Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-dnltx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T17:59:57.625Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Constraining the state's ability to employ force: the standing army debates, 1697–99

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 May 2010

SHAWN HUMPHREY*
Affiliation:
University of Mary Washington, Fredericksburg, VA, USA
BRADLEY A. HANSEN*
Affiliation:
University of Mary Washington, Fredericksburg, VA, USA

Abstract:

Britain's Glorious Revolution of 1688 is one of the most widely studied cases of institutional change. Recent institutional analyses of the Glorious Revolution, however, have failed to address one of the central issues in political science: control of the state's comparative advantage in violence. This paper examines this issue through analysis of the standing army debates of the late 1690s. Participants in the debates disputed whether a standing army or a militia would be the most effective institutional arrangement to guard against threats from abroad and tyranny at home. Both sides of the debate analyzed the effects of a standing army in terms of the incentives that it created for soldiers, citizens, the monarch, and foreign governments.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Barzel, Y. (2002), A Theory of the State: Economic Property Rights, Legal Rights and the Scope of the State, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, R., Grief, A., and Singh, S. (2002), ‘Organizing Violence’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46 (5): 599628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, J. (1988), The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Caruthers, B. (1990), ‘Politics, Popery, and Property: A Comment on North and Weingast’, The Journal of Economic History, 50 (3): 693698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, G. (1996), ‘The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth in England, 1540– 1800’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 26 (4): 563588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Defoe, D. (1697), Some reflections on a pamphlet lately published, entitled, an argument showing that a standing army is inconsistent with a free government and absolutely destructive to the constitution of the English monarchy, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Defoe, D. (1698a), An argument showing that a standing army, with consent of Parliament is not inconsistent with a free government, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Defoe, D. (1698b), A brief reply to the history of standing armies in England, with some account of the authors, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Fletcher, A. (1697), A discourse concerning militias and standing armies with relation to the past and present governments of Europe and of England in particular, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Gerth, H. H. and Mills, C. Wright (1946), From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hobbes, T. (1904), Leviathan, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hoppit, J. (2000), A Land of Liberty? England, 1689–1727, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Horwitz, H. (1977), Parliament, Policy and Politics in the Reign of William III, Newark: University of Delaware Press.Google Scholar
Humphrey, S. (2004), ‘Protecting your Protection in a Violent World: The Link between a State's Organization of Violence and Its Constitutional Design’, Homo Oeconomicus, 21 (1): 117152.Google Scholar
Klerman, D. and Mahoney, P. G. (2005), ‘The Value of Judicial Independence: Evidence from Eighteenth Century England’, American Law and Economic Review, 7 (1): 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, M. (1988), Of Rule and Revenue, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Levi, M. (2006), ‘Why We Need A New Theory of Government’, Perspectives on Politics, 4 (1): 519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNeill, W. H. (1982), Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Force and Society Since AD 1000, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
North, D. and Weingast, B. (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitments: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England’, The Journal of Economic History, 49 (4): 803832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1993), ‘Dictatorship, Democracy and Development’, American Political Science Review, 87 (3): 567576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwoerer, L. (1966), ‘The Role of King William III of England in the Standing Army Controversy, 1697–1699’, Journal of British Studies, 5 (2): 7494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwoerer, L. (1974), ‘No Standing Armies!’: The Antiarmy Ideology in Seventeenth-Century England, Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sened, I. (1997), The Political Institution of Private Property, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1976), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Somers, J. (1697), Letter, balancing the necessity of keeping a land-force in times of peace, with the dangers that may follow on it, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Stasavage, D. (2002), ‘Partisan Politics and Public Debt: The Importance of “Whig Supremacy” for Britain's Financial Revolution’, European Review of Economic History, 11 (1): 123153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sussman, N. and Yafeh, Y. (2006), ‘Institutional Reforms, Financial Development and Sovereign Debt: Britain 1690–1790’, The Journal of Economic History, 66 (4): 906935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toland, J. (1698), The militia reformed: or an easy scheme of furnishing England with a constant land force, capable to prevent or to subdue any foreign power; and to maintain perpetual quiet at home, without endangering the public liberty, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Trenchard, J. (1697a), An argument showing that a standing army is inconsistent with a free government, and absolutely destructive to the constitution of the English monarchy. London: s.n.Google Scholar
Trenchard, J. (1697b), The second part of an argument, showing that a standing army is inconsistent with a free government, and absolutely destructive to the constitution of the English monarchy. A postscript, containing remarks on a late published list of irish papists now in the french King's service, London: s.n.Google Scholar
Wells, J. and Wills, D. (2000), ‘Revolution, Restoration, and Debt Repudiation: The Jacobite Threat to England's Institutions and Economic Growth’, The Journal of Economic History, 60 (2): 418441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar