Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T06:42:35.388Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Access charge and imperfect competition

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

François Boldron
Affiliation:
Université catholique de Louvain (CORE)
Cyril Hariton
Affiliation:
Groupe ESC ToulouseUniversity of Toulouse (GREMAQ)
Get access

Summary

A benevolent social planner, which faces a cost of public funds because of distortive taxation, wants to finance an upstream monopoly. This monopoly produces a necessary input for a downstream competitive sector which competes á la Cournot (with either a fixed number of firms or free entry in the downstream sector). We show that in both cases an ad valorem access charge is a better regulatory tool than a per unit access charge if the access charges are restrained to be positive. The reverse holds when access charges are used to subsidize the downstream market. We then analyze the incidence of the imperfect competition on final prices.

Résumé

Résumé

Un gouvernement bienveillant qui fait face à un coût exogène des fonds publics (à cause d'un système fiscal imparfait) souhaite financer un monopole (un opérateur de téléphone local, par exemple) qui produit un bien nécessaire pour des firmes en compétition à la Cournot (l'accès à ce réseau local pour des opérateurs longues distances). Nous montrons qu'une charge d'accès ad valorem est un instrument de régulation plus efficace qu'une charge d'accès unitaire si ces deux dernières doivent être positivies (si elles sont négatives, pour une subvention, le meilleur instrument est la charge d'accès unitaire). Ce résultat est établi avec un nombre fixe d'entreprises ou avec entrée libre dans le secteur aval. Enfin, nous étudions l'impact sur les prix finaux de la concurrence imparfaite.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2003 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

We thank Helmuth Cremer and Jacques Crémer and an anonymous referee for their help and comments. We also thank John Turtle and the participants at the European Economic Association congress (EEA 2000, Bolzano), at the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics conference (EARIE 2000, Lausanne), at the Journées de Microéconomie appliquée (JMA 1999, Lyon) and at the ENTER Jamboree (London) for their useful remarks, especially Carmelo Rodriguez. Both of us thank also GREMAQ (University of Toulouse, France) as well as CORE (Université catholique de Louvain, Belgium) for their hospitality and their financial support. Eventuelly, Cyril Hariton gratefully acknowledges financial support by the European Commission through her Marie-Curie Fellowship (HPMF-CT-2002-02172).

References

Anderson, S., de Palma, A. and Kreider, B. (2001a), “Tax incidence in differentiated product oligopoly”, Journal of Public Economies, 81(2), 173182.Google Scholar
Anderson, S., de Palma, A. and Kreider, B. (2001b), “The efficiency of indirect taxes under imperfect competition”, Journal of Public Economies, 81(2), 231251.Google Scholar
Armstrong, M., (1998), “Network interconnection in telecommunications”, The Economie Journal, 108, 545564.Google Scholar
Armstrong, M., Doyle, C. and Vickers, J. (1996), “The access pricing problem: A synthesis”, Journal of Industrial Economics, 44(2), 131150.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y., (1976), “An alternative approach to the analysis of taxation”, Journal of Political Economy, 84, 11771197.Google Scholar
Boldron, F. (2003), «Le choix entre taxe unitaire et taxe ad valorem», Revue Française d’Économie, 17(3), 109129.Google Scholar
Boldron, F., and Hariton, C. (2001), “Access charge and imperfect competition”, GREMAQ, working paper 21.06.571, University of Toulouse.Google Scholar
Cournot, A., (1960), Researches Into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth, Frank Cass and Co., London.Google Scholar
Delipalla, S. (1995), “Specific versus ad valorem taxation : Empirical evidence from the european cigarette industry”, University of Kent.Google Scholar
Delipalla, S., and Keen, M. (1992), “The comparison between ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition”, Journal of Public Economics, 49, 351367.Google Scholar
Delipalla, S., and O’Donnell, O. (2001), “Estimating tax incidence, market power and market conduct”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19(6), 885908.Google Scholar
Dessein, W., (1998), “Network competition when customers are heterogeneous” , University of Toulouse and Université Libre de Bruxelles.Google Scholar
European Commission, (01/10/1998), “Status of voice communication on internet under community law and, in particular, under directive 90/338/EEC”, Official Journal, C6, 4. [http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/liberalization/legislation/] Google Scholar
Hamilton, S., (1999), “Tax incidence under oligopoly : A comparison of policy approaches”, Journal of Public Economics, 71, 233245.Google Scholar
Johnson, T.R., (1978), “Additional evidence on the effects of alternative taxes on cigarette prices”, Journal of Political Economy, 86, 325328.Google Scholar
Keen, M., (1998), “The balance between specific and ad valorem taxation”, Fiscal studies, 19(1), 137.Google Scholar
Kowalczyck, and Skeath, (1994), “Pareto ranking optimal tariffs under foreign monopoly”, Economic Letters, 45(3), 355359.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J., Rey, P. and Tirole, J. (1998a), “Network competition : I. Overview and non discriminatory pricing”, Rand Journal of Economics, 29(1), 137.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J., Rey, P. and Tirole, J. (1998b), “Network competition : II. Price discrimination”, Rand Journal of Economics, 29(1), 3856.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J. and Tirole, J., (1993), A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation, Massachussets Institute of Technology Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J., and Tirole, J. (1994), “Access pricing and competition”, European Economic Review, 38(9), 16731710.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J., and Tirole, J. (1996), “Creating competition through interconnection – theory and practice”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 10, 227256.Google Scholar
Laffont, J.-J., and Tirole, J., (2000), Competition in Telecommunications, MIT Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Lee, S., and Hamilton, J. (1998), “Using market structure to regulate a vertically integrated monopolist”, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 15(3), 223248.Google Scholar
Myles, G., (1995), Public Economics, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Myles, G. (1996), “Imperfect competition and the optimal combination of ad valorem and specific taxation”, International Tax and Public Finance, 3, 2944.Google Scholar
Reinhorn, L., (1999), “Optimal taxation with cournot oligopoly”, mimeo, University of Durham.Google Scholar
Salanié, B., (1998), Microéconomie : Les Défaillances Du Marché, Economica, Paris.Google Scholar
Seade, J., (1980), “The stability of cournot revisited”, Journal of Economie Theory, 23, 1527.Google Scholar
Skeath, S., and Trandel, G. (1994), “A pareto comparison of ad valorem and unit taxes in non competitive environments”, Journal of Public Economics, 53, 5371.Google Scholar
Suits, D., and Musgrave, R. (1955), “Ad valorem and unit taxes compared”, Quaterly Journal of Economics, 67, 598604.Google Scholar
Vickers, J.S., (1989), “The nature of costs and the number of firms at equilibrium”, International Journal of Industrial Organization.Google Scholar
Vickers, J.S., (1995), “Competition and regulation in vertically related markets”, Review of Econmic Studies, 62, 117.Google Scholar
Werbach, K., (1997), “Digital tornado : The internet and telecommunications policy”, Federal Commission, Office of Plans and Policy working paper series number 29. [http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/OPP/working_papers/oppwp29.pdf] Google Scholar
Wicksell, M., (1959), “Taxation in the monopoly case”, in Musgrave, R. and Shoup, C. (eds), Readings in the Economics of Taxation, London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar