Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c47g7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T15:11:49.975Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - From Property Rights to Markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2014

Terry L. Anderson
Affiliation:
Property and Environment Research Center
Gary D. Libecap
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Barbara
Get access

Summary

Whether property rights evolve from the bottom up or are assigned directly by government, they can provide important benefits by supporting environmental markets. Chapters 3 and 4 provided examples of the evolution of informal property rights and their role in providing environmental quality. In this chapter we turn to cases where environmental markets are based on formal property rights codified through a political and legal process. The examples are water rights, conservation credits, emission allowances, and tradable fishery shares. The details illustrate how environmental markets work and the nature of the property rights underwriting them.

In all of the cases, the rights are not based on fee simple titles but instead are use privileges. This distinction is important because privileges are just that, use opportunities that can be modified, reassigned, or revoked more easily by political or judicial action than is the case with formal title. Political action occurs through Congress and regulatory agencies, and judicial review through the courts. Use privileges have no constitutional takings protections, and monetary losses from government interventions are not compensable. Although use privileges give regulatory agencies greater flexibility, they are more uncertain and can have shorter time horizons and weaker incentives for investing in or reallocating the environmental resource than can more secure formal rights. When property rights are vague, environmental markets are weakened, and more environmental benefits must come from command-and-control regulation and tax policies. We examined the problems with those approaches in Chapters 2 and 3. A major lesson of this chapter is that property rights must be protected from regulatory takings if we are to harness markets to improve environmental quality. We provide examples of successful markets, some emerging ones, and some that have been weakened by political and bureaucratic intervention. This range of experiences reveals what is possible, what more remains, and what dangers can arise. We begin with two successful instances regarding water.

Type
Chapter
Information
Environmental Markets
A Property Rights Approach
, pp. 134 - 172
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2014

