Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-m8qmq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T16:32:19.924Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Floor Behavior in the U.S. Congress: Committee Power Under the Open Rule

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Barry R. Weingast
Affiliation:
Hoover Institution

Abstract

The open rule in the House is a complex set of restrictions, limiting, for example, the number of motions and the order of recognition. By incorporating constraints based on the actual set of rules into a model, I show that legislative outcomes appear more predictable than was previously thought. These rules nearly always allow the proponents of legislation to respond to an opponent's amendment, mitigating the potential damage of the latter. An advantage of the approach is that it provides a new interpretation of the changes in floor activity observed in the postreform period.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Austen-Smith, David. 1986. “Endogenous Agenda Formation under Incomplete Information.” University of Rochester. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bach, Stanley. 1986. “Representatives and Committees on the Floor: Amendments to Appropriation Bills in the House of Representatives, 1963–82.” Congressional Research Service. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Bach, Stanley. 1987. “The Amendment Process in the U.S. House.” Congressional Research Service. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey, and Gasmi, Farid. 1985. “Endogenous Agenda Formation in Three-Person Committees.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New Orleans.Google Scholar
Baron, David, and Ferejohn, John. 1987. “The Power to Propose.” Stanford University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Baron, David, and Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” Stanford University. Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvert, Randall. 1987a. “Coordination and Power: The Foundation of Leadership among Rational Legislators.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall. 1987b. “Reputation and Legislative Leadership.” Public Choice 55:81120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denzau, Arthur, and Mackay, Robert. 1983. “Gatekeeping and the Monopoly Power of Committees.” American Journal of Political Science 27:740–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deschler, Lewis, and Brown, William Holmes. 1982. Procedure in the U.S. House of Representatives. 4th ed. Washington: GPO.Google Scholar
Dyson, James, and Soule, John. 1970. “Congressional Committee Behavior in Roll Call Votes: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1955–64.” Midwest Journal of Political Science 14:626–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenno, Richard. 1962. “The Appropriations Committee As a Political System.” In New Perspectives on the House of Representatives, 3rd ed., ed. Peabody, Robert L. and Polsby, Nelson W.. Chicago: Rand-McNally.Google Scholar
Fenno, Richard. 1966. Power of the Purse: Appropriations Politics in Congress. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Fenno, Richard. 1973. Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Froman, Lewis. 1967. The Congressional Process. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Gilligan, Thomas W., and Krehbiel, Keith. 1987. “Collective Decisionmaking and Standing Committees: An Informational Rationale for Restrictive Amendment Procedures.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3:287336.Google Scholar
Hall, Richard L., and Evans, Larry C.. 1985. “The Role of the Subcommittee in Committee Decision Making: An Explanation.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New Orleans.Google Scholar
Hinckley, Barbara. 1978. Stability and Change in Congress. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Humes, Brian. 1987. “Choice of a Gernmaness Rule.” Michigan State University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1987. “Institutional Erosion of Committee Power.” American Political Science Review 81:929–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David. 1984. “Corporate Culture.” Stanford University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard. 1976. “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models with Some Implications for Agenda Control.” Journal of Economic Theory 12:472–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, Donald R. 1960. U.S. Senators and Their World. New York: Vintage.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglas C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade, Part I: The Medieval Law Merchant.” Hoover Institution. Typescript.Google Scholar
Oleszek, Walter. 1984. Congressional Procedure and the Policy Process. 2d ed. Washington: Congressional Quarterly.Google Scholar
Olson, David. 1976. The Politics of Legislation. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Polsby, Nelson W. 1986. Congress and the Presidency. 4th ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Rieselbach, Leroy. 1973. Congressional Politics. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Riker, William H., and Austen-Smith, David. 1987. “Asymmetric Information and the Coherence of Legislation.” American Political Science Review 81:897918.Google Scholar
Ripley, Randall B. 1967. Party Leaders in the House of Representatives. Washington: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1982. “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model.” Econometrica 50:97109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1978. “Instability of Simple Dynamic Games.” Review of Economic Studies 45:575–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth, and Weingast, Barry. 1981. “Structure and Strategy.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York City.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1981. “Uncovered Sets and Sophisticated Voting Outcomes with Implications for Agenda Institutions.” American Journal of Political Science 28:4974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth, and Weingast, Barry. 1987. “Foundations of Committee Power.” American Political Science Review 81:85104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sinclair, Barbara. 1983. Majority Leadership in the U.S. House. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Steven. 1986. Revolution in the House: Why Don't We Do It on the Floor. Brookings Institution Discussion Paper in Government Studies no. 5.Google Scholar
Sullivan, Terry. 1987. “The Impact of Procedural Reform, 1960–80.” University of North Carolina. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry. 1989. “Fighting Fire with Fire: Amending Activity and Institutional Change in the Post-Reform Congress.” Hoover Institution. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry, and Marshall, William. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress.” Journal of Political Economy 96:132–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar