Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa
  • Get access
    Check if you have access via personal or institutional login
  • Cited by 7
  • Cited by
    This article has been cited by the following publications. This list is generated based on data provided by CrossRef.

    O’Flynn, Ian 2015. Pulling Together: Shared Intentions, Deliberative Democracy and Deeply Divided Societies. British Journal of Political Science, p. 1.


    BERGGREN, NICLAS BERGH, ANDREAS and BJØRNSKOV, CHRISTIAN 2012. The growth effects of institutional instability. Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 8, Issue. 02, p. 187.


    Driscoll, Amanda and Krook, Mona Lena 2012. Feminism and rational choice theory. European Political Science Review, Vol. 4, Issue. 02, p. 195.


    Cantelli, Fabrizio 2011. Old—and New—Policy Analysis: A Pragmatic Re-Assessment from Dewey to 9/11. Canadian Journal of Political Science, Vol. 44, Issue. 02, p. 439.


    Bedford, Kate 2009. Gender and institutional strengthening: the World Bank's policy record in Latin America. Contemporary Politics, Vol. 15, Issue. 2, p. 197.


    Landa, Dimitri and Meirowitz, Adam 2009. Game Theory, Information, and Deliberative Democracy. American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 53, Issue. 2, p. 427.


    Blomquist, William and Ostrom, Elinor 2008. Deliberation, learning, and institutional change: the evolution of institutions in judicial settings. Constitutional Political Economy, Vol. 19, Issue. 3, p. 180.


    ×

The Priority of Democracy: A Pragmatist Approach to Political-Economic Institutions and the Burden of Justification

  • JACK KNIGHT (a1) and JAMES JOHNSON (a2)
  • DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055407070062
  • Published online: 01 February 2007
Abstract

Politics reflects a seemingly incontrovertible condition—any imaginable human population is diverse across multiple, overlapping dimensions including material interests, moral and ethical commitments, and cultural attachments. Such diversity means, in turn, that disagreement and conflict are unavoidable. Under these circumstances politics largely consists in contests over the contours of shared institutional arrangements. Given that there almost always are a number of ways to institutionalize social interaction, any population occupying the circumstances of politics must determine which institutional form or arrangement to rely on in any particular domain. The “priority” of democracy, on our account, derives from its usefulness in approaching this crucial task. This priority derives from features that are, in our view, unique to democracy, namely a level of reflexivity that distinguishes it from other ways of coordinating ongoing social interaction. As we demonstrate, much of the literature on social institutions tacitly and improperly privileges a quite different component of our institutional arrangements, namely markets. We show that once one clarifies the premises and argumentative strategies common to this literature, it simply is not possible to sustain the privilege it accords to markets. In fact, we argue that the analytical models and explanatory strategies that institutionalists deploy actually sustain our case for the priority of democracy.

Copyright
Corresponding author
Jack Knight is the Sidney W. Souers Professor of Government in Arts and Sciences at Washington University in St. Louis. (knight@artsci.wustl.edu).
James Johnson is Associate Professor of Political Science at the University of Rochester. (jd.johnson@rochester.edu).
Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

American Political Science Review
  • ISSN: 0003-0554
  • EISSN: 1537-5943
  • URL: /core/journals/american-political-science-review
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×