Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-7qhmt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T02:36:50.379Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Contracting around International Uncertainty

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 October 2005

BARBARA KOREMENOS
Affiliation:
University of Michigan

Abstract

International cooperation is plagued by uncertainty. Although states negotiate the best agreements possible using available information, unpredictable things happen after agreements are signed that are beyond states' control. States may not even commit themselves to an agreement if they anticipate that circumstances will alter their expected benefits. Duration provisions can insure states in this context. Specifically, the use of finite duration depends positively on the degree of uncertainty and states' relative risk aversion and negatively on the cost. These formally derived hypotheses strongly survive a test with data on a random sample of agreements across all four of the major issue areas in international relations. Not only do the results, highlighting evidence on multiple kinds of flexibility provisions, strongly suggest that the design of international agreements is systematic and sophisticated; but also they call attention to common ground among various subfields of political science and law.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2005 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbott Kenneth W., and Duncan Snidal. 2000. “Hard and Soft Law in International Governance.” International Organization 54 (Summer): 42156.Google Scholar
Barnett Michael N., and Marthega Finnemore. 1999. “The Politics, Power, and Pathologies of International Organizations.” International Organization 53 (Autumn): 699723.Google Scholar
Bennett D. Scott, and Allan Stam. 2000a. “EUGene: A Conceptual Manual.” International Interactions 26, 179204.Google Scholar
Bennett D. Scott, and Allan C. Stam. 2000b. “A Universal Test of an Expected Utility Theory of War.” International Studies Quarterly 44 (September): 45180.Google Scholar
Bordo Michael, and Finn Kydland. 1995. “The Gold Standard as a Rule: An Essay in Exploration.” Explorations in Economic History 32 (October): 42364.Google Scholar
Brown Michael E., ed. 2000. Rational Choice and Security Studies: Stephen Walt and His Critics. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Bueno de Mesquita Bruce. 1985. “The War Trap Revisited: A Revised Expected Utility Model.” American Political Science Review 79 (March): 15677.Google Scholar
Conybeare John. 1985. “Trade Wars: A Comparative Study of Anglo-Hanse, Franco-Italian, and Hawley-Smoot Conflicts.” World Politics 38 (October): 14772.Google Scholar
Dixon William J. 1994. “Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict.” The American Political Science Review 88 (March): 1432.Google Scholar
Downs George, and David Rocke. 1995. Optimal Imperfection?: Domestic Uncertainty and Institutions in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Duffield John. 2003. “The Limits of ‘Rational Design.’International Organization 57 (Spring): 41130.Google Scholar
Dye Ronald A. 1985. “Optimal Length of Labor Contracts.” International Economic Review 26 (February): 23350.Google Scholar
Finnemore Martha. 1996. National Interests in International Society. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Gartzke Erik, and Dong-Joon Jo. 2002. “The Affinity of Nations Index, 1946–1996.” Version 3.0. http://www.columbia.edu/~eg589/datasets.html.), November 8, 2002.Google Scholar
Glaser Charles. 1994. “Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self Help.” International Security 19 (Winter): 5090.Google Scholar
Gray Jo Anna. 1978. “On Indexation and Contract Length.” Journal of Political Economy 86 (February): 118.Google Scholar
Guzman Andrew, and Beth A. Simmons. 2002. “Litigation and Settlement.” Journal of Legal Studies 31: S205S235.Google Scholar
Harris Milton, and Bengt Holmstrom. 1987. “On the Duration of Agreements.” International Economic Review 26 (June): 389406.Google Scholar
Keck Margaret E., and Kathryn Sikkink. 1998. Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Koremenos Barbara. 2000. “Bending but Not Breaking: Flexibility in International Financial and Monetary Agreements.” Working Paper 1.73. University of California, Berkeley: Center for German and European Studies.
Koremenos Barbara. 2001. “Loosening the Ties that Bind: A Learning Model of Agreement Flexibility.” International Organization 55 (Spring): 289325.Google Scholar
Koremenos Barbara. 2005. “Bringing More ‘Precision’ to the Three Dimensions of Legalization.” Paper presented at the European University Institute, Fiesole, Italy.
Koremenos Barbara. N.d. “If Only Half of International Agreements Have Dispute Resolution Provisions, Which Half Needs Explaining?Journal of Legal Studies. Forthcoming.
Koremenos Barbara, Charles Lipson, and Duncan Snidal. 2001. “Rational Design: Looking Back to Move Forward.” International Organization 55 (Autumn): 105182.Google Scholar
Kreps David M. 1990. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Levy Jack S. 1988. “When do Deterrent Threats Work?British Journal of Political Science 18 (October): 485512.Google Scholar
Martin Lisa L. 1992. Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Martin Lisa L. 2000. Democratic Commitments: Legislatures and International Cooperation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Morrow James D. 1987. “On the Theoretical Basis of a Measure of National Risk Attitudes.” International Studies Quarterly 31 (December): 42338.Google Scholar
Oneal John R., and Bruce M. Russett. 1997. “The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950–1985.” International Studies Quarterly 41 (June): 26793.Google Scholar
O'Neill Barry. 2001. “Risk Aversion in International Relations Theory.” International Studies Quarterly 45 (December): 61740.Google Scholar
Osborne Martin J., and Ariel Rubinstein. 1990. Bargaining and Markets. Boston: Academic Press.
Rosendorff Peter, and Helen Milner. 2001. “The Optimal Design of International Trade Institutions: The Sources and Impact of Escape Clauses.” In The Rational Design of International Institutions, ed. Barbara Koremenos, Charles Lipson, and Duncan Snidal. International Organization. Special Issue 55 (Autumn): 82957
Signorino Curtis, and Jeffrey Ritter. 1999. “Tau-b or Not Tau-b: Measuring the Similarity of Foreign Policy Positions.” International Studies Quarterly 43 (March): 11544.Google Scholar
Simmons Beth A. 2000. “International Law and State Behavior. Compliance with the Public International Law of Money.” American Political Science Review, 94 (4): 81935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith Alastair. 1996. “Diversionary Foreign Policy in Democratic Systems.” International Studies Quarterly 40 (March): 13353.Google Scholar
Smith Alastair. 1998. “International Crises and Domestic Politics.” American Political Science Review 92 (September): 62338.Google Scholar
Tomz Michael, Jason Wittenberg, and Gary King. 2001. “Clarify: Software for Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results.” http://gking.harvard.edu/clarify (April 23, 2003).Google Scholar
Vreeland James Raymond. 2003. “A Continuous Schumpeterian Conception of Democracy.” Working Paper, Yale University, New Haven, CT.