Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-t5pn6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T10:39:17.868Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Logic of Clan Politics: Evidence from the Central Asian Trajectories

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Kathleen Collins
Affiliation:
University of Notre Dame
Get access

Abstract

This article argues that clans, informal organizations based on kin and fictive kin ties, are political actors that have a profound impact on the nature of posttransitional regimes and the potential for regime durability. The article first develops the concept of “clan” conceptually. It then develops several propositions about clan politics and explores them empirically in the context of the post-Soviet Central Asian cases. These cases suggest the limits of the prevailing transitions and institutionalist approaches; these theories cannot explain regime transition in the Central Asian cases because they focus on the formal level and ignore the crucial informal actors—clans—and the informal politics that shape these cases. The distinct mode of transition, new regime institutions, and leadership and elite ideologies evident at the formal level have a very short-term effect; withinfiveyears, these cases converge toward a pattern of informal, clan-based politics. By contrast, this article draws upon the insights of the early literature on political development as well as the state-society literature to develop an alternative framework for explaining the dynamic between clans and the regime. Clan networks and clan deals penetrate and transform the formal regime in several ways—by clan-based appointments and patronage, by stripping state assets to feed one's clan network, and by crowding out other mechanisms of representation. As they undermine formal institutions, clans create an informal regime best understood as “clan politics.”

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Akayev, Askar, quoted in Kyrgyzstan Human Development Report (Bishkek: UNDP, 2001), 4Google Scholar; and Karimov, Islam, Uzbekistan na poroge XXI veka (Uzbekistan on the threshold of the twenty-first century) (Tashkent, 1997)Google Scholar.

2 North, Douglass, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Jack Knight, “Informal Institutions and the Microfoundations of Politics” (Paper presented at Harvard University, April 5, 2002).

3 Exceptions include Lauth, Hans-Joachim, “Informal Institutions and Democracy,” Democratization 7 (Winter 2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Greif, Avner, “Self-Enforcing Political Systems and Economic Growth: Late Medieval Genoa,” in Bates, Robert, Greif, Avner, Levin, Margaret, and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, Analytic Narratives (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998)Google Scholar.

4 See Hodgekin, Thomas, Nationalism in Colonial Africa (London: Frederick Muller, 1956)Google Scholar; Coleman, James, Nigeria: Background to Nationalism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1958)Google Scholar; idem, Nationalism and Development in Africa: Selected Essays, ed. Sklar, Richard (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1994)Google Scholar; and Zolberg, Aristide, Creating Political Order (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1966)Google Scholar. Revisionist modernization theory treated social organization as capable of interaction with the state and transformation. See Rudolph, Lloyd and Rudolph, Susanne, The Modernity of Tradition: Political Development in India (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967)Google Scholar.

5 Huntington, Samuel, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968)Google Scholar. Huntington was more pessimistic than earlier scholars about the role of traditional social organization in politics.

6 North, Douglass, “Where Have We Been and Where Are We Going?” in Ben-Ner, Avner and Putterman, Louis, eds., Economics, Values, and Organization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998)Google Scholar; and Greif(fn. 3).

7 O'Donnell, Guillermo, “Illusions about Consolidation,” Journal ofDemocracy 7 (April 1996)Google Scholar.

8 Migdal, Joel, State in Society: Studying How States and Societies Transform and Constitute OneAnother (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001), 50CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 I look at effect on the “political trajectory” (not a short-term regime outcome). Both regime type and regime durability are part of the political trajectory, and the two are closely interconnected. See also Bunce, Valerie, Subversive Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999), 512CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10 The first three case studies are based on primary research of over three years of field work; the latter two are based on secondary research supplemented by a number of in-country author interviews.

11 On the Soviet Union as a colonial/imperial state, see Beissinger, Mark and Young, Crawford, Beyond State Crisis? Postcolonial Africa and Post-Soviet Eurasia in Comparative Perspective (Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 2002)Google Scholar; and Laitin, David, Identity in Formation (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1998)Google Scholar.

12 Noted exceptions include O'Donnell (fn. 7); Verdery, Katherine and Buroway, Michael, eds., Uncertain Transition (Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield, 1999)Google Scholar.

13 O'Donnell, Guillermo and Schmitter, Philippe, Transitions from Authoritarian Rule (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1986)Google Scholar: and Karl, Terry and Schmitter, Philippe, “Modes of Transition in Latin America, Southern, and Eastern Europe,” International Social Science Journal 128 (1991)Google Scholar. For critiques, see McFaul, Michael, “The Fourth Wave of Democracy and Dictatorship: Noncooperative Transitions in the Post communist World,” World Politics 54 (January 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Bunce, Valerie, “Rethinking Recent Democratization: Lessons from the Postcommuist Experience,” World Politics 55 (January 2003)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Collins, Kathleen, “Clans, Pacts, and Politics: Understanding Regime Transition in Central Asia,” (Ph.D. diss., Stanford University, 1999)Google Scholar, chap. 3; and idem, “Clans, Pacts, and Politics in Central Asia,” Journal ofDemocracy 13 (July 2002)Google Scholar.

15 Przeworski, Adam, Democracy and the Market (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mainwaring, Scott and Scully, Timothy, eds., Building Democratic Institutions (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1995)Google Scholar; Linz, Juan and Stepan, Alfred, Problems ofDemocratic Transition and Consolidation (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1996)Google Scholar.

16 McFaul (fn. 13); Fish, M. Steven, “Postcommunist Subversion: Social Science and Democratization in East Europe and Eurasia,” Slavic Re-view 58 (Winter 1999Google Scholar); idem, “The Dynamics of Democratic Erosion,” in Anderson, Richard, Fish, Steven, Hanson, Stephen, and Roeder, Philip, Postcommunism and the Theory ofDemocracy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001)Google Scholar; Higley, John and Gunther, Richard, eds., Elites and Democratic Consolidation in Latin America and Southern Europe (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1992)Google Scholar; and Rustow, Dankwart, “Transition to Democracy: Toward a Dynamic Model,” Comparative Politics 2 (April 1970)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

17 See, for example, Collier, Ruth Berins, Paths towards Democracy: The Working Class and Elites in Western Europe and South America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; David Collier and Ruth Collier, Berins, Shaping the PoliticalArena (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1991)Google Scholar.

18 Exceptions include Bunce (fn. 9); McFaul (fn. 13); Levitsky, Steven and Way, Lucan, “The Rise of Competitive Authoritarianism,” Journal ofDemocracy 13 (April 2002)Google Scholar.

19 Helmke and Levitsky, “Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda,” Working Paper no. 307 (Notre Dame: Kellogg Institute, September 2003).

20 Lauth (fn. 3) blurs informal institutions and organizations. Nor does he provide empirical analysis.

21 See Fortes, M. and Evans-Pritchard, E. E., African Political Systems (London: Oxford University Press, 1940)Google Scholar.

22 See Legum, Colin, “The Dangers of Independence,” Transition 6–7 (October 1962)Google Scholar; Apter, David, Ghana in Transition (New York: Antheneum Publishers, 1963)Google Scholar; Zolberg, Aristide, “The Structure of Political Conflict in the New States of Tropical Africa,” American Political Science Review 62 (March 1968)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cohen, Abner, Custom and Politics in Urban Africa (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969)Google Scholar.

23 See fn. 4. See also Coleman, James, “Nationalism in Tropical Africa,” American Political Science Review 48 (June 1954)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Coleman, James and Rosberg, Carl, eds., Political Parties and National Integration in Tropical Africa (Berkeley: University of California, 1964)Google Scholar.

24 Huntington (fn. 5), 140–41.

25 , Coleman and , Halisi, “American Political Science and Tropical Africa,” African Studies Review 24 (September-December 1983), 220–21Google Scholar.

26 Examples include Price, Robert, Society and Bureaucracy in Contemporary Ghana (Berkeley: University of California, 1975)Google Scholar; Hyden, Goran, Beyond Ujaama in Tanzania: Underdevelopment and an Uncap-tured Peasantry (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980)Google Scholar; and Scott, James C., The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1976)Google Scholar.

27 Migdal (fn. 8); and Migdal, Joel, Kohli, Atul, and Shue, Vivienne, eds., State Power and Social Forces (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Migdal, Kohli, and Shue (fn. 27).

29 Ibid., 2.

30 , Herbst, States and Power in Africa (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999)Google Scholar. See also Beissinger and Young (fn. 11).

31 , Scott, Seeing Like a State (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1999)Google Scholar.

32 Numerous scholars have looked at the role of clientelism in inhibiting democratic consolidation. See, for example, Frances Hagopian, “Traditional Politics against State Transformation in Brazil,” in Migdal, Kohli, and Shue (fn. 27); O'Donnell (fn. 7).

33 This definition draws on North (fn. 2), 3–6; Knight (fn. 2), 11; and Helmke and Levitsky (fn. 19), 36–39.

34 North (fn. 2), 4–5.

35 See Shryock, Andrew, Nationalism and the Genealogical Imagination (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997)Google Scholar, 40–41, 318; Tapper, Richard, “Anthropologists, Historians, and Tribespeople on Tribe and State Formation in the Middle East,” in Khoury, Philip and Kostiner, Joseph, eds., Tribes and State Formation in the Middle East (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990), 5051Google Scholar; and Lindholm, Charles, “Kinship Structure and Political Authority: The Middle East and Central Asia,” Comparative Studies in Society and History 28 (April 1986)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Humphrey, Caroline and Sneath, David, The End of Nomadism? (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1999), 2627Google Scholar; and Shryock (fn. 35), 313.

37 Many anthropologists and historians argue that “fictive kinship”—ties through marriage, family friends, religious circles, and close business or political relations—is an essential element of kinship and clan. Marriage and political/business ties often overlapped, thus extending the family circle. See Shryock (fh. 35), 318; Humphrey and Sneath (fn. 36); Khoury and Kostiner (fn. 35); and Lindholm (fn. 35).

38 On the “strong ties” of kinship, see Gibson, James, “Social Networks, Civil Society, and the Prospects for Consolidating Russia's Democratic Transition,” American Journal of Political Science 45 (January 2001), 53CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Granovetter, Mark, “The Strength of Weak Ties,” American Journal of Sociology 78 (May 1973), 1361CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Padgett, John and Ansell, Christopher, “Robust Action and the Rise of the Medici, 1400–1434,” American Journal of Sociology 98 (May 1993), 1267CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

39 Humphrey and Sneath (fn. 36).

40 Edgar, Adrienne, “Genealogy, Class, and ‘Tribal Policy’ in Soviet Turkmenistan, 1924–1934,” Slavic Review 60 (Summer 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

41 Humphrey and Sneath (fn. 36).

42 On clan and tribal support for King Hussein of Jordan, see Shryock (fn. 35), 318–20.

43 Gibson (fn. 38), 52–53.

44 Elster, Jon, “Rationality and the Emotions,” Economic Journal 106 (September 1996), 1389–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

45 Chong, Dennis, Rational Lives (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46 Kornai, Janos, The Socialist System (Cambridge: Harvard: Harvard University Press, 1991)Google Scholar. In significant ways the communist/socialist economy was characterized by shortages, barter, and transaction problems of the premodern economy.

47 Shryock (fn. 35); Padgett and Ansell (fn. 38).

48 See Knight (fn. 2) on self-enforcement mechanisms and informal institutions.

49 Roniger, Luis and Gunes-Ayata, Ayse, Democracy, Clientelism, and Civil Society (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1994), 34Google Scholar, 11.

50 Pattioni, Simona, ed., Clientelism, Interests and Democratic Representation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 2001), 24CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See fnn. 49, 32.

51 Rose-Ackerman, Susan, Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Pattioni (fn. 50); Hutchcroft, Paul, Booty Capitalism: The Politics of Banking in the Philippines (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1997)Google Scholar.

52 Ledenevna, Anna, Russia's Economy of Favors (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998)Google Scholar. Lucan Way distinguishes between weak ties that use blat or corruption and strong ties of kin/clan; Way, “Weak Ties in Moldova” (Paper presented at Harvard University, April 4, 2002).

53 Hoffman, David, The Oligarchs: Wealth and Power in the New Russia (New York: Public Affairs, 2002)Google Scholar; Chubb, Judith, The Mafia and Politics: The Italian State under Siege (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.

54 Jones Luong, for example, assumes that by creating new administrative territories the Soviets eliminated or made irrelevant pre-Soviet identities. See Luong, Pauline Jones, Institutional Change and Political Continuity in Post-Soviet Central Asia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 17, 52–53. This view neglects the more pervasive social identities underlying regions, even as regional boundaries change.

55 Anderson, Benedict, Imagined Communities (London: Verso, 1991)Google Scholar; and Laitin (fn. 11).

56 Suny, Ronald, The Revenge of the Past (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; Tishkov, Valery, The Mind Aflame (Oslo: PRIO, 1997)Google Scholar; and Martin, Terry, The Affirmative Action Empire (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press 2001)Google Scholar.

57 Anderson (fn. 55), 5–7.

58 Khoury and Kostiner (fn. 35), 4–5; and Albert Hourani, “Tribes and States in Islamic History,” in Khoury and Kostiner (fn. 35), 303–4. “Tapper (fn. 35), 52–53.

60 In much of Asia and the Middle East, this subdivision of ethnic group into tribe and then clan (and eventually the nuclear family) is common. See Khoury and Kostiner (fn. 35). However, the terminology of ethnicity, tribe, and clan varies significantly across Africa. See Coleman (fn. 4,1994). The terms are often used interchangeably, in part because there are numerous, distinct ethnolinguistic groups that are often smaller in size. Those African cases most similar to the Asian ones are the Sudan and Somalia, where subethnic clans and tribes are operative units. See Laitin, David and Samatar, Said, Nation in Search of a State (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1986)Google Scholar.

61 Most work assumes informal institutions emerge in response to the state.

62 Weber, Max, The Theory ofSocial and Economic Organization (New York: Oxford University Press, 1947)Google Scholar.

63 Ibid.

64 Alec Nove and J. A. Newth typify the view that the Soviets successfully modernized Central Asia; Nove Newth, and, The Soviet Middle East: A Communist Model for Development (New York: Praeger, 1967)Google Scholar. Jones Luong has a similar view (fn. 54).

65 Khoury and Kostiner (fn. 35), 16–19.

66 Contrast the timing, mode, and pattern of state formation in these regions with that of Western Europe. See Tilly, Charles, Coercion, Capital, and European States, 990–1990 (Cambridge: Blackwell, 1990)Google Scholar; Young, Crawford, The African State in Comparative Perspective (New Haven: Yale University Press: 1994)Google Scholar; Huntington (fn. 5); and Beissinger and Young (fn. 11). The simultaneous growth of capitalism in Western Europe is also unparalleled in Central Asia.

67 Allworth, Edward, ed., Central Asia: 130 Years of Russian Domination (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 1994)Google Scholar; Brower, Daniel and Lazzerini, Edward, Russia's Orient: Imperial Borderlands and Peoples, 1700–1917 (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1997)Google Scholar; and Herbst (fn. 30).

68 Scott (fn. 31); and Hyden (fn. 26). On the limits of colonial states, see Herbst (fn. 30), 76–96.

69 Humphrey and Sneath (fn. 36) note that in rare cases, such as Inner Mongolia, the state succeeded in formalizing lists of clans and their members, thereby disempowering them (pp. 26–27).

70 On social resistance, see fnn. 26, 27.

71 Caste-state relations in India in the 1960s suggest this logic. See Rudolph and Rudolph (fn. 4).

72 Kornai (fn. 46). See also Ouchi, William, “Markets, Bureaucracies and Clans,” Administrative Science Quarterly 25 (March 1980)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Williamson, Oliver, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985)Google Scholar.

73 Beissinger and Young (fn. 11).

74 O'Donnell and Schmitter (fn. 13); Karl and Schmitter (fn. 13); Higley and Gunther (fn. 16).

75 Central Asia is similar to sub-Saharan Africa in this way and distinct from East Asia or Latin America.

76 Khalid, Adeeb, The Politics of Muslim Cultural Reform (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998), 189–90Google Scholar; Koichuev, T., Mokrynin, V., and Ploskikh, V., Kyrgyzy, I ikh predki (The Kyrgyz and their ancestors) (Bishkek: Glav. Red. Kyrgyzskoi Entsiklopedii, 1994)Google Scholar; and V.V. Bartol'd, Istoriia kul'turnoi zhizni Turkestana (History of cultural life of Turkestan), in , Bartol'd, Sochineniia (Works) (Moscow: Itd. Vostochnoi Literatury, 1963)Google Scholar, vol. 2/i.

77 Brower and Lazzerini (fn. 67); Khalid (fn. 76), chap. 2; and Bartol'd (fn. 76).

78 Brower and Lazzerini (fn. 67).

79 Hirsch, Francine, “Empire of Nations: Colonial Technologies and the Meaning of the Soviet Union” (Ph.D. diss., Princeton University, 1998)Google Scholar, chap. 1.

80 Fierman, William, ed., Soviet Central Asia: The Failed Transformation (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1991), 1833Google Scholar.

81 See fn. 56; see also Slezkine, Yuri, “The USSR as a Communal Apartment or How a Socialist State Promoted Ethnic Particularism,” Slavic Review 53 (Summer 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

82 Scott (fn. 31).

83 Martin (fn. 56).

84 Suny (fn. 56), 113–18; and Hirsch (fn. 79), chaps. 3, 5.

85 See Roy, Olivier, The New Central Asia (New York: New York University Press, 2000)Google Scholar, chap. 6; and Collins (fn. 14, 1999), chaps. 4, 8.

86 Massell, Gregory, The Surrogate Proletariat (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1974)Google Scholar, chap. 1, 386–89.

87 Bunce, Valerie, “The Political Economy of the Brezhnev Era: The Rise and Fall of Corporatism,” British Journal of Political Science 13 (April 1983), 135CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Suny (fn. 56), 118–20.

88 On similar phenomena in Africa, see Naomi Chazan, “Engaging the State: Associational Life in Sub-Saharan Africa,” in Migdal, Kohli, and Shue (fn. 27), 261–63.

89 Author interview with local clan elder, Andijan province, Uzbekistan, August 2000.

90 Author interview with son of former Communist Party apparatchik and powerful clan leader, Tashkent, Uzbekistan, May 1997.

91 Ligachev, Yegor, Inside Gorbachev's Kremlin (New York: Pantheon, 1993), 204–53Google Scholar.

92 Author interviews with Oleg Grinevskii, former aide to Khrushchev and Brezhnev in the Org-Otdel, Stanford, May 1999, and with former aide to Gorbachev, Moscow, June 2000. See also Iliukhin, V., Oborotni: Kakbylo nadumano “Uzbeks/we delo” (Reversals: How the Uzbek affair was invented) (Tashkent, 1993)Google Scholar.

93 Donald Carlisle, “Power and Politics in Soviet Uzbekistan: From Stalin to Gorbachev,” in Fierman (fn. 80), 112–16.

94 Usubaliev, T. U., Kleveshchite, Kleveshchite (Slander, slander) (Bishkek: Uchkun, 1995)Google Scholar.

95 Author interviews with journalists in Tashkent, Bishkek, and Dushanbe, July 1998, August 2000, January 2003.

96 Author interviews with kin of Rashidov and government officials in Uzbekistan and Kyrgyzstan, May-June 1998.

97 Author interviews with Uzbek and Tajik government officials, Tashkent, August 1998, Dushanbe, March 2001.

98 Author interview with Kyrgyz government adviser, Bishkek, August 1998.

99 Erkebaev, A., 1990 god: Prikhod k vlasti A. Akaeva (1990: A. Akaev's coming to power) (Bishkek: ATC Books International, 1997)Google Scholar; and Dj. Asankulov, “Askar Akaev kak otkritaia kniga,” in Askar Akaev (Bishkek: “Asaba” 1993).

100 Author interview with Uzbek government adviser, Tashkent, September 1998. See also Carlisle (fn. 93), 116–18.

101 Author interview (fn. 100).

102 James Critchlow, “Prelude to Independence,” in Fierman (fn. 80), 153.

103 Abai Tursunov, ”Islam Karimov, sil'nyi chelovek v 'zalozhnikakh',”Kontinent, October 16, 2002 (www.continent.kz/2002/10/16, accessed October 2002).

104 On the Soviet period and transitions, see Michael Ochs, “Turkmenistan: The Quest for Stability and Control,” and Olcott, Martha, “Democratization and the Growth of Political Participation in Kazakhstan,” both in Dawisha, Karen and Parrott, Bruce, eds., Conflict, Cleavage and Change in Central Asia and the Caucasus (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997)Google Scholar.

105 Olcott (fn. 104), 204–5.

106 Akiner, Shirin, The Formation ofKazakh Identity (London: Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1995), 5657Google Scholar.

107 Ochs (fn. 104).

108 Roy (fn. 85).

109 Author interviews with Tajik government representative, Tashkent, May 1998, and with Oleg Grinevskii, Stanford, May 1999.

110 On the podesta facilitating informal agreements, see Greif (fn. 3), 46–47.

111 Fish (fn. 16); McFaul (fn. 13).

112 Munck, Gerardo and Leff, Carol Skalnik, “Modes of Transition and Democratization: South America and Eastern Europe in Comparative Perspective,” Comparative Politics 29 (April 1997), 344–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar. They argue that the “identity of the actors in the transition and their strategies” explain how democracies emerge and consolidate. In clan-based societies, the identity of the transitional actors is critically different.

113 James Mahoney, “Causal Mechanisms, Correlations, and a Power Theory of Society” (Paper presented at the American Political Science Association, August 31,2002), 9.

114 On asset stripping by individuals, not groups, see Solnick, Steven, Stealing the State: Control and Collapse in Soviet Institutions (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1998)Google Scholar.

115 Lauth (fn. 3), 30; and Gibson (fn. 38), 59.

116 O'Donnell (fn. 7); and Rose-Ackerman (fn. 51).

117 Similar conditions lead to state failure. See Rotberg, Robert, ed., State Failure and State Weakness in a Time of Terror (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 2003), 2022Google Scholar.

118 Fish (fn. 16); McFaul (fn. 13).

119 Lack of space precludes providing an exhaustive list. These areas reflect the basic dimensions of democracy, defined by Dahl as participation, contestation, and representation. See Dahl, Robert, Polyarchy (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971)Google Scholar; and Linz and Stepan (fn. 15), 56.

120 This is not an element of all authoritarian regimes, but it is a critical element in building “socialist” authoritarianism in Uzbekistan, which has sought to maintain a centrally planned economy.

121 Erkebaev (fn. 99), 99–100.

122 Eugene Huskey, “Kyrgyzstan: The Fate of Political Liberalization,” in Dawisha and Parrott (fn. 104), 254–55.

123 Author interview with Dj. Dzeksheev, a leader of the Democratic Movement of Kyrgyzstan, Bishkek, November 1994.

124 Author interview with governmental adviser, Kyrgyzstan, August 1998.

125 Author interviews with Tolekan Ismailova, head of the democratic Coalition of NGOs, Kyrgyzstan, Stanford, November 2002, and with Ercan Murat, head of the United Nations Development Program, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, August 1995. Both credit Akayev with the early progress toward democracy. See also Huskey (fn. 122), 252–53.

126 The 1995 elections were declared “free and fair” by the OSCE, the UN, and other international observers, but the OSCE noted they were plagued by “family voting.” See Nations in Transit 2000: Kyrgyz Republic (New York: Freedom House, 2001), 223Google Scholar. The 1991 election, held just after the Soviet collapse, was not monitored.

127 On thresholds and definitions of democracy, minimalist to more comprehensive, see Diamond, Larry, Developing Democracy: Towards Consolidation (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1999)Google Scholar.

128 Akayev (fn. 1).

129 For more detail, see Collins (fn. 14,1999), chap. 7.

130 Author interview with local political expert from Kyrgyzstan, May 2003.

131 Nations in Transit 2001: Kyrgyz Republic (www.freedomhouse.org/research/nitransit/2001/index.htm, accessed March 2002). The report notes that independent deputies included government officials and clan leaders. There were also a handful of intellectuals, mostly from representing parties.

132 Alisher Khamidov, “Kyrgyzstan: Organized Opposition and Civil Unrest,” December 16, 2002 (www.eurasianet.org/departments/rights/articles/eavl21602.shtml, accessed December 2002).

133 Author interview with political party expert, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, June 1998.

134 Author interview with political party leader, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, October 1996.

135 Author interview with journalist, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, January 2002.

136 Ibid.

137 Consider, by contrast, the Argentinian case; Helmke, Gretchen, “The Logic of Strategic Defection: Court-Executive Relations in Argentina under Dictatorship and Democracy,” American Political Science Review 96 (June 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

138 Author interview with trade union leader, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, August 1995.

139 Author interview with State Department official, January 2002.

140 Author interview with Joormat Otorbaev, economic adviser to the president of Kyrgyzstan, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, January 2002.

141 Author interviews with Feliks Kulov, former vice president, with akim of Chui oblast', Bishkek, August 1995, and with other Kyrgyz officials, 1995–2001.

142 Alisher Khamidov, “Kyrgyzstan's Unrest Linked to Clan Rivalries” (www.eurasianet.org/departments/insight/articles/earO6O52.shtml, accessed June 2002). And author interview with Kyrgyzjournalist, Osh, August 2002.

143 Author interview with Raya Kadyrova, NGO leader and sociologist, Bishkek, Kyrgyzstan, Bishkek, August 2002.

144 Author interview with Uzbek expert, Tashkent, January 2002.

145 Kul'chick, Yuri, Respublika Uzbekistan v seredine 90-kh godov (The Republic of Uzbekistan in the middle of the 1990s) (Moscow: RAN, 1995)Google Scholar.

146 Author interview with OSCE representatives, Tashkent and Bishkek, June 2000. See also Kul'chick (fn. 145).

147 This is not an element of all authoritarian regimes but is a critical element in building “socialist” authoritarianism in Uzbekistan, which has sought to maintain a centrally planned economy.

148 International Crisis Group (ICG), “Uzbekistan's Reform Program: Illusion or Reality?” (Osh/Brussels: ICG, February 18,2003); Asia Report no. 46 (www.crisisweb.org/home/index/.cfm?idsl466Il=l, accessed February 2003).

149 Author interviews with Uzbek businessmen, Tashkent 2000 and 2002. See also Farangis Said, “Machinations Mar Uzbekistan's Banking System,” Central Asia-Caucasus Analyst, November 8,2000 (www.cacianalyst.org/view_article.php?articleid=308, accessed May 2003).

150 Author interview with World Bank adviser, Tashkent, Uzbekistan, August 2002.

151 ICG (fn. 148), 25.

132 Author interview with David Pierce, head of the World Bank, Tashkent, Uzbekistan, August 2002.

153 Usman Khaknazarov, “Vozrozhdenie ‘serogo kardinala uzbekskoipolitiki,” Tsentr Azna, January 2, 2003 (www.centrasia.ru, accessed January 2003; also found at www.navi.kz/articles/?artid+2280, accessed July 2003); and Alisher Taksanov, “Kanonizirovanie klanov,”Internet-gazeta, Kazakhstan, December 20, 2002 (www.navi.kz/articles/?artid+2176, accessed December 2002). The articles were quickly blocked in Uzbekistan.

154 Author interview with anonymous official in Uzbekistan, Tashkent, 2002.

155 Author interview with dissident Tajik journalist, Moscow, August 1998.

156 Sergei Biriukov, “Elity-klientely,” Russkii zhurnal, March 18, 2003 (www.russ.ru/politics/20030318-bir.html, accessed April 2003).

157 Rubin, Barnett, “Russian Hegemony and State Breakdown: Causes and Consequences of the Tajik Civil War,” in Rubin, Barnett and Snyder, Jack, eds., Post-Soviet Political Order (London: Rout-ledge Press, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

1S8 Akbarzadeh, Shahram, “Why Did Nationalism Fail in Tajikistan?” Europe-Asia Studies 48 (November 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Rubin, Barnett, “The Fragmentation of Tajikistan,” Survival 55 (Winter 19931994), 71CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

159 Author interview with former U.S. official in Tajikistan, Baku, August 1998.

160 Author interview with UNOCHA representative, Dushanbe, March 2001.

161 Nasrin Dadmehr, “Tajikistan: Regionalism and Weakness,” in Rotberg (fn. 117).

162 Shirin Akiner, Tajikistan: Reconciliation or Disintegration? (forthcoming); and Dadmehr (2003). On clans and mafias, see , Chubb, Tie Mafia and Politics: The Italian State under Seige (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.

163 Author interviews with Abdumalik Abdullojanov, former prime minister, Tajikistan, and with other Tajik officials, Tashkent, August 1998.

164 Author interviews with Tajik journalist and with OSCE representative, Dushanbe, August 2002.

165 See Roy (fn. 85); and Rubin (fn. 157).

166 Author interview with member of the Islamic Renaissance Party, Dushanbe, March 2001.

167 Author interview with UNDP representative, Dushanbe, Tajikistan, August 2002. See also Roger McDermott, “The Army in Tajikistan: Ten Years of Independence,” Central Asia-Caucasus Analyst, March 12,2003 (www.cacianalyst.org/view_article.php?articleid=1143, accessed April 2003); and former ambassador R. Grant Smith, “Dealing with Warlords,” Central Asia-Caucasus Analyst, January 30, 2002 (www.cacianalyst.org/view_article.php?articleid=45, accessed March 2002).

168 According to one Tajik journalist, clans have become increasingly criminalized since the war. Author interview with journalist, Moscow, August 2000.

169 Schatz, Edward, “The Politics of Multiple Identities: Lineage and Ethnicity in Kazakhstan,” Europe-Asia Studies 52 (2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See Biriukov (fn. 156).

I70 Olcott(fn. 104), 202–3.

171 Author interview with OSCE official, Tashkent, June 2000.

172 Author conversation with lawyer based in Kazakhstan, August 2003.

173 RFE/RL, Kazakh News (October 10,2001).

174 Aldar Kusainov, “Kazakhstan's Critical Choice,” January 1,2003 (www.eurasianet.org/departments/rights/articles/eavOl1303.shtmlwww.eurasianet.org/departments/rights/articles/eav011303.shtml, accessed February 2003).

175 Ibid.

176 Fairbanks, Charles, “Disillusionment in the Caucasus and Central Asia,” Journal of Democracy 12 (October 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

177 Ochs (fn. 104), 317.

178 International Crisis Group (ICG), “Turkmenistan: Cracks in the Marble” (Osh/Brussels: ICG, January 17,2003), 21 (www.crisisweb.org/home/index.cfm?id=1445&l=l, accessed January 2003).

179 Rustem Safronov, “Turkmenistan Purge Indicative of Instability” (www.eurasianet.org/departments/insight/articles/eavO312O2.shtml, March 12,2002, accessed March 2002).

180 ICG (fn. 178), 7–9.

181 Author interview with Turkmen dissident, Moscow, August 2000.

182 Expert, “Turkmenistan Faces Multiple Sources of Domestic Strife,” February 12, 2003 (www.eurasianet.org/departments/recaps/articles/eav021203.shtml, accessed February 2003).

183 Rustem Safronov, “Opposition in Exile: Turkmenistan,” December 9,2002 (www.eurasianet.org/departments/rights/articles/eavl20902.shtml, accessed December 2002).

184 Roger McDermott, “Shake-up in Turkmen Spy Agency Hints at Pending Crisis,” September 30, 2002 (www.eurasianet.org/departments/insight/articles/eav093002_ pr.shtml, accessed October 2002).

185 “Analyst Predicts ‘Radical Change’ Near for Turkmenistan,” October 21, 2002 (www.eurasianet.org/departments/recaps/articles/eavl02102.shtml, accessed November 2002).

186 ICG (fh. 178), 3–7.

187 Ariel Cohen, “Confronting Kazakhstan's ‘Dutch Disease,’” Central Asia-Caucasus Analyst, March 26,2003 (www.cacianalyst.org/view_article.php?articleid=1263, accessed April 2003); and Karl, Terry, The Paradox of Plenty (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1999)Google Scholar.

188 Ross, Michael L., “Does Oil Hinder Democracy?” World Politics 53 (April 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.