Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-cfpbc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T07:58:53.665Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

When do different systems of government lead to similar power-sharing? The case of government formation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 May 2022

Thiago N. Silva*
Affiliation:
School of Politics & International Relations, The Australian National University, Canberra, Australia University of Mannheim, Mannheim, Germany
*
*Corresponding author. Email: Thiago.Silva@anu.edu.au
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Recent studies provide evidence that the absence of a no-confidence procedure in presidential systems is crucial for understanding why the allocation of portfolios does not follow the same pattern in both parliamentary and presidential democracies. In this study, I argue that distinctions within presidential systems must be used to explain the substantial variation in the allocation of portfolios to presidential parties. I theorize that when the president is more dependent upon the legislature to make and enact policies, the balance of power in presidential cabinets is more likely to reflect the balance of power in the legislature. In this case, the presidential cabinet can resemble the proportional cabinets usually formed in parliamentary systems. With new data from 20 presidential democracies worldwide spanning more than 70 years, the results support the expectation of a greater formateur's advantage when presidents have greater institutionally-granted powers to influence the policy agenda in the legislature.

Type
Research Note
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - SA
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the same Creative Commons licence is included and the original work is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Political Science Association

The allocation of ministerial posts (portfolios) is the main outcome of the government formation process, and central to what “to govern” means (Laver and Shepsle, Reference Laver and Shepsle1996; Martínez-Gallardo, Reference Martínez-Gallardo2010; Golder, Reference Golder2015). Portfolios provide office benefits (e.g., patronage, perks, and control of budgets) to the party that holds them and also influence the overall direction of government policy, who formulates it, and the way the policy will be implemented. These payoffs represent the bottom line of the executive political process in coalition governments, and the understanding of their distribution can elucidate who gets to govern, and how governments formulate and enact their policies.

In parliamentary systems, there is evidence that among the parties that enter into a government together, cabinet portfolios are roughly allocated in proportion to the number of seats each party brings to the coalition (Schofield and Laver, Reference Schofield and Laver1985; Laver and Schofield, Reference Laver and Schofield1990; Laver et al., Reference Laver, de Marchi and Mutlu2011; Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason, Reference Falcó-Gimeno and Indridason2013; Bergman et al., Reference Bergman, Ersson and Hellström2015).Footnote 1 Given the absence of the vote of no confidence in presidential systems, formateur parties in presidential democracies are not reliant on their coalition partners for their continued survival in office. As a result, scholars suggest that the distribution of portfolios in presidential systems should occur in a disproportional fashion (Amorim Neto, Reference Amorim Neto2006a,Reference Amorim Netob; Ariotti and Golder, Reference Ariotti and Golder2018). The expectation of a higher share of portfolios for the president's party has been supported in the literature and defined as the formateur's advantage or the formateur's bonus (Altman, Reference Altman2000; Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010; Ariotti and Golder, Reference Ariotti and Golder2018; Chaisty et al., Reference Chaisty, Cheeseman and Power2018).

In this study, I show that while the president's party does typically receive more portfolios than predicted by their seat share contribution on average, there is significant variation in the size of the portfolio share held by the formateur's party in presidential systems. I then develop a theory to explain when a greater formateur's advantage can be expected within presidential democracies, providing a more-nuanced comparison between the dependence of the executive upon the legislature in parliamentary and presidential forms of government.

Because they depend on a legislative majority to survive and to legislate, prime ministers are more dependent upon the legislature than presidents. However, the absence of a no-confidence constraint in presidential systems does not make presidents less dependent on the legislature to make and enact policies. The need for all executives to make policies means that all presidents are dependent upon the legislature to some degree. The degree of the ability of the president to shape the legislative agenda has clear implications on how governments are formed, and when presidential cabinets will look similar to parliamentary cabinets. Presidents form coalitions—i.e., allowing other parties to control portfolios—when they need support from other parties to accomplish their legislative goals. Therefore, the greater the power of the presidents to influence the policy agenda in the legislature, the less they will relinquish control of portfolios. As a result, there will be a correlation between president's policy-making powers and the size of the formateur's advantage. The empirical implication is that when presidents have greater institutionally-granted policy-making powers, a greater formateur's advantage should be observed.