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Scarborough, Brandon and Lund, Hertha L. (2007), Saving Our Streams: Harnessing Water Markets. Bozeman: PERCGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Terry L. and Scarborough, Brandon (2011),“Oregon Water Trust: Saving Our Streams through Markets,” Bozeman: PERC
King, Mary Ann (2004), “Getting Our Feet Wet: An Introduction to Water Trusts,” Harvard Environmental Law Review 28: 495–434Google Scholar
Neuman, Janet C. (2005), “The Good, the Bad, and The Ugly: The First Ten Years of the Oregon Water Trust,” Nebraska Law Review 83(2): 432–484Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. (2011), “Institutional Path Dependence in Climate Adaptation: Coman's ‘Some Unsettled Problems of Irrigation,’” American Economic Review 101 (February): 64–80, 69–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howe, Charles W. and Goemans, Christopher (2003), “Water Transfers and their Impacts: Lessons from Three Colorado Water Markets,” Journal of the American Water Resources Association October: 1055–1065, 1056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyler, Daniel (1992), The Last Water Hole in the West: The Colorado-Big Thompson Project and the Northern Colorado Conservancy District, Boulder: University of Colorado PressGoogle Scholar
Howe, Charles W., Schurmeier, Dennis R., and Shaw, Jr W. Douglas. (1986), “Innovative Approaches to Water Allocation: The Potential for Water Markets,” Water Resources Research, 22(4): 439–445, 443CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, Janis M. and Sunding, David L. (2001), “Emerging Markets in Water: A Comparative Analysis of the Central Valley and Colorado-Big Thompson Projects,” Natural Resources Journal 41 (Spring): 283–328, 305Google Scholar
Brewer, Jedidiah R., Glennon, Robert, Ker, Alan, and Libecap, Gary D. (2008), “Water Markets in the West: Prices, Trading, and Contractual Flows,” Economic Inquiry 46(2): 91–112, 99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scarlett, Lynn and Boyd, James (2011), Ecosystem Services: Quantification, Policy Applications, and Current Federal Capabilities, Discussion Paper RFF DP 11–12, Washington D.C.: Resources for the FutureGoogle Scholar
Madsen, Becca, Carroll, Nathaniel, Kandy, Daniel, and Bennett, Genevieve (2011), 2011 Update: State of Biodiversity Markets, Washington, D.C.: Forest Trends, 5Google Scholar
Boyd, James and Wainger, Lisa (2003), Measuring Ecosystem Service Benefits: The Use of Landscape Analysis to Evaluate Environmental Trades and Compensation, Discussion Paper 01–63, Washington D.C.: Resources for the Future, provide examples of wetlands mitigation projects and valuation techniques
Farrow, R. Scott, Schultz, Martin T., Celikkol, Pinar, and Van Houtven, George L. (2005), “Pollution Trading in Water Quality Limited Areas: Use of Benefits Assessment and Cost-Effective Trading Ratios,” Land Economics 81(2): 191–205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher-Vanden, Karen and Olmstead, Sheila (2013), “Moving Pollution Trading from Air to Water: Potential, Problems, and Prognosis,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(1): 147–172, 149, 164–166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernandez, Linda and Karp, Larry (1998), “Restoring Wetlands through Wetlands Mitigation Banks,” Environmental and Resource Economics 12: 323–344CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonds, Matthew H. and Pompe, Jeffrey J. (2003), “Calculating Wetland Mitigation Banking Credits: Adjusting for Wetland Function and Location,” Natural Resources Journal 43: 961–977Google Scholar
Ribaudo, Marc, Johansson, Robert, and Jones, Carol (2006), “Environmental Credit Trading: Can Farming Benefit,” Amber Waves 4(1)Google Scholar
Fox, Jessica and Nino-Murcia, Anamaria (2005), “Status of Species Conservation Banking in the United States,” Conservation Biology 19(4): 996–1007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McConnell, Virginia and Walls, Margaret (2009), “U.S. Experience with Transferable Development Rights,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 3(2): 288–303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walls, Margaret and McConnell, Virginia (2007), Transfer of Development Rights in U.S. Communities: Evaluating Program Design, Implementation, and Outcomes, Washington D.C.: Resources for the FutureGoogle Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D. (1966), “The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems,” in Wolozin, H., ed., The Economics of Air Pollution, New York: W.W. Norton, 61–68Google Scholar
Dales, J.H. (1968), Property and Prices, Toronto: University of Toronto PressGoogle Scholar
Tietenberg, Tom (2007), “Tradable Permits in Principle and Practice,” in Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., eds., Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience, New York: Oxford University Press, 63–94, 78Google Scholar
Gangadharan, Lata (2000), “Transaction Costs in Pollution Markets: An Empirical Study,” Land Economics 76(44): 601–614CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egelston, Anne and Cohen, Maurie J. (2004): California RECLAIM's Market Failure: Lessons for the Kyoto Protocol, Climate Policy 4:4, 427–444CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fowlie, Meredith, Holland, Stephen P., and Mansur, Erin T. (2011), “What Do Emissions Markets Deliver and to Whom? Evidence from Southern California's NOx Trading Program,” Working Paper, March 28
Goulder, Lawrence H. (2013), “Markets for Pollution Allowances: What Are the (New) Lessons?Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(1): 87–102CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellerman, Denny (2007), “Are Cap-and-Trade Programs More Environmentally Effective than Conventional Regulation?” in Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., eds., Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience, New York: Oxford University Press, 48–62, 56–58Google Scholar
Fraas, Arthur G. and Richardson, Nathan (2010), “Banking on Allowances: The EPA's Mixed Record in Managing Emissions-Market Transitions,” Discussion Paper 10–42, Washington D.C.: Resources for the Future
Dewees, Donald N. (1998), “Tradable Pollution Permits,” in Newman, Peter, ed., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, Vol. 3, London: MacMillan, 596–601, 597–598Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. and Schmalensee, Richard (1998), “The Political Economy of Market-Based Environmental Policy: The U.S. Acid Raid Program,” The Journal of Law and Economics 41(1): 37–83, 43–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stavins, Robert N. (2007), “Market-Based Environmental Policies: What Can We Learn from U.S. Experience (and Related Research)?” in Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., eds., Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation, New York: Oxford University Press, 19–47, 23Google Scholar
Schmalensee, Richard and Stavins, Robert N. (2013), “The SO2 Allowance Trading System: The Ironic History of a Grand Policy Experiment,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(1): 103–122, 104–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burtraw, Dallas and Szambelan, Sarah Jo (2009), “U.S. Emissions Trading Markets for SO2 and NOx,” Discussion Paper 09–04Washington D.C.: Resources for the Future, October, 6Google Scholar
Ellerman, A. Denny, Joskow, Paul L., Schmalensee, Richard, Montero, Juan-Pablo, and Bailey, Elizabeth M. (2000), Markets for Clean Air: The US Acid Rain Program, New York: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tietenberg, Tom H. (2006), Emissions Trading Principles and Practice, 2nd Ed., Washington D.C.: Resources for the FutureGoogle Scholar
Keohane, Nathaniel O. and Olmstead, Sheila M. (2007), Markets and the Environment, Washington D.C.: Island Press, 183–190Google Scholar
Peters, Mark (2010), “Changes Choke Cap-and-Trade Market,” Wall Street Journal July 12, at
Wald, Matthew L., “Court Blocks E.P.A. Rule on Cross-State Pollution,” New York Times August 22, 2012Google Scholar
Tracy, Ryan, “Court Voids Rule on Coal Pollution,” Wall Street Journal August 21, 2012
Kiefer, Kati (2010), “A Missing Market: The Future of Interstate Emissions Trading Programs after North Carolina v. EPA,” Saint Louis University Law Journal 54: 635–674Google Scholar
Matthiasson, Thorolfur and Agnarsson, Sveinn (2010), “Property Rights in Icelandic Fisheries,” in Grafton, R. Quentin, Hilborn, Ray, Squires, Dale, Tait, Maree, and Williams, Meryl J., eds., Handbook of Marine Fisheries Conservation and Management, New York: Oxford University Press, 299–309Google Scholar
Connor, Robin and Shallard, Bruce (2010), “Evolving Governance in New Zealand Fisheries,” in R. Quentin Grafton, et al. