Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-sxzjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-17T11:56:25.441Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The organisation of markets as a key factor in the rise of Holland from the fourteenth to the sixteenth century: a test case for an institutional approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2012

BAS VAN BAVEL
Affiliation:
Utrecht University.
JESSICA DIJKMAN
Affiliation:
Utrecht University.
ERIKA KUIJPERS
Affiliation:
Leiden University.
JACO ZUIJDERDUIJN
Affiliation:
Utrecht University.

Abstract

Although the importance of New Institutional Economics and the institutional approach for understanding pre-industrial economic development and the early growth of markets are widely accepted, it has proven to be difficult to assess more directly the effects of institutions on the functioning of markets. This paper uses empirical research on the rise of markets in late medieval Holland to illuminate some of the factors behind the development of the specific institutional framework of markets for land, labour, capital and goods, and some effects of these institutions on the actual functioning of the markets. The findings are corroborated by a tentative comparison with the functioning of markets in Flanders and eastern England.

L'organisation des marchés comme facteur-clé dans la croissance de la hollande du quatorzième au seizième siècle: un scénario de test pour une approche institutionnelle

Malgré l'importance incontestée de la Nouvelle Économie Institutionnelle et du recours à l'approche institutionnelle pour comprendre le développement économique préindustriel et la croissance précoce des marchés, il se révèle bien difficile d'évaluer plus directement tous les effets des institutions sur le fonctionnement des marchés. Dans le cadre de cet article, nous avons recours à une recherche empirique pour étudier la croissance des marchés en Hollande du bas moyen âge pour éclairer certains des facteurs qui autorisèrent le développement d'un cadre institutionnel spécifique concernant aussi bien le marché de la terre que celui du travail, celui des capitaux et celui des marchandises et certains des effets qu'eurent ces institutions sur le fonctionnement réel des marchés. Les résultats du test sont confirmés par un essai de comparaison avec le fonctionnement des marchés en Flandre et Angleterre de l'Est.

Die marktorganisation als schlüsselfaktor für den aufstieg hollands vom 14. bis zum 16. jahrhundert: testlauf für einen institutionellen forschungsansatz

Obwohl die Bedeutung der Neuen Institutionenökonomik und des institutionellen Ansatzes für das Verständnis der vorindustriellen Wirtschaftsentwicklung und das frühe Wachstum von Märkten allgemein anerkannt sind, hat es sich doch als schwierig erwiesen, die Wirkungen von Institutionen auf die Funktionsweise von Märkten genauer zu erfassen. Dieser Beitrag fußt auf empirischer Forschung über die Herausbildung von Märkten im spätmittelalterlichen Holland, um einige der Faktoren, welche die Entwicklung spezifischer institutioneller Rahmenbedingungen der Märkte für Land, Arbeit, Kapital und Güter beeinflussten, sowie einige Auswirkungen dieser Institutionen auf die tatsächliche Funktionsweise der Märkte zu beleuchten. Die Ergebnisse lassen sich durch einen vorläufigen Vergleich mit der Funktionsweise von Märkten in Flandern und Ostengland untermauern.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

ENDNOTES

1 North, D. C. and Thomas, R., The rise of the western world. A new economic history (New York, 1973)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Ogilvie, Sheilagh, ‘Whatever is, is right? Economic institutions in pre-industrial Europe’, Economic History Review 60 (2007), 649–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here 668–71.

3 A notion more often found in work on political economy, and recently made again by Ogilvie, ‘Whatever is, is right?’, 649–84.

4 van Bavel, Bas, de Moor, Tine and van Zanden, Jan Luiten, ‘Introduction: factor markets in global economic history’, Continuity and Change 24, 1 (2009), 921CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Jan Luiten van Zanden estimates the tertiary sector at 22 per cent in 1514. van Zanden, J. L., ‘Taking the measure of the early modern economy. Historical national accounts for Holland in 1510/1514’, European Review of Economic History 6 (2002), 131–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar, especially 138; see also van Bavel, B. J. P., ‘Early proto-industrialization in the Low Countries? The importance and nature of market-oriented non-agricultural activities in the countryside in Flanders and Holland, c. 1250–1570’, Revue Belge de philologie et d'histoire 81 (2003), 1109–187CrossRefGoogle Scholar, especially 1143.

6 van Bavel, B. J. P., ‘Rural wage labour in the in the sixteenth-century Low Countries. An assessment of the importance and nature of wage labour in the countryside of Holland, Guelders and Flanders’, Continuity and Change 21, 1 (2006), 3772CrossRefGoogle Scholar, especially 62–3.

7 van Bavel, B. J. P. and van Zanden, J. L., ‘The jump-start of the Holland economy during the late-medieval crisis, c. 1350–c. 1500’, Economic History Review 57, 3 (2004), 503–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 North and Thomas, The rise of the western world, 132–45.

9 de Vries, J. and van der Woude, A. M., The first modern economy: success, failure and perseverance of the Dutch economy, 1500–1815 (Cambridge, 1997), 159–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10 These investigations were part of the research project ‘Power, markets and economic development: the rise, organisation and institutional framework of markets in Holland, eleventh–sixteenth centuries’. The project was carried out at Utrecht University, 2001–2007 (funded by the Netherlands Organisation for Scientific Research (NWO), directed by Bas van Bavel).

11 Campbell, B. M. S., ‘Factor markets in England before the Black Death’, Continuity and Change 24, 1 (2009), 79106CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 For an overview, see Van Bavel and Van Zanden, ‘The jump-start’, 505; and P. C. M. Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Van waterland tot stedenland. De Hollandse economie ca. 975–ca. 1570’, in T. de Nijs and E. Beukers, Geschiedenis van Holland, I, Tot 1572 (Hilversum, 2002), 103–48, especially 136.

13 Van Bavel and Van Zanden, ‘The jump-start’.

14 W. P. Blockmans, G. Pieters and W. Prevenier, ‘Het sociaal-economische leven 1300–1482. Tussen crisis en welvaart. Sociale veranderingen 1300–1500’, in D. P. Blok, W. Prevenier and D. J. Roorda eds., Algemene Geschiedenis der Nederlanden IV (Haarlem, 1982), 42–86, here 43–6.

15 M. Bailey, Medieval Suffolk. An economic and social history, 1200–1500 (Woodbridge, 2007), 129, 149–51. Chris Dyer gives the slightly lower figures of 14 and 27 per cent, respectively; see C. Dyer, ‘How urbanized was medieval England?’, in J.-M. Duvosquel and E. Thoen eds., Peasants and townsmen in medieval Europe. Studia in honorem Adriaan Verhulst (Ghent, 1995), 169–83. No similar calculations are available for Norfolk.

16 Bailey, Medieval Suffolk, 67 and 183–4. Population developments in Norfolk display a similar trend. See Whittle, Jane, The development of agrarian capitalism. Land and labour in Norfolk, 1440–1580 (Oxford, 2000), 175–6CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

17 Bailey, Medieval Suffolk, 265–6.

18 Campbell, ‘Factor markets in England’; and B. J. P. van Bavel, ‘The land market in the North Sea area in a comparative perspective, 13th–18th centuries’, in S. Cavaciocchi ed., Il mercato della terra secc. XIII–XVIII. Atti delle “Settimane di Studi” e altri convegni 35 (Prato, 2003), 119–45.

19 Whittle, The development, 93 and 99. See also below pp. 355–359.

20 Van Bavel, ‘The land market’, 129–32; also for the following, and for Norfolk, see Whittle, The development, 31 and 76–82.

21 B. J. P. van Bavel, ‘The emergence and growth of short-term leasing in the Netherlands and other parts of northwestern Europe (11th–16th centuries). A tentative investigation into its chronology and causes’, in B. J. P. van Bavel and P. Schofield eds., The rise of leasing. CORN Publication series 10 (Turnhout, 2009), 179–213.

22 C. J. Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets. Markets for renten, state formation and private investment in Holland (1300–1550) (Leiden/Boston, 2009), 184–90.

23 P. R. Schofield, ‘Access to credit in the early fourteenth-century English countryside’, in P. R. Schofield and N. J. Mayhew eds., Credit and debt in medieval England c. 1180–c. 1350 (Oxford, 2002), 106–26, especially 119.

24 Many of these pamphleteers pressed for the adoption of registration systems found in Holland and elsewhere in the Dutch Republic. An overview of this literature is given in Publications on registering deeds of land’, The Legal Observer or Journal of Jurisprudence 1 (1831), 234Google Scholar; and The registry question in former times’, The Jurist or Quarterly Journal of Jurisprudence and Legislation 4 (1833), 2643Google Scholar.

25 T. de Moor, J. L. van Zanden and J. Zuijderduijn, ‘Micro-credit in late medieval Waterland. Households and the efficiency of capital markets in Edam en De Zeevang (1462–1563)’, in S. Cavaciocchi ed., The economic role of the family in the European economy from the 13th to 18th centuries (Florence, 2009), 651–68.

26 Howell, Martha C., The marriage exchange: property, social place, and gender in cities of the Low Countries, 1300–1550 (Chicago, 1998), 202–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Whittle, Jane, ‘Inheritance, marriage, widowhood and remarriage: a comparative perspective on women and landholding in north-east Norfolk, 1440–1580’, Continuity and Change 13, 1 (1998), 3372CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 Bailey, M., ‘Villeinage in England: a regional case study, c. 1250–c. 1349’, Economic History Review 62, 2 (2009), 430–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here 433–5.

28 Nicholas, David, Medieval Flanders (London, 1992), 106Google Scholar.

29 Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Van waterland tot stedenland’, 137.

30 Bailey, Medieval Suffolk, 197, 199.

31 Hatcher, J., ‘England in the aftermath of the Black Death’, Past and Present 144 (Aug. 1994), 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Clark, Elaine, ‘Medieval labor law and English local courts’, American Journal of Legal History 27 (1983), 330–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and on sixteenth-century legislation, see Woodward, D., ‘The background to the statute of artificers: the genesis of labour policy, 1558–63’, Economic History Review 33, 1 (1980), 3244Google Scholar.

32 In Flanders run-aways could count on a whipping, see the ordinances of Hulsterambacht 1440 and 1546, Bosch, ‘Rechtshistorische aanteekeningen’, 384, Also a Brabant by-law from 1587 states that a servant that breaks his contract will be submitted to criminal law: Ibid., 382.

33 Bosch, J. W., ‘Rechtshistorische aanteekeningen betreffende de overeenkomst tot het huren van dienstpersoneel’, Themis: regtskundig tijdschrift 92 (1931), 355418Google Scholar and 93 (1932), 23–92 and 215–77.

34 Bosch, , Themis 92, 355418Google Scholar.

35 Bailey, Medieval Suffolk, 184–93; Whittle describes the enforcement of labour laws in Norfolk: see The development, 287–96.

36 Bolton, J. L., The Medieval English economy, 1150–1500 (London, 1980), 213Google Scholar; see also Cohn, Samuel, ‘After the Black Death: labour legislation and attitudes towards labour in late-medieval western Europe’, Economic History Review 60, 3 (2007), 457–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Poos, L. R., ‘The social context of the Statute of Labourers Enforcement’, Law and History Review 1 (1983), 2752CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here 34–7; Clark, ‘Medieval labor law’, 330–53.

37 Whittle, The development, 294.

38 Ibid., 295.

39 Woodward, ‘The background to the Statute of Artificers’.

40 Cohn, ‘After the Black Death’.

41 C. Given-Wilson, ‘Service, serfdom and English labour legislation, 1350–1500, in A. Curry and E. Matthews eds., Concepts and patterns of service in the later Middle Ages (Woodbridge, 2000), 21–37, especially 24.

42 Hamaker, H. G., De Middeneeuwsche keurboeken van de stad Leiden (Leiden, 1873), 60, 240Google Scholar.

43 Schofield, Phillipp R., Peasant and community in medieval England, 1200–1500 (Basingstoke, 2003), 1415, 21–2CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Baker, J. H., An introduction to English legal history, 4th edn. (London, 2002), 22–7, 233–6Google Scholar.

44 Le Bailly, M. C., Recht voor de Raad. Rechtspraak voor het Hof van Holland, Zeeland en West-Friesland in het midden van de vijftiende eeuw (Hilversum, 2001)Google Scholar.

45 Developments in Holland are discussed by Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets.

46 Allen, R. C., Enclosure and the yeoman (Oxford, 1992), 102–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hopcroft, R. L. and Emigh, R. J., ‘Divergent paths of agrarian change: eastern England and Tuscany compared’, Journal of European Economic History 29, 1 (2000), 951Google Scholar, especially 15–16. Compare with the near-absence of mortgages in medieval England: C. Briggs, Credit and village society in fourteenth-century England (Oxford, 2009), 83.

47 H. De Schepper and J.-M. Cauchies, ‘Legal tools of the public power in the Netherlands 1200–1600’, in A. Padoa-Schioppa ed., The origins of the modern state in Europe, 13th to 18th centuries. Legislation and justice (Oxford/Strasbourg, 1996), 229–68, especially 254 and 265.

48 P. C. M. Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Town and country in Holland, 1300–1550’, in S. R. Epstein ed., Town and country in Europe, 1300–1800 (Cambridge, 2001), 54–79, here 72–3.

49 J. R. Maddicott, ‘The English peasantry and the demands of the crown 1294–1341’, in T. H. Aston ed., Landlords, peasants and politics in medieval England (Cambridge, 1987), 285–359, especially 299–318; James Masschaele, Peasants, merchants, and markets. Inland trade in medieval England, 1150–1350 (New York, 1997), 36–41.

50 Janse, A., Grenzen aan de macht. De Friese oorlog van de graven van Holland omstreeks 1400 (The Hague, 1993), 299308Google Scholar.

51 Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets, 107–8, 152–3. In England, according to Mieczysław Fryde and Edmund Fryde, forced loans became ‘fairly common’ in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. See M. M. Fryde and E. B. Fryde, ‘Public credit, with special reference to north-western Europe’, in M. M. Postan, E. E. Rich and E. Miller eds., The Cambridge economic history of Europe. Volume III. Economic organization and policies in the Middle Ages (Cambridge, 1971), 430–553, especially 435.

52 Beresford, M. W., New towns of the Middle Ages. Town plantation in England, Wales and Gascony (London, 1967), 182Google Scholar; Rigaudière, A., ‘Le financement des fortifications urbaines en France du milieu du XIVe siècle à la fin du XVe siècle’, Revue historique 553 (Jan. 1985), 1995, here 36Google Scholar.

53 As seems to have been the case in Leiden (Leyden) 1426, when the town was at war and corvée labour was organised at the town moats. A. Meerkamp van Embden ed., De stadsrekeningen van Leiden (1390–1424; 1424–1434). WHG 3rd series, 32 and 34 (Amsterdam, 1913), vol. II, 94–6.

54 B. J. P. van Bavel and P. C. M. Hoppenbrouwers, Landholding and land transfer in the North Sea area (late Middle Ages–19th century). CORN Publication series 5 (Turnhout, 2004), 22–4.

55 Nicholas, D., Town and countryside: social, economic, and political tensions in fourteenth-century Flanders (Bruges, 1971), 117–18Google Scholar; Stabel, Peter, Dwarfs among giants. The Flemish urban network in the late Middle Ages (Louvain, 1997), 163–5Google Scholar.

56 Unger, W. S., ‘De Hollandsche graanhandel en de graanhandelspolitiek in de middeleeuwen’, De Economist 65 (1916), 243–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 337–87, 461–87, especially 356–7.

57 Korteweg, K. N., ‘Het stadsrecht van Geertruidenberg’, Verslagen en mededeelingen der Vereeniging tot uitgaaf der bronnen van het oud-vaderlands recht 10 (1946), 1683Google Scholar, especially 67–8; Reinout Jan Rutte, Stedenpolitiek en stadsplanning in de Lage Landen (12de–13de eeuw) (Zutphen, 2002), 115–17.

58 Jessica Dijkman, Shaping medieval markets. The organisation of commodity markets in Holland, C. 1200 – C. 1450 (Leiden, 2011), 108–58.

59 James Galloway, ‘Town and country in England, 1300–1570’, in S. R. Epstein ed., Town and country in Europe, 1300–1800 (Cambridge, 2001), 106–31, especially 117.

60 For informal rural trade in the West Midlands, see Dyer, C., ‘The hidden trade of the Middle Ages: evidence from the West Midlands of England’, Journal of Historical Geography 18 (1992), 141–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

61 Dijkman, Shaping medieval markets, 89–6.

62 For example, Poos, Lawrence R. and Bonfield, Lloyd, Select cases in manorial courts, 1250–1550. Property and family law (London, 1998)Google Scholar.

63 Whittle, The development, especially 37–63; Mark Bailey recently downplayed the role of villeinage in Suffolk, however. See Bailey, ‘Villeinage in England’.

64 See Razi, Zvi, ‘Serfdom and freedom in medieval England: a reply to the revisionists’, Past and Present 195, Supplement 2 (2007), 182–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hatcher, J., ‘English serfdom and villeinage: towards a reassessment’, Past and Present 90, 1 (1981), 339CrossRefGoogle Scholar; C. Dyer, ‘Work ethics in the fourteenth century’, in James Bothwell, P. J. P. Goldberg and W. M. Ormrod, eds., The problem of labour in fourteenth-century England (York, 2000), 21–41; Hatcher, John, ‘Labour, leisure and economic thought before the 19th century’, Past and Present 160, 1 (1998), 64115CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

65 North, D. C., Institutions, institutional change and economic performance (Cambridge, 1990), 69CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

66 Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets, 112–29; Zuijderduijn, J., ‘Het lichaam van het dorp. Publieke schuld op het Hollandse platteland rond 1500’, Tijdschrift voor Sociale en Economische Geschiedenis 5 (2008), 107–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

67 E. Isenmann, Die deutsche Stadt im Spätmittelalter (Stuttgart, 1988), 174–6; H.-J. Gilomen, ‘Renten, Rentenkauf, Rentenmarkt’, in Lexikon des Mittelalters VII (Munich/Zürich, 1995), 735–8.

68 Webber, C. and Wildavsky, A., A history of taxation and expenditure in the western world (New York, 1986), 253–4, 257Google Scholar.

69 Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets, 129–34.

70 Qualitative and quantitative evidence is presented in Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets, 183–247, and in C. Van Bochove, H. Deneweth and J. Zuijderduijn, ‘Real estate and financial markets in England and the Low Countries, 1300–1800’ (working paper, 2011), 24–5, showing averages of 18 to 49 annuities contracted per 1,000 inhabitants per annum for Holland in the fifteenth to sixteenth centuries. These figures, which are derived from registers of annuities mortgaged on land, may serve to estimate the total volume of the capital market in Holland in the fourteenth century. Even if we reduce the aforementioned figures to a very conservative 5 annuities per 1000 inhabitants per annum, and consider the population of Holland to have been c. 200,000 in 1400, we would still have 100,000 annuities contracted in Holland in the fourteenth century. This is not exceptional for northwestern Europe though: inhabitants of Lübeck, a town in the north of Germany with c. 20,000 inhabitants, contracted 2,557 annuities between 1275 and 1315.

71 Zuijderduijn, Medieval capital markets, 231–42.

72 For example, in Den Bosch at the beginning of the sixteenth century, see Hanus, Jord, Tussen stad en eigen gewin. Stadsfinanciën, renteniers en kredietmarkten in 's-Hertogenbosch (begin zestiende eeuw) (Amsterdam, 2007)Google Scholar.

73 Briggs, Chris, ‘Empowered or marginalized? Rural women and credit in later thirteenth- and fourteenth-century England’, Continuity and Change 19, 1 (2004), 343CrossRefGoogle Scholar, here 15.

74 Van Bavel, ‘Rural wage labour’.

75 Whittle, The development, 227–31, with some notes on the reliability of the sources, and J. P. Cooper, ‘In search of agrarian capitalism’, in T. H. Aston and C. H. E. Philpin eds., The Brenner debate: agrarian class structure and economic development in pre-industrial Europe (Cambridge, 1985), 138–91, especially 167–8.

76 J. Bieleman, Geschiedenis van de landbouw in Nederland, 1500–1950: veranderingen en verscheidenheid (Meppel, 1992), 55–6. Compare for Flanders: E. Thoen, ‘A “commercial survival economy” in evolution. The Flemish countryside and the transition to capitalism (Middle Ages–19th century)’, in P. C. M. Hoppenbrouwers and J. L. van Zanden eds., Peasants into farmers? The transformation of rural economy and society in the Low Countries (Middle Ages–19th century) in light of the Brenner debate, CORN Publication series 4 (Turnhout, 2001), 102–49.

77 For the figures underlying this estimate, see Dijkman, Shaping medieval markets, 317–25.

78 Zuijderduijn, ‘Het lichaam’, 130.

79 J. Zuijderduijn, ‘Village-indebtedness in Holland (15th–16th centuries)’, in P. R. Schofield and T. Lambrecht eds., Credit and the rural economy in north-western Europe c. 1200–c. 1850. CORN Publication series 12 (Turnhout, 2009), 39–62.

80 De Moor, van Zanden and Zuijderduijn, ‘Micro-credit’, 658–9.

81 Ibid., 659.

82 For the southern Low Countries, see M. J. Tits-Dieuaide, La formation des prix céréaliers en Brabant et en Flandres au XVe siècle (Brussels, 1975), 36–44; for the London region, see Bruce M. S. Campbell, James A. Galloway, Derek Keene and Margaret Murphy, A medieval capital and its grain supply: agrarian production and distribution in the London region c. 1300 (Belfast/London, 1993), 46–77; James A. Galloway, ‘One market or many? London and the grain trade of England’, in James A. Galloway ed., Trade, urban hinterlands and market integration c. 1300–1600 (London, 2000), 23–41.

83 Campbell, Galloway, Keene and Murphy, A medieval capital, 27–8, 180–2.

84 Dijkman, Shaping medieval markets, 304–11. Besides Noordwijkerhout and Bruges, the following locations were included in this analysis: Ghent, Louvain, Brussels, Utrecht, Maastricht, London and Exeter.

85 P. Stabel, De kleine stad in Vlaanderen. Bevolkingsdynamiek en economische functies van de kleine en secundaire stedelijke centra in het Gentse kwartier (14de–16de eeuw) (Brussels, 1995), 185–92, E. Thoen, Landbouwekonomie en bevolking in Vlaanderen gedurende de late middeleeuwen en het begin van de moderne tijden. Testregio: de kasselrijen van Oudenaarde en Aalst, eind 13de – eerste helft van de 16de eeuw (Ghent, 1988), 955–60.

86 Calculated using the data provided by Whittle, The development, 244.

87 Van Bavel and Van Zanden, ‘The jump-start’, 511–13.

88 In 1510 and in 1515, for example, hundreds of hired labourers who were working at the dikes near Haarlem (at its peak over 900 labourers at any one time) were recruited in all parts of Holland and beyond; see P. J. E. M. van Dam, ‘Digging for a dike. Holland's labour market ca. 1510’, in Hoppenbrouwers and van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 220–5, 247–9 (tables).

89 B. de Munck, P. Lourens and J. Lucassen, ‘The establishment and distribution of craft guilds in the Low Countries, 1000–1800', in M. R. Prak, C. Lis, J. Lucassen and H. Soly eds., Craft guilds in the early modern Low Countries: work, power, and representation (Aldershot, 2006), 32–73.

90 De Vries, Jan, ‘On the modernity of the Dutch Republic’, Journal of Economic History 33, 1 (1973), 191202CrossRefGoogle Scholar; W. P. Blockmans, ‘The economic expansion of Holland and Zeeland in the fourteenth-sixteenth centuries’, in E. A. Aerts, B. Henau, P. Janssens and R. van Uytven eds., Studia Historica Oeconomica. Liber Amicorum Herman van der Wee (Louvain, 1993), 41–58.

91 De Vries and Van der Woude, The first modern economy, 160.

92 The argument goes back to H. van der Linden, ‘Het platteland in het Noordwesten met nadruk op de occupatie circa 1000–1300’, in D. P. Blok, W. Prevenier and D. J. Roorda eds., Algemene Geschiedenis der Nederlanden II (Haarlem, 1982), 48–82, especially 73–8. See a recent survey of the reclamation of the peat lands by Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Van waterland tot stedenland’; on the position of the nobility, J. de Vries, ‘The transition to capitalism in a land without feudalism’, in Hoppenbrouwers and van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 67–84, especially 75–6; on the early emergence of public bodies, C. van der Kieft, ‘De stedelijke autonomie in het graafschap Holland gedurende de middeleeuwen’, Holland Historisch Tijdschrift 1 (1969) 98–104, especially 99, and H. Mitteis, Rechtsfolgen des Leistungsverzugs beim Kaufvertrag nach niederländischen Quellen des Mittelalters. Ein Beitrag zur Geschichte des Handelsrecht (Heidelberg, 1913), 20–1.

93 Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Town and country’, 76–8.

94 J. C. N. Raadschelders, ‘Plaatselijke bestuurlijke ontwikkelingen 1600–1980. Een historisch-bestuurskundig onderzoek in vier Noord-Hollandse gemeenten’ (unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Leiden, 1990); C. M. Lesger, Hoorn als stedelijk knooppunt. Stedensystemen tijdens de late middeleeuwen en vroegmoderne tijd (Hilversum, 1990), 215.

95 D. E. H. de Boer, Graaf en grafiek. Sociale en economische ontwikkelingen in het middeleeuwse ‘Noordholland’ tussen ±1345 en ±1415 (Leiden, 1978), 211–45.

96 Van Bavel and Van Zanden, ‘The jump-start’; Van Zanden, ‘Taking the measure’, 149–50; J. L. van Zanden, ‘A third road to capitalism? Proto-industrialisation and the moderate nature of the late medieval crisis in Flanders and Holland, 1350–1550’, in Hoppenbrouwers and van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 85–101; Van Bavel, ‘Early proto-industrialization’.

97 Van Bavel, ‘Early proto-industrialization’, 1162; P. C. M. Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Mapping an unexplored field. The Brenner debate and the case of Holland’, in Hoppenbrouwers and van Zanden, Peasants into farmers?, 41–66, here 54–7.

98 Van Zanden, ‘Taking the measure’.

99 van den Berg, W. J. and van Zanden, J. L., ‘Vier eeuwen welstandsongelijkheid in Alkmaar, ca. 1530–1930’, Tijdschrift voor Sociale Geschiedenis 19, 2 (1993), 193215Google Scholar.

100 Lee Soltow and Jan Luiten van Zanden, Income and wealth inequality in the Netherlands 16th–20th century (Amsterdam, 1998), especially 77–110.

101 P. Lourens and J. Lucassen, ‘“Zunftlandschaften” in den Niederlanden und im benachbarten Deutschland’, in Wilfried Reininghaus ed., Zunftlandschaften in Deutschland und den Niederlanden im Vergleich (Münster, 2000), 11–43, here 15–20; E. Kuijpers and M. Prak, ‘Burger, ingezetene, vreemdeling. Burgerschap in Amsterdam in de 17e en 18e eeuw’, in J. Kloek and K. Tilmans eds., Burger. Een geschiedenis van het begrip in de Nederlanden van de Middeleeuwen tot de 21e eeuw (Amsterdam, 2002), 113–32, especially 121–2.

102 B. J. P. van Bavel, ‘Rural development and landownership in Holland, c. 1400–1650’, in O. Gelderblom ed., The political economy of the Dutch Republic (Farnham, 2009), 167–96.

103 Brünner, E. C. G., De order op de buitennering van 1531. Bijdrage tot de kennis van de economische geschiedenis van het graafschap Holland in den tijd van Karel V (Utrecht, 1918)Google Scholar; Hoppenbrouwers, ‘Town and country’, 64–6.