The theoretical framework here advanced is based on an existing general argument about the distribution of portfolios by the president in exchange for agenda-setting power in the legislative process (for instance, see Shugart and Carey, Reference Shugart and Carey1992; Mainwaring and Shugart, Reference Mainwaring and Shugart1997; Amorim Neto, Reference Amorim Neto2006b; Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010; Alemán and Tsebelis, Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011; Kellam, Reference Kellam2015). Yet, in this study, this argument is tested in a new way, identifying, for the first time in the study of coalition governments in presidential democracies, the direction of the proportionality deviation—i.e., whether to the president's party benefit or not.

As supported by the results from new data on government formation in 20 presidential systems over 73 years (1946–2019), if the president is more dependent upon the legislature to make and enact policies, the balance of power in presidential cabinets is more likely to reflect the balance of power in the legislature. In this case, the presidential cabinet can be very similar to the proportional cabinets usually formed in parliamentary systems. However, when institutional provisions allow some presidents greater leeway in making and enacting policies, then a more disproportional distribution of portfolios to the benefit of the president's party—a formateur's advantage—is expected. The findings of this study enhance our understanding on when and why we should expect similarities and differences in coalition dynamics between presidential and parliamentary democracies, and in particular the dynamics of coalition formation within presidential systems.

1 Portfolio allocation in parliamentary and presidential democracies

It is frequently the case in multiparty systems that no single party holds an absolute majority of seats in the national legislature. This circumstance usually compels heads of government to form a coalition in order to govern effectively. This inevitably involves horse trading between elites to determine how the government will be formed and which portfolios will be allocated to those parties that comprise the coalition.Footnote 2

Heads of government distribute ministerial portfolios across parties in exchange for legislative support. Legislative parties value portfolios, either because of their intrinsic benefits (e.g., access to office perks and patronage) or because portfolios provide the opportunity to shape the policy agenda of the government.

In parliamentary systems, the formateur of the coalition government most often comes from the largest party in the legislature and generally becomes the new head of government (e.g., prime minister) if the formation succeeds. Because the prime minister depends on legislative parties for her government's survival, the prime minister cannot afford to ignore the preferences of the parties that will comprise the government (Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010). Ignoring these preferences could result in a legislative majority removing the government from office by passing a vote of no confidence. If this happens, neither the formateur's party nor the parties that comprise the new legislative majority can be confident of a greater seat share in the next government formation attempt. Therefore, the presence of the vote of no confidence in parliamentary systems deters the formateur from forming a cabinet too disproportional in her party's favor (Golder and Thomas, Reference Golder and Thomas2014).

From the absence of the vote of no confidence in presidential systems, formateur parties are not reliant on their coalition partners for their continued survival in office. As a result, scholars suggest that formateurs in presidential systems will value the contribution of the legislative seats of their coalition partners to the government less than would be the case in parliamentary systems (Ariotti and Golder, Reference Ariotti and Golder2018). This means that non-formateur parties cannot expect the offers they receive to be as generous from presidential formateurs as from prime ministerial formateurs. It follows that formateur parties should receive a higher share of portfolios, relative to their legislative size, in presidential systems than in parliamentary systems (Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010; Indridason, Reference Indridason2015). As a consequence, while we should expect a proportional distribution of portfolios in parliamentary systems, in presidential systems we should observe a disproportional distribution to the benefit of the formateur's party. The literature already reveals a bonus in the portfolio share for the president's party on average (Altman, Reference Altman2000; Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010; Indridason, Reference Indridason2015; Ariotti and Golder, Reference Ariotti and Golder2018). Yet, as I demonstrate below, there is a substantial variation in the allocation of portfolios to presidential parties to be explained.

Figure 1 depicts the variation in the allocation of portfolios in parliamentary and presidential democracies, identifying the formateur's party. Each dot in Figure 1 represents a party that ended up in the coalition government, with solid dots identifying the formateur's party. Observations located on the 45-degree dashed line (i.e., a perfect proportionality or Gamson's Law) are parties that received a proportional share of portfolios based on their seat share contribution to the coalition. Observations above the dashed line are parties that received more portfolios than expected based on the number of legislative seats they contribute to the coalition, while parties below the dashed line are parties that received less portfolios than expected based on their number of legislative seats.Footnote 3

Figure 1. Proportionality in portfolio allocation in parliamentary and presidential systems, (a) parliamentary systems, (b) presidential systems.

Comparing the plots of Figure 1, it is noteworthy that seat share contribution accounts for much more of the variation of portfolio share in parliamentary systems than in presidential systems. The higher variation of the solid black dots identifying the formateur's party above and below the Gamson's Law line in Figure 1b suggests that something else, besides seat share contribution, could explain the variance in portfolio share in presidential democracies.

Building on existing arguments about the effect of presidential institutional powers on the formation and composition of executive cabinets (Shugart and Carey, Reference Shugart and Carey1992; Mainwaring and Shugart, Reference Mainwaring and Shugart1997; Amorim Neto, Reference Amorim Neto2006b; Amorim Neto and Samuels, Reference Amorim Neto and Samuels2010; Alemán and Tsebelis, Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011; Kellam, Reference Kellam2015), in the next section I theorize that the extent to which the president controls the legislative process is a crucial factor to understanding the variation in the allocation of portfolios to presidential parties. I then demonstrate it identifying the direction of the proportionality deviation, for example, whether to the president's party benefit or to junior partners of the coalition.

2 Explaining the formateur's advantage within presidential democracies

In both parliamentary and presidential forms of government, chief executives seek to endure in office (and to reap the political benefits that come from controlling ministries), and to legislate (i.e., to influence the policy agenda). In parliamentary systems, coalition formation by the formateur has a direct effect on survival, through the no-confidence procedure (no-confidence constraint), and a direct effect on policy through coalition parties’ commitment to vote for the agenda of the government (legislative constraint). In presidential systems, however, coalition formation can affect policy but not the survival of the government (at least not directly).

While in parliamentary systems, the government usually exerts control over legislation, in presidential systems, the policy-making powers of the president can vary significantly (Shugart and Carey, Reference Shugart and Carey1992; Alemán and Schwartz, Reference Alemán and Schwartz2006; Cheibub, Reference Cheibub2007). Presidents have a greater or lesser influence on policy, conditional on how dependent they are on the legislature to make and enact policies. This dependence relies on presidents’ policy-making powers granted by constitutions.Footnote 4 The bargaining process between the president and the legislature around a coalition formation, therefore, depends on institutional arrangements that define the balance of power between the president and legislative parties and their abilities to influence the policy agenda. The greater the president's policy-making powers, the less dependent the president is on the legislature to legislate (the smaller the legislative constraint), and the greater the president's ability to shape the legislative agenda. Consequently, this leads to a greater presidential control over resources and benefits of office, allowing presidents to control a higher share of portfolios than the share of legislative seats her party contributes to the coalition. Otherwise, the greater the legislative constraint experienced by the president, more dependent is the president upon the legislature to legislate and have her policies approved. Under this context, we should see a more proportional distribution of portfolios (as we commonly see in parliamentary systems), i.e., a distribution of power within the executive cabinet that resembles the distribution of power within the legislature.

According to the theory here advanced, a greater share of portfolios controlled by presidential parties should be observed in countries where, ceteris paribus, presidents have a greater opportunity to influence the policy agenda in the legislature. The greater the policy-making powers of the presidents, the less dependent they are on the legislature to legislate, and the less they will relinquish control of portfolios. As a result, the empirical implication to be tested in this study is: the greater the president's policy-making powers, the greater the president's party portfolio share.

3 Empirical strategy

The unit of analysis in this study is the coalition partyFootnote 5 annually considered. The empirical analyses were conducted using new data from 20 presidential multiparty democracies worldwide.Footnote 6 The data comprise a total of 117 unique coalition parties (among those, 48 unique presidential parties), spanning over 73 years (1946–2019).Footnote 7

The dependent variable—portfolio share—captures the distribution of cabinet portfolios among the parties that comprise the coalition government. Thus, this variable indicates the percentage of portfolios coalition parties (i.e., either the formateur or junior parties) receive from the total number of portfolios available.Footnote 8

The main independent variable in the analysis—presidential power—captures the institutional strength of the executive authority, as developed by Doyle and Elgie (Reference Doyle and Elgie2014). The literature is prolific on measuring presidential power, and there are well-known problems with each of these measurements (Fortin, Reference Fortin2012). To maximize the reliability of presidential power measurement, Doyle and Elgie (Reference Doyle and Elgie2014) generated a time-series cross-sectional dataset of presidential power scores with country years as the unit of observation, based on 28 existing measures in the literature. This is the most comprehensive measurement of presidential power (both in terms of countries and years covered), and using a single index leveraging the reliability of other existing indices help us avoid empirical results that would be too sensitive for the particular measure that is used. The presidential power scores range from 0 to 1 in separate time periods following constitutional changes of a country's presidential powers. Greater values of the index indicate that the presidency is a powerful actor within the decision-making and legislative-making processes of the country.Footnote 9 Based on the empirical implication to be tested in this study, a greater formateur's advantage is expected as presidential power increases.

To capture the effect of presidential power on the portfolio share held by the formateur, an interactive term between formateur and presidential power should be added to the model specification. The formateur's party is identified by a dichotomous variable—formateur—assuming the value of 1 for the formateur's (or president's) party, and the value of 0 otherwise. The variable seat share contribution indicates the percentage of legislative seats coalition parties contribute to the total number of legislative seats held by the government's coalition, when the cabinet is appointed by the formateur.

Two control variables are included in the regression models to account for possible confounders and to isolate the effect of presidential power. First, a dummy for electoral year is added based on the empirical expectation that as the next election approaches, parties have fewer incentives to join or remain in the government, and therefore cabinet termination should be more likely (Chasquetti, Reference Chasquetti1999; Altman, Reference Altman2000; Alemán and Tsebelis, Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011). Second, presidential majority indicates whether the president's party alone holds the majority of seats in the legislature. Presidential minority situations in the legislature immediately after the elections exert a strong pressure on the president to form a coalition government (Cheibub, Reference Cheibub2007).

4 Empirical analysis: results and interpretation

Figure 2 presents the results for the main empirical implication tested in this study, i.e., the greater the presidential power, the greater the portfolio share of the president's party. Controlling for electoral year and presidential majority, the results support this empirical expectation. As depicted in Figure 2a, the estimate for the interactive term between presidential power and formateur is positive and statistically significant at level 0.05, indicating that the greater the institutional powers of the president, the greater the formateur's portfolio share. In substantive terms, on average and holding the control variables constant, a country with a strong president (in terms of institutional executive prerogatives) leads to a bonus of approximately 23 percent of the portfolios available to the benefit of the president's party. Seat share contribution is still a strong predictor for portfolio share, and it is far from a one-to-one proportionality.

Figure 2. The effect of presidential powers on the formateur's portfolio share. (a) Estimates and confidence intervals. (b) Marginal effects. Notes: Dependent variable: portfolio share. Model specified with country and year fixed-effects. 95% confidence level. A full regression report can be viewed in Model 3 of Table E.1 in the Supplementary Material.

We can also highlight the main result of this study, considering the changes in the effect of formateur on portfolio share conditional on the variation of the presidential power. As we can see in Figure 2b depicting this marginal effect, the effect of formateur on portfolio share increases as the presidential power increases. Therefore, the stronger the institutional powers of the president, the greater the effect of formateur on portfolio share. Considering the range of presidential power in the sample (from 0.03 [the weakest presidency] to 0.61 [the strongest presidency]), the president's party receives a bonus of approximately 10 percent of the portfolios available when we move from the weakest presidency to the strongest presidency; from a bonus of 10 percent (from being the formateur's party with weak institutional powers) to a bonus of approximately 23 percent (from being the formateur's party with strong institutional powers).

4.1 Robustness checks

The results provide support for the theory advanced in this study. On average, and controlling for possible confounders, a greater bonus of portfolio share to the president's party is found in those countries in which the president is less dependent on the legislature, and has a greater opportunity to formulate, influence, and enact her policy agenda, i.e., presidents that are constitutionally empowered with greater policy-making powers. To further evaluate the consistency of this finding, I conduct several robustness checks, including the impact of salient portfolios on this result.Footnote 10

To identify the effect of extreme values of my measurement of presidential power on the estimates of my model, a robustness test removing one country at a time in the analysis is presented in Appendix G of the Supplementary Material. Although in the expected positive direction, the estimate for the interactive term between formateur and presidential power is not statistically significant at conventional levels when Indonesia (the case with the weakest presidency in my sample, with a score of 0.03 in presidential power) is removed.Footnote 11

The estimates for the models weighting for the salience of the ministry of finance—considered the most-important ministerial post to be allocated by presidents in presidential democracies (Martínez-Gallardo, Reference Martínez-Gallardo2010; Batista, Reference Batista2017)—suggest that strong presidents might have an advantage in the allocation of portfolios that is not only quantitative, but also qualitative (i.e., controlling the most-important portfolios). However, as indicated by the overlapping confidence intervals (at level 0.05), this result is far from conclusive and worthy of exploration in future research.Footnote 12

5 Conclusion

A stable finding in the studies of coalition formation in presidential systems asserts that the absence of a dissolution constraint in presidential democracies leads to the expectation of a formateur's advantage in the allocation of portfolios. I provide empirical evidence of a substantial variation in the allocation of portfolios to presidential parties, and advance a theory for this variation that is consistent with this expectation but also makes novel predictions.

While the president's party receives, on average, more portfolios than predicted by their seat share contribution, in this study I demonstrate with theory and data that the variation we see in the formateur's advantage can be explained by the trade-off between the president's desire to control as many portfolios as possible, and her desire to legislate and influence policy. When the president is less dependent on the legislature to formulate and enact her policies, she relinquishes less control of portfolios to other members of the coalition. As a consequence, presidents with greater institutionally-granted powers to influence the policy agenda in the legislature hold, on average, more portfolios than the share of legislative seats their parties contribute to the coalition. Still, the balance of power in presidential cabinets can reflect the balance of power in the legislature when the head of government is more dependent on the legislature to legislate. In this case, the presidential cabinet can be very similar to the proportional cabinets usually formed in parliamentary systems.

By conceiving the dependence of the president on the legislature as a continuous variable that varies with the president's ability to make and enact policy in the legislature, this study enhances our understanding of key aspects of executive-legislative relations in different systems of government, and, particularly, when and why we should expect similarities across presidential and parliamentary democracies with regards to coalition government formation. This study also highlights that while there are important differences between presidential and parliamentary systems, a unified framework can lead to a prolific research agenda.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2022.20.

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Alejandro Medina, Guy Whitten, José Cheibub, Kirby Goidel, Marcelo Camerlo, Maria Escobar-Lemmon, Michelle Taylor-Robinson, Samuel Müller, Thiago Talzzia, Thomas Bräuninger, William Clark, three anonymous reviewers, and the editors of Political Science Research and Methods for their invaluable comments. The author acknowledges funding support from the German Research Foundation (grant number 139943784) via Collaborative Research Center (SFB) 884, “The Political Economy of Reforms” at the University of Mannheim.

Data availability statement

The replication file and the data that support the findings of this study are openly available in Harvard Dataverse at https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/RHMSKP.

Footnotes

1 The positive relationship between the share of legislative seats a governing party contributes to the coalition and its share of portfolios is not perfect. Studies on parliamentary systems reveal deviations from the one-to-one proportionality (see Browne and Franklin, Reference Browne and Franklin1973; Golder and Thomas, Reference Golder and Thomas2014).

2 The use of the term coalition in this study refers to government coalition and not legislative coalition. A coalition government is composed of the formateur's political party—i.e., the party that forms the government—and all parties that accept the ministerial posts offered by the formateur, whether these parties support the government in the legislature or not.

3 Figure 1a was produced using Warwick and Druckman's data (Warwick and Druckman, Reference Warwick and Druckman2006), comprising 807 observations at the coalition party level as the unit of analysis, from cabinets formed across 14 European countries from 1945 to 2000. Figure 1b was produced using new data at the coalition party level as well from 20 presidential cabinets formed over more than 70 years (1946–2019), comprising 656 observations. The full tests for Gamson's Law in parliamentary and presidential democracies are presented in Appendix A. See Appendix B for a detailed description of the data for presidential systems.

4 Studies on coalition governance in presidential systems highlight the effect of presidential policy-making powers—such as decree powers, the president's exclusive power to introduce legislation in certain areas, veto powers, and urgency requests—on shaping the time and agenda-setting of the legislative branch (Figueiredo and Limongi, Reference Figueiredo and Limongi1999, Reference Figueiredo and Limongi2000; Shugart and Haggard, Reference Shugart and Haggard2001; Colomer and Negretto, Reference Colomer and Negretto2003; Freitas, Reference Freitas2016).

5 A coalition government is composed of the formateur's political party (which is always the presidential party in presidential systems) and all parties that accept the ministerial posts offered by the formateur. Hence, a coalition party is defined according to whether a party holds a cabinet membership—that is, if the party controls at least one portfolio.

6 The dataset was constructed by the author from several sources. A detailed description of the data is presented in Appendix B of the Supplementary Material. The author would like to thank Marcelo Camerlo for generously sharing his ministerial composition data for Latin American democracies.

7 Only coalition governments were considered in the analyses, and following Cheibub et al. (Reference Cheibub, Gandhi and Vreeland2010) and Bjørnskov and Rode (Reference Bjørnskov and Rode2020), only democratic periods were considered. The countries and years covered in the analyses are: Argentina (2000–2002), Bolivia (1985–2002), Brazil (1946–1962, 1986–2019), Burundi (2005–2010), Chile (1990–2018), Colombia (1978–2018), Ecuador (1984–2004), El Salvador (2000–2014), Ghana (2001), Honduras (1982–2010), Indonesia (2005–2013), Kenya (2003–2014), Malawi (1994–2014), Panama (1995–2014), Paraguay (1999–2012), Peru (1980–1990, 2001–2010), Philippines (2007–2010), Sierra Leone (2008–2010), Uruguay (1985–2004), and Venezuela (1961–2002).

8 Descriptive statistics are presented in Appendix C of the Supplementary Material.

9 The distribution of the variable presidential power across the cases is presented in Appendix D. The weakest executive authority in the sample is the Indonesian presidency, with a score of 0.03 based on the current Indonesian constitution enacted in 1945, and its amendments post-Suharto era (1966–1998). The strongest executive authority in the sample is the Kenyan presidency, with a score of 0.62, based on the country's current constitution, enacted in 2010.

10 The results from benchmark models (without controls), with or without country, year and government fixed-effects specifications are presented in Appendix E, and indicate a consistent finding with a positive and significant estimate (at level 0.05) for the interactive term between formateur and presidential power in all models (see Table E.1 in the Supplementary Material). As a further robustness check, I also conduct my original models keeping single-party governments in the data set and adding a control variable identifying this type of government. The results of this test are consistent with the main model's results presented in Figure 2 (see Table F.1 in the Supplementary Material).

11 This issue is considered in Appendix G. Building on Neumayer and Plümper (Reference Neumayer and Plümper2017), consistent tests for the estimation of my model on account of influential observations (e.g., computing influence statistics and robust regression [see, Li, Reference Li1985; Fox, Reference Fox1997; Andersen, Reference Andersen2008]), reinforce the validity and consistency of my results. Nevertheless, the fact that the main finding of this study is weakened by the removal of a case with an extremely weak presidency makes the assessment of possible non-linear relationships worthy of future investigation. I thank an anonymous reviewer for bringing this issue to my attention.

12 The results for this test are presented in Figure H.1 of the Supplementary Material.

References

Alemán, E and Schwartz, T (2006) Presidential vetoes in Latin American constitutions. Journal of Theoretical Politics 18, 98120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alemán, E and Tsebelis, G (2011) Political parties and government coalitions in the Americas. Journal of Politics in Latin America 3, 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altman, D (2000) The politics of coalition formation and survival in multiparty presidential democracies: the case of Uruguay, 1989-1999. Party Politics 6, 259283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amorim Neto, O (2006a) Presidencialismo e Governabilidade nas Américas. FGV, Konrad Adenauer Stiffung, Rio de Janeiro.Google Scholar
Amorim Neto, O (2006b) The presidential calculus: executive policy making and cabinet formation in the Americas. Comparative Political Studies 39, 415440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amorim Neto, O and Samuels, D (2010) Democratic regimes and cabinet politics: a global perspective. Revista Ibero-Americana de Estudos Legislativos 1, 1023.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, R (2008) Modern Methods for Robust Regression. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariotti, MH and Golder, S (2018) Partisan portfolio allocation in African democracies. Comparative Political Studies 51, 341379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Batista, M (2017) Taking portfolios difference seriously: a composite measure based on policy, office, and budget in Brazil. Brazilian Political Science Review 11, 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergman, T, Ersson, S and Hellström, J (2015) Government formation and breakdown in Western and Central Eastern Europe. Comparative European Politics 13, 345375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bjørnskov, C and Rode, M (2020) Regime types and regime change: a new dataset on democracy, coups, and political institutions. The Review of International Organizations 15, 531551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browne, E and Franklin, M (1973) Aspects of coalition payoffs in European parliamentary democracies. American Political Science Review 67, 453469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaisty, P, Cheeseman, N and Power, T (2018) Coalitional Presidentialism in Comparative Perspective: Minority Presidents in Multiparty Systems. Oxford University Press, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chasquetti, D (1999) Compartiendo el gobierno: multipartidismo y coaliciones en uruguay (1971-1997). Revista Uruguaya de Ciencia Política 10, 2546.Google Scholar
Cheibub, JA (2007) Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and Democracy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Cheibub, JA, Gandhi, J and Vreeland, J (2010) Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice 143, 67101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colomer, J and Negretto, G (2003) Governanza con poderes divididos en América Latina. Política y Gobierno 10, 1361.Google Scholar
Doyle, D and Elgie, R (2014) Maximizing the reliability of cross-national measures of presidential power. British Journal of Political Science 46, 731741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falcó-Gimeno, A and Indridason, I (2013) Uncertainty, complexity, and Gamson's law: comparing coalition formation in Western Europe. West European Politics 36, 221247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figueiredo, A and Limongi, F (1999) Executivo e Legislativo na Nova Ordem Constitucional. Rio de Janeiro, Brazil: Editora FGV.Google Scholar
Figueiredo, A and Limongi, F (2000) Presidential power, legislative organization, and party behavior in the Brazilian legislature. Comparative Politics 32, 151170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortin, J (2012) Measuring presidential powers: some pitfalls of aggregate measurement. International Political Science Review 34, 91112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, J (1997) Extending linear least squares: time series, nonlinear, robust, and nonparametric regression. In Applied regression analysis, linear models, and related models. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications. Chap. 14, pp. 369–437.Google Scholar
Freitas, A (2016) Unboxing the active role of the legislative power in Brazil. Brazilian Political Science Review 10, 00004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golder, S (2015) Government formation and cabinets. In Scott R and Kosslyn S (Eds), Emerging Trends in the Social and Behavioral Sciences. New York City: John Wiley & Sons.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golder, S and Thomas, J (2014) Portfolio allocation and the vote of no confidence. British Journal of Political Science 44, 2939.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Indridason, I (2015) Live for today, hope for tomorrow? Rethinking Gamson's law. Working Paper, University of California, Riverside, pp. 1–34.Google Scholar
Kellam, M (2015) Parties for hire: how particularistic parties influence presidents’ governing strategies. Party Politics 21, 515526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M and Schofield, N (1990) Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Laver, M and Shepsle, K (1996) Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M, de Marchi, S and Mutlu, H (2011) Negotiation in legislatures over government formation. Public Choice 1/47, 285304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, G (1985) Robust regression. In David Hoaglin, Frederick Mosteller and John Tukey (Eds), Exploring Data Tables, Trends, and Shapes. Hoboken: Wiley-Interscience, pp. 281–344.Google Scholar
Mainwaring, S and Shugart, M (1997) Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez-Gallardo, C (2010) Inside the cabinet: the influence of ministers in the policymaking process. In Carlos Scartascini ES and Tommasi M (Eds), How Democracy Works. Political Institutions, Actors, and Arenas in Latin American Policymaking. Washington, DC:Inter-American Development Bank, pp. 119–145.Google Scholar
Neumayer, E and Plümper, T (2017) Robustness Tests for Quantitative Research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, N and Laver, M (1985) Bargaining theory and portfolio payoffs in European coalition governments, 1945-1983. British Journal of Political Science 15, 143164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, M and Carey, J (1992) Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, M and Haggard, S (2001) Institutions and public policies in presidential systems. In Haggard S and McCubbins MD (Eds), Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 64–104.Google Scholar
Warwick, P and Druckman, J (2006) The portfolio allocation paradox: an investigation into the nature of a very strong but puzzling relationship. European Journal of Political Research 45, 635665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Proportionality in portfolio allocation in parliamentary and presidential systems, (a) parliamentary systems, (b) presidential systems.

Figure 1

Figure 2. The effect of presidential powers on the formateur's portfolio share. (a) Estimates and confidence intervals. (b) Marginal effects. Notes: Dependent variable: portfolio share. Model specified with country and year fixed-effects. 95% confidence level. A full regression report can be viewed in Model 3 of Table E.1 in the Supplementary Material.

Supplementary material: PDF

Silva supplementary material

Silva supplementary material

Download Silva supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 350.7 KB
Supplementary material: Link
Link