Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T12:20:01.140Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Preserving Slave Families for Profit: Traders' Incentives and Pricing in the New Orleans Slave Market

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2009

Charles W. Calomiris*
Affiliation:
Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial Institutions, Columbia Business School, Columbia University, 3022 Broadway, Uris Hall 601, New York, NY 10027. E-mail: cc374@columbia.edu.
Jonathan B. Pritchett*
Affiliation:
Associate Professor, Department of Economics, 206 Tilton Hall, Tulane University, New Orleans, LA 70118. E-mail: jprit@tulane.edu.

Abstract

We investigate determinants of slave family discounts in the New Orleans slave market. We find large price discounts for families unrelated to scale effects, childcare costs, legal restrictions, or transport costs. We posit that because family members voluntarily cared for each other, sellers sometimes found it advantageous to keep families together (when families included needy or dependent members). Evidence from ship manifests carrying slaves for sale in New Orleans provides direct evidence for selectivity bias in explaining slave family discounts. Children likely to have been shipped with their mothers are 1 to 2 inches shorter than other children.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Advertiser [New Orleans], 23 September 1830.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. and William, R. AllenExchange and Production: Theory in Use. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing 1969Google Scholar
Choo, Eugene and Jean, Eid“Interregional Price Difference in the New Orleans Auctions Market for Slaves.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 26 no. 4 (2008) 486–509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Courier [New Orleans], 24 September 1830.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. and Stanley, EngermanTime on the Cross: Evidence and Methods. Boston: Little, Brown and Company 1974.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. and Stanley, EngermanTime on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery. Boston: Little, Brown and Company 1974.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. and Stanley, Engerman. “The New Orleans Slave Sale Sample, 1804-1862 [Computer File].” ICPSR Study No. 7423. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 1976.Google Scholar
Fogel, Robert W. and Stanley, Engerman“Some Notes on the Apparent Aversion to the Separate Sale of Children Under Age Ten in the New Orleans Slave Market.” In Without Consent or Contract: Evidence and Methods, edited by Robert, W. FogelRalph, A. Galatine and Richard, L. Manning256–59New York: W. W. Norton 1992.Google Scholar
Freudenberger, Herman and Jonathan, B. Pritchett“The Domestic United States Slave Trade, New Evidence.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 21 no. 3 (1991) 447–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, William H.Econometric Analysis. Englewild Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall 1993.Google Scholar
Greenwald, Bruce and Robert, Glasspiegel“Adverse Selection in the Market for Slaves: New Orleans, 1830-1860.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 no. 3 (1983) 479–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klebaner, Benjamin J.“American Manumission Laws and the Responsibility for Supporting Slaves.” Virginia Magazine of History and Biography 63 no. 4 (1955) 443–53.Google Scholar
Kotlikoff, Laurence.“The Structure of Slave Prices in New Orleans, 1804 to 1862.” Economic Inquiry 17 no. 4 (1979) 496–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotlikoff, Laurence.“Quantitative Description of the New Orleans Slave Market, 1804 to 1862.” In Without Consent or Contract: Markets and Production, Technical Papers, Vol. 1, edited by Robert, W. Fogel and Stanley, L. Engerman31–53New York: W. W. Norton 1992Google Scholar
Louisiana. Acts Passed at the First Session of the First Legislature of the Territory of Orleans. New Orleans: Bradford & Anderson 1806.Google Scholar
Margo, Robert A., and Richard, H. Steckel“The Heights of American Slaves: New Evidence on Slave Nutrition and Health.” Social Science History 6 no. 4 (1982) 515–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
New Orleans Notarial Archives. New Orleans, LA.Google Scholar
Phillips, Ulrich B.Life and Labor in the Old South. Boston: Little, Brown and Company 1929.Google Scholar
Pritchett, Jonathan B.“The Interregional Slave Trade and the Selection of Slaves for the New Orleans Market.” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 28 no. 3 (1997) 57–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pritchett, Jonathan B., and Richard, M. Chamberlain“Selection in the Market for Slaves: New Orleans, 1830-1860.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 no. 2 (1993) 461–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pritchett, Jonathan B. and Herman, Freudenberger“A Peculiar Sample: The Selection of Slaves for the New Orleans Market.” This JOURNAL 52 no. 1 (1992) 109–27.Google Scholar
Savitt, Todd L.Medicine and Slavery: The Diseases and Health Care of Blacks in Antebellum Virginia. Urbana: University of Illinois Press 1978Google Scholar
Schafer, Judith Kelleher.Slavery, the Civil Law, and the Supreme Court of Louisiana. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press 1994Google Scholar
Schafer, Judith Kelleher.Becoming Free, Remaining Free: Manumission and Enslavement in New Orleans, 1846-1862. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press 2003Google Scholar
Sweig, Donald M.“Reassessing the Human Dimension of the Interstate Slave Trade.” Prologue 12 no. 1 (1980) 4–19.Google Scholar
Tadman, Michael.Speculators and Slaves: Masters, Traders, and Slave in the Old South. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press 1989Google Scholar