Skip to main content
×
×
Home

United States – Anti-Dumping Act of 1916 (Original Complaint by the European Communities) – Recourse to Arbitration by the United States under 22.6 of the DSU, WT/DS136/ARB, 24 February 2004: A Legal and Economic Analysis

  • Robert Howse (a1) and Robert W. Staiger (a2)
Extract

This arbitration on the level of countermeasures, pursuant to the Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU) 22.6, originates from findings against the United States with respect to a provision of the 1916 Anti-Dumping Act, which permits a private cause of action for treble damages against an alleged dumping importer or producer where the dumping meets certain criteria including, notably, a predatory intention. An unusual feature of this case is that, apparently, the provision in question has never been used, at least against the European Community (EC), the complainant. In any case, the provision in question was found to be in violation of the WTO Anti-Dumping Agreement, both because it would impose measures on dumping other than and in addition to anti-dumping duties, and because in so doing, the procedural requirements of the Anti-Dumping Agreement would not be followed.

    • Send article to Kindle

      To send this article to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about sending to your Kindle. Find out more about sending to your Kindle.

      Note you can select to send to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be sent to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

      Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

      United States – Anti-Dumping Act of 1916 (Original Complaint by the European Communities) – Recourse to Arbitration by the United States under 22.6 of the DSU, WT/DS136/ARB, 24 February 2004: A Legal and Economic Analysis
      Available formats
      ×
      Send article to Dropbox

      To send this article to your Dropbox account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your <service> account. Find out more about sending content to Dropbox.

      United States – Anti-Dumping Act of 1916 (Original Complaint by the European Communities) – Recourse to Arbitration by the United States under 22.6 of the DSU, WT/DS136/ARB, 24 February 2004: A Legal and Economic Analysis
      Available formats
      ×
      Send article to Google Drive

      To send this article to your Google Drive account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your <service> account. Find out more about sending content to Google Drive.

      United States – Anti-Dumping Act of 1916 (Original Complaint by the European Communities) – Recourse to Arbitration by the United States under 22.6 of the DSU, WT/DS136/ARB, 24 February 2004: A Legal and Economic Analysis
      Available formats
      ×
Copyright
References
Hide All

1 Robert, Howse and Damien, Neven, 2004. “United States - Tax treatment for ‘Foreign Sales Corporations’ Recourse to Arbitration by the United States under Article 22.6 of the DSU and Article 4.11 of the SCM Agreement (WT/DS106/ARB): A comment,” in Horn, and Mavroidis, (eds.) The WTO Case Law of 2002, The American Law Institute Reporters’ Studies, Cambridge University Press, 2004.

2 This is a complex issue conceptually: on the relationship between “egalite” and “equivalence” in economic justice, see Kojeve, A., Outline of a Phenomenology of Right, tr. Frost and Howse (2000).

3 Cannizzaro, E., “The Role of Proportionality in the Law of International Countermeasures,” EJIL (2001) 889916, pp. 902–903.

4 See, for example, Analytical Index: Guide to GATT Law and Practice, Volume 2, WTO, 1995, pp. 657–658.

5 The Arbitrators emphasize (pp. 16–17, 5.24–5.28) that their trade-effects approach follows in line with the general approach adopted in earlier arbitrations. However, given the nature and application of the US Anti-Dumping Act of 1916, any possible trade effects would have had to take the form of a “chilling” or deterrent effect, and the Arbitrators considered but ultimately rejected the quantification of such effects as too speculative. Consequently, most of the Arbitrators' discussion with regard to the level of nullification or impairment caused by the 1916 Act focuses on direct monetary payments made by European companies to the United States as a result of final legal judgements or settlements under the 1916 Act. We focus our evaluation on the general economic rationale for the trade effects approach, and for simplicity we ignore in our discussion the additional means of nullification or impairment that arose more specifically in the context of the 1916 Act (e.g. final legal judgments against foreign firms).

6 See Sykes, Alan O., “The Remedy for Breach of Obligations Under the WTO Dispute Settlement Understanding: Damages or Specific Performance?” in Bronckers, Marco and Quick, Reinhard (eds.) New Directions in International Economic Law, Kluwer Law International (The Hague), 2000; Schwartz, Warren F. and Sykes, Alan O., “The Economic Structure of Renegotiation and Dispute Resolution in the World Trade Organization,” Journal of Legal Studies 31, 2002; and Lawrence, Robert Z., Crimes & Punishments? – Retaliation Under the WTO, Institute for International Economics (Washington, DC) 2003. Sykes (2000) and Schwartz and Sykes (2002) also offer a number of arguments for why the WTO might favor a liability-rule approach over the natural alternative of a “property-rule” approach, which would allow a government to escape from its commitments only after securing the permission of adversely affected trading partners. We refer the reader to those papers for further discussion of these and related issues.

7 In principle, it might be possible that the resulting network of bilateral breaches could ultimately come to rest at a new internationally efficient point. But as a practical matter, the potential for instability seems real, and so we view these multilateral spillovers as a crucial fault associated with the remedies described in Figure 2. We also note that, by assuming that the tangency condition depicted in Figure 2 for the two-country case applies as well to an efficient point in our four-country example, we are implicitly assuming that the particular efficient MFN tariffs under consideration are “politically optimal” tariffs (see Kyle, Bagwell, and Staiger, Robert W., “An Economic Theory of GATT,” American Economic Review, March 1999; and Kyle, Bagwell, and Staiger, Robert W., The Economics ofThe World Trading System, MIT Press, 2002). More generally, as shown in Kyle, Bagwell, and Staiger, Robert W., “Multilateral Trade Negotiations, Bilateral Opportunism and the Rules of GATT/WTO,” Journal of International Economics, December 2005, efficient MFN tariffs in a multi-country setting do not imply a tangency such as that depicted in Figure 2, but these (non-politically-optimal) efficient points suffer from a related kind of instability even in the absence of preference shocks.

8 This point is related to the seminal observations of Murray, Kemp, and Wan, Henry L Jr., “An Elementary Proposition Concerning the Formation of Customs Unions,” Journal of International Economics 6, 1976. The essential observation underlying the present discussion, that reciprocal tariff changes in the presence of MFN leave third countries unaffected, is shown in Bagwell and Staiger (2005). We also note that we have couched our arguments in broad terms, so that we may interpret essential features of the trade-effects approach as that approach is applied in a wide variety of settings (e.g. Arts. XIX, XXIII, and XXVIII). However, our multilateral stability arguments are made under the assumption that both the initial breach and the retaliation are non-discriminatory, and hence conform to MFN. This assumption fits well in the context of Arts. XIX and XXVIII. But discriminatory measures are often at the heart of Art. XXIII disputes, and Art. XXIII provides explicitly for discriminatory retaliation, so this assumption will often be violated in the context of Art. XXIII, weakening our arguments for the multilateral stability of the trade-effects remedy in this context. While a deeper exploration of the stability properties of the trade effects approach in a discriminatory setting would be interesting and worthwhile, we simply observe here that the economic appeal of the trade-effects approach will be strongest in settings where deviations from MFN are relatively minor.

9 See Bagwell and Staiger (1999, 2002), for a development of the notion of politically optimal tariffs.

10 See Alan Winters, L., “Regionalism and the Rest of the World: The Irrelevance of the Kemp-Wan Theorem,” Oxford Economic Papers, 1997, for a discussion of the distinction between fixed equilibrium trade volumes and a fixed terms of trade.

11 For further discussion of the links between standard economic arguments and the GATT/ WTO concept of market access, see Bagwell, and Staiger, (2002).

12 See Staiger, Robert W. and Wolak, Frank A., “Measuring Industry-Specific Protection: Antidumping in the United States,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1994, pp. 51118; and Krupp, Corinne M. and Pollard, Patricia S., “Market Responses to Antidumping Laws: Some Evidence from the US Chemical Industry,” Canadian Journal of Economics 29(1), February 1996, pp. 199227.

13 See, for example, Shin, Hyun Ja, “Possible Instances of Predatory Pricing in Recent Antidumping Cases,” in Lawrence, Robert Z. (ed.), Brookings Trade Forum, 1998, pp. 8198.

14 Jackson, J.H., “The WTO Dispute Settlement Understanding-Misunderstanding on the Nature of Legal Obligation,” 91 American Journal of International Law 60 (1997).

15 Sykes, A.O., “The Remedy for Breach of Obligations under the WTO Dispute Settlement Understanding: Damages or Specific Performance?” in Bronckers, M. and Quick, R., eds., New Directions in International Economic Law: Essays in Honour of John H. Jackson (The Hague: Kluwer, 2000), pp. 347357.

16 Esserman, Susan and Howse, Robert 2004, “The WTO on trial,” Foreign Affairs, 82(1), 130140. Howse, Robert and Nicolaidis, Kalypso, (2003), “Enhancing WTO legitimacy constitutionalization or global subsidiarity?Governance, 16(1), 7394.

17 We have benefited from the illuminating discussion ofrelated and similar considerations in Jackson, John H., “Status of WTO Dispute Settlement Reports: Obligations to Comply or Option to ‘Buy Out’?American Journal ofInternational Law, January 2004, 109125.

* We thank participants at ALI meetings where we presented this paper for helpful comments, particularly Alan Sykes, Frieder Roessler, and Gary Horlick.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

World Trade Review
  • ISSN: 1474-7456
  • EISSN: 1475-3138
  • URL: /core/journals/world-trade-review
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×

Metrics

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 0
Total number of PDF views: 28 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 419 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between September 2016 - 19th September 2018. This data will be updated every 24 hours.