Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-42gr6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T12:32:01.027Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The political consequences of the product cycle: industrial history and political outcomes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Extract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

What explains the continuing stagnation in the industrial economies of the West? What will be the impact of such stagnation upon domestic politics and upon international relations? Are there domestic and foreign policies which the state can undertake to bring about a return to sustained economic prosperity and a recapitulation of that lost golden age of 1948–1973? These are now the central questions for scholars in the emerging field of international political economy. A recent special issue of International Organization, edited by Peter Katzenstein, has presented some of the most useful and sophisticated approaches to these questions and analyses of the international political economy of the West during the period of the last thirty years.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation and Cambridge University Press 1979

References

1 Katzenstein, Peter J., editor, Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States, a special issue of International Organization 31, 4 (Autumn 1977)Google Scholar. A systematic and perceptive review of recent literature on one theme of the new international political economy, the impact of international economics upon domestic politics, is given in Gourevitch, Peter, “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics,” International Organization 32, 4 (Autumn 1978).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 Schumpeter, Joseph A., Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process, two volumes (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1939).Google Scholar

3 Vernon, Raymond, Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of U.S. Enterprises (New York: Basic Books, 1971)Google Scholar. An earlier formulation of the idea of certain patterns or cycles in the development of industries can be found in Hoffmann, Walther G., The Growth of Industrial Economies, translated by Henderson, W. O. and Chaloner, W. H. (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1958).Google Scholar

4 Robert, Gilpin, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment (New York: Basic Books, 1975).Google Scholar

5 Hobsbawm, E. J., The Age of Revolution: Europe 1789–1848 (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1962)Google Scholar; also the country studies in Cipolla, Carlo M., editor, The Emergence of Industrial Societies (London: Collins, Fortana Books, 1973)Google Scholar. Statistics on the growth of the textile industry in European countries can be found in Mitchell, B. R., European Historical Statistics, 1750–1970 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1976), pp. 427436Google Scholar; and in Cipolla, op. cit., pp. 780788Google Scholar. Three useful overall accounts of European industrialization, from contrasting perspectives, are Landes, David S., The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969)Google Scholar; Tom, Kemp, Industrialization in Nineteenth Century Europe (London: Longman, 1969)Google Scholar; and Rostow, W. W., The Stages of Economic Growth (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1960; second edition, 1971)Google Scholar, elaborated in his The World Economy: History and Prospect (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1978). In his works, Rostow develops and employs at length the concepts of the leading sector.Google Scholar

6 Artz, Frederick B., Reaction and Revolution, 1814–1832 (New York: Harper and Row, 1963), chapters I–III; Hobsbawm, op. cit., chapter 2.Google Scholar

7 Quoted in Artz, Frederick B., op. cit., pp. 8586.Google Scholar

8 Hobsbawm, E. J., Industry and Empire: The Making of Modern Society, Vol. II, 1759 to the Present Day (New York: Pantheon, 1968), chapters 3–4Google Scholar; William, Langer, Political and Social Upheaval, 1832–1852 (New York: Harper and Row, 1969), chapters II–III.Google Scholar

9 Langer, op. cit., chapters III–IV; Artz, op. cit., chapters VIII, IX; Biucchi, B. M., “The Industrial Revolution in Switzerland,” in Cipolla, op. cit., pp. 627652.Google Scholar

10 On industrialization in Prussia and Austria, see Knut Borchandt, “The Industrial Revolution in Germany 1700–1914” and Gross, N. T., “The Industrial Revolution in the Habsburg Monarchy 1750–1914,” in Cipolla, op. cit., pp. 76156, 228276.Google Scholar

11 Langer, op. cit., chapter IV.

12 The economic basis of the contrast between Britain and Prussia is one theme discussed in Moore, Barrington Jr., Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966).Google Scholar

13 On industrialization in Italy and Spain, see Luciano Cafagna, “The Industrial Revolution in Italy 1830–1914” and Nadal, Jordi, “The Failure of the Industrial Revolution in Spain 1830–1914,” in Cipolla, op. cit., pp. 279325, 532620.Google Scholar

14 On Italian politics during the nineteenth century, see Whyte, Arthur James, The Evolution of Modern Italy (New York: W. W. Norton, 1965)Google Scholar; and Smith, Denis Mack, Italy: A Modern History, revised edition (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1969)Google Scholar. On Spanish politics, see Brenan, Gerald, The Spanish Labyrinth: An Account of the Social and Political Background of the Civil War (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1950)Google Scholar; and Ullman, Joan Connolly, The Tragic Week: A Study of Anticlericalism in Spain, 1875–1912 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1968).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Gallagher, John and Robinson, Ronald, “The Imperialism of Free Trade,” in Nadel, George H. and Curtis, Perry, editors, Imperialism and Colonialism (New York: Macmillan, 1964).Google Scholar

16 Hobsbawm, E. J., Industry and Empire, chapter 7.Google Scholar

17 Quoted in Edwardes, Michael, The Last Years of British India (Cleveland: World Publishing, 1963), p. 234.Google Scholar

18 Gerschenkron, Alexander, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1962).Google Scholar

19 O'Donnell, Guillermo A., Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism: Studies in South American Politics (Berkeley: International Studies, University of California, Berkeley, Politics of Modernization Series No. 9, 1973).Google Scholar

20 Hobsbawm, , Industry and Empire, chapters 6 and 7. A useful overall account of the growth and impact of the European iron and steel industries and railroads is Hobsbawm's The Age of Capital, 1848–1875 (New York: Charles Scribner's Sons, 1975).Google Scholar

21 See, for example, Gerschenkron, op. cit., and Cameron, Rondo E., France and the Economic Development of Europe, 1800–1914, Conquests of Peace and Seeds of War (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1961), chapter IV.Google Scholar

22 Elwitt, Sanford, The Making of the Third Republic: Class and Politics in France, 1868–1884 (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1975), introduction and chapter I.Google Scholar

23 Woodruff, William, “The Emergence of an International Economy, 1700–1914,” in Cipolla, op. cit., pp. 673674.Google Scholar

24 See, for example, Gerschenkron, op. cit., and Cameron, op. cit., chapter IV. A useful and detailed discussion of the relationships between economics and politics in Germany under Bis marck is presented by Stern, Fritz, Gold and Iron: Bismarck, Bleichröder, and the Building of the German Empire (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1977).Google Scholar

25 Cameron, op. cit., Henderson, W. O., Britain and Industrial Europe: 1750–1970: Studies in British Influence on the Industrial Revolution in Western Europe, third edition (London: Leicester University Press, 1972).Google Scholar

26 Cafagna, op. cit., pp. 289290, 302325.Google Scholar

27 See the comparison between Britain and America drawn by Robert Gilpin, op. cit.

28 W. O. Henderson, op. cit.

29 Rostow, W. W., British Economy in the 19th Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1948), p. 88. (Rostow originally developed his argument in 1938.)Google Scholar

30 The connections between the end of railroad expansion and the beginning of the Great Depression are also discussed in Hobsbawm, Industry and Empire. An excellent comparative analysis of the politics of the Great Depression is Gourevitch, Peter Alexis, “International Trade, Domestic Coalitions, and Liberty: Comparative Responses to the Crisis of 1873–1896,” The Journal of Inter-Disciplinary History, VIII (Autumn, 1977): 281313Google Scholar. An earlier classic account is Hans Rosenberg, “Political and Social Consequences of the Great Depression of 1873–1896 in Central Europe,” Economic History Review, XIII (1943): 5873.Google Scholar

31 Various aspects of imperialism are analyzed in Roger Owen and Bob Sutcliffe, editors, Studies in the Theory of Imperialism (London: Longman, 1972)Google Scholar.

32 Quoted in Carr, J. C. and Taplin, W., History of the British Steel Industry (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1962), p. 39.Google Scholar

33 Hobsbawm, , Industry and Empire, p. 107.Google Scholar

34 Rostow, , The World Economy, p. 381.Google Scholar

35 Data on the naval budgets of Britain and other European powers are given in Moll, Kendall D., The Influence of History Upon Seapower, 1865–1914 (Menlo Park, California: Stanford Research Institute, 1969).Google Scholar

36 Quoted in Marder, Arthur J., The Anatomy of British Sea Power: A History of British Naval Policy in the Pre-Dreadnought Era, 1880–1905 (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1940), p. 36.Google Scholar

37 Morris, James, “A View of the Royal Navy,” Encounter XL (03 1973): 20.Google Scholar

38 Semmel, Bernard, Imperialism and Social Reform: English Social-Imperial Thought 1895–1914 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1960).Google Scholar

39 Cameron, op. cit., and Caron, François, “French Railroad Investment, 1850–1914,” in Essays in French Economic History, Cameron, Rondo, editor (Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, 1970), pp. 315340.Google Scholar

40 On this coalition between industrialists and Junkers, see Gerschenkron, Alexander, Bread and Democracy in Germany (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1943)Google Scholar; also Berghahn, V. R., Germany and the Approach of War in 1914 (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1973).Google Scholar

41 Moll, op. cit., The classic analysis of the political economy of German naval procurement is Eckart Kehr, Battleship Building and Party Politics in Germany 1894–1901 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975). (Kehr's book was originally published in Germany in 1930.) Also see Berghahn, op. cit.Google Scholar

42 Henderson, W. O., The Rise of German Industrial Power, 1834–1914 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975).Google Scholar

43 Webster, R. A., Industrial Imperialism in Italy, 1908–1915 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975).Google Scholar

44 The politics of the German steel industry during the 1920s are discussed in Feldman, Gerald D., Iron and Steel in the German Inflation, 1916–1923 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977)Google Scholar; Maier, Charles S., Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade After World War I (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975)Google Scholar; and Abraham, David, Inter-Class Conflict and the Formation of Ruling Class Consensus in Late Weimar Germany (Doctoral dissertation submitted to the Department of History, University of Chicago, 12 1977).Google Scholar

45 On I. G. Farben, see Howard, Frank A., Buna Rubber: The Birth of an Industry (New York: D. Van Nostrand, 1947)Google Scholar; and Borkin, Joseph, The Crime and Punishment of I. G. Farben (New York: The Free Press, 1978), an informative and perceptive industrial history, which goes beyond the connotations of its title.Google Scholar

46 The politics of the German chemical and electrical industries during the 1920s are discussed by Maier, op. cit., and Abraham, op. cit.

47 Howard, op. cit.; Borkin, op. cit., chapter 2.

48 Abraham, op. cit., presents a thorough and sophisticated demonstration of this argument.

49 Borkin, op. cit., chapter 3.

50 Abraham, op. cit.; Borkin, op. cit., chapter 3. On the industrial role in the 1932 elections, also see Bullock, Alan, Hitler: A Study in Tyranny, revised edition (New York: Harper and Row, 1964)Google Scholar. An earlier, classic account of the relations between industry and the Nazis is Franz Neu mann, Behemoth: The Structure and Process of National Socialism (New York: Oxford University Press, 1942).Google Scholar

51 Sarti, Roland, Fascism and the Industrial Leadership in Italy, 1919–1940 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1971).Google Scholar

52 Winch, Donald, Economics and Politics: A Historical Study (London: Hodder and Stoughton, 1969).Google Scholar

53 Shay, Robert Paul Jr., British Rearmament in the Thirties: Politics and Profits (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977).Google Scholar

54 On the early developments of the automobile industry in the United States, see Flink, James J., The Car Culture (Cambridge, Massachusetts: The M.I.T. Press, 1975).Google Scholar

55 Useful accounts of the causes of the Great Depression of 1929–1939 are given in Aldcroft, Derek H., From Versailles to Wall Street, 1919–1929 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1977)Google Scholar; and Kindleberger, Charles P., The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973).Google Scholar

56 The phrase is from Emma Rothschild, Paradise Lost: The Decline of the Auto-Industrial Age (New York: Random House, 1973).Google Scholar

57 Rostow, W. W., Politics and the Stages of Growth (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1971), pp. 227229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

58 European economic policies in the 1950s and 1960s are discussed by Shonfield, Andrew, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (New York: Oxford University Press, 1969).Google Scholar

59 Bacha, Edmar L., “Issues and Evidence on Recent Brazilian Economic Growth” (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard Institute for International Development, Development Discussion Papers, 1976).Google Scholar

60 Quoted in Gall, Norman, “The Rise of Brazil,” Commentary 63 (01 1977): 4950.Google Scholar

61 I have discussed the American aerospace industry in a number of places, including my “Aerospace Production Lines and American Defense Spending,” in American Defense Policy, Head, Richard G. and Rokke, Ervin J., editors, third edition (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1973), pp. 626640Google Scholar; “Why We Buy the Weapons We Do,” Foreign Policy 2 (Summer 1973): 3356Google Scholar; and statement and testimony on American defense production in Defense Industrial Base: DOD Procurement Practices, Hearings before the Joint Committee on Defense Production, Congress of the United States, 95th Congress (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977), pp. 6390.Google Scholar

62 On the issue of innovation and regulation, see Competition in the Telecommunications Industry, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Communications of the Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, House of Representatives, 94th Congress (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977).Google Scholar

63 On the implications of these new military technologies, see Digby, James, Precision-Guided Weapons, Adelphi Papers, no. 118 (London: The International Institute for Strategic Studies, Summer 1975)Google Scholar; and Burt, Richard, New Weapons Technologies: Debate and Directions, Adelphi Papers, no. 126 (London: The International Institute for Strategic Studies, Summer 1976).Google Scholar