants. Another description of new states informs us that “corruption and nepotism rot good intentions and retard progressive policies.”

Others have reacted against this moralistic approach and warn us that we must beware of basing our beliefs about the cause of coups on post-coup rationalizations, and also of judging the social consequences of an act from the motives of the individuals performing it. Under some circumstances Mandeville is right that private vice can cause public benefit.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1967

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

The author is indebted to Samuel P. Huntington, Leon Lindberg and Robert Erwin for reading an earlier version of this paper.

References

1 Friedrich, C. J., Man and His Government (New York, 1963), p. 167Google Scholar. See also “Political Pathology,” The Political Quarterly, 37 (January–March, 1966), 70–85.

2 Wraith, Ronald and Simpkins, Edgar, Corruption in Developing Countries (London, 1963), pp. 11, 12Google Scholar. Young, K. T. Jr., “New Politics in New States,” Foreign Affairs, 39 (04, 1961), at p. 498CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 See, for example: Leff, Nathaniel, “Economic Development Through Bureaucratic Corruption,” The American Behavioral Scientist, 8 (11, 1964), 814CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bayley, David H., “The Effects of Corruption in a Developing Nation,” The Western Political Quarterly, 19 (12, 1966), 719732CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Klaveren, J. J. Van in a “Comment” in Comparative Studies in Society and History, 6 (01, 1964), at p. 195CrossRefGoogle Scholar, even argues that “recent experience in the so-called underdeveloped countries has most vividly brought home the fact that corruption is not a mass of incoherent phenomena, but a political system, capable of being steered with tolerable precision by those in power.”

4 Gluckman, Max, Custom and Conflict in Africa (Oxford, 1955), p. 135Google Scholar.

5 Bryce, James, Modem Democracies (New York, 1921), Vol. II, p. 509Google Scholar.

6 Leys, Colin, “What is the Problem About Corruption?Journal of Modern African Studies, 3, 2 (1965), 224225CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Braibanti, Ralph, “Reflections on Bureaucratic Corruption,” Public Administration, 40 (Winter, 1962), 365371CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Nor, by the nature of the subject, is there likely to be. In Pye's words, no single scale can be used for measuring political development”: Pye, Lucian (ed.), Communications and Political Development (Princeton, 1963)Google Scholar. See also Pye, Lucian, “The Concept of Political Development,” The Annals, 358 (March 1965), 119Google Scholar; Huntington, Samuel, “Political Development and Political Decay,” World Politics, 17 (04, 1965), 386430CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Packenham, Robert, “Political Development Doctrines in the American Foreign Aid Program,” World Politics, 18 (01, 1966), 194235CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 See Huntington, op. cit., 389.

9 Lipset, S. M., Political Man (Garden City, 1959), 7275Google Scholar.

10 The second part of the definition is taken from Banfield, Edward C., Political Influence (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1961), p. 315Google Scholar.

11 See, for example: Smith, M. G., “Historical and Cultural Conditions of Political Corruption Among the Hausa,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 6 (01, 1964), at p. 194CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fallers, Lloyd, “The Predicament of the Modern African Chief: An Instance from Uganda,” American Anthropologist, 57 (1955), 290305CrossRefGoogle Scholar. I agree with Bayley on this point: op. cit., 720–722.

12 Rambo, A. Terry, “The Dominican Republic,” in Needier, Martin (ed.), Political Systems of Latin America (Princeton, 1964), p. 172Google Scholar; New York Times, March 5, 1966. Ayeh Kumi's quoted statement has almost certainly greatly under-estimated his own assets.

13 On the economic problems of “African socialism,” see Berg, Elliot, “Socialism and Economic Development in Tropical Africa,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78 (11, 1964), 549573CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Barbara Ward, addressing the Harvard Center for International Affairs, Cambridge, Mass., March 3, 1966.

15 McMullan, M., “A Theory of Corruption,” The Sociological Review (Keele), 9 (07, 1961), at p. 196CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shils, Edward, Political Development in the New States (The Hague, 1962), p. 385Google Scholar.

16 See Werlin, Herbert, “The Nairobi City Council: A Study in Comparative Local Government,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 7 (01, 1966), at p. 185Google Scholar.

17 Wraith and Simpkins, op. cit., p. 172.

18 Needler, Martin, “The Political Development of Mexico,” this Review, 55 (06, 1961), at pp. 310311Google Scholar.

19 Greenstone, J. David, “Corruption and Self Interest in Kampala and Nairobi,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 7 (01, 1966), 199210CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 See Nye, J. S., “The Impact of Independence on Two African Nationalist Parties,” in Butler, J. and Castagno, A. (eds.), Boston University Papers on Africa (New York, 1967), 224245Google Scholar.

21 Sklar, Richard L., “Contradictions in the Nigerian Political System,” Journal of Modern African Studies, 3, 2 (1965), at p. 206CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Lieuwen, Edwin, Arms and Politics in Latin America (New York, 1960), p. 149Google Scholar.

23 Benham, F. and Holley, H. A., A Short Introduction to the Economy of Latin America (London, 1960), p. 10Google Scholar.

24 Leys, op. cit., at p. 229.

25 Crozier, Brian, The Morning After: A Study of Independence (London, 1963), p. 82Google Scholar.

26 In Pye's, words, the military “can contribute to only a limited part of national development,” Aspects of Political Development (Boston, 1966), p. 187Google Scholar.

27 “Have no fear,” General Mobutu told the Congo people, “My Government is not composed of politicians.” Mobutu alleged that political corruption cost the Congo $43 million: East Africa and Rhodesia, January 13, 1966; Africa Report, January 1966, 23.

28 Crozier, op. cit., pp. 62, 74.

29 For two interpretations, see Martin Kilson, “Behind Nigeria's Revolts”; Wallerstein, Immanuel, “Autopsy of Nkrumah'e Ghana,” New Leader, January 31, 912Google Scholar; March 14, 1966, 3–5.

30 Bretton, Henry, Power and Stability in Nigeria (New York, 1962), p. 79Google Scholar.

31 Hoselitz, Bert, “Levels of Economic Performance and Bureaucratic Structures,” in LaPalombara, Joseph (ed.), Bureaucracy and Political Development (Princeton, 1963), 193195Google Scholar. See also Nathaniel Leff, loc. cit., 8–14.

32 See Tanganyika Standard, May 15, 1963.

33 McMullan, op. cit., p. 195.

34 Higgins, Benjamin, Economic Development (New York, 1959), p. 62Google Scholar.

35 Leys, op. cit., p. 227. See also McKitrick, Eric, “The Study of Corruption,” Political Science Quarterly, 72 (12, 1957), 502514CrossRefGoogle Scholar, for limits on corruption in urban America.

36 Mandeville, Bernard, The Fable of the Bees, Vol. I (Oxford: Clarendon Press, by Kaye, F. B., 1924), 37Google Scholar.

37 See Hirschman, Albert O., “Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasir Vanishing Act,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 13 (July 1965), 385393CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

38 Shils, op. cit., p. 385.

39 McMullan, op. cit., 195; Lewis, Oscar, The Children of Sanchez (New York, 1961)Google Scholar.

40 Bayley, op. cit., p. 724.

41 Weiner, Myron, The Politics of Scarcity (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962), p. 236Google Scholar.

42 Cf. Riordan, William, Plunkitt of Tammany Hall (New York, 1948), p. 4Google Scholar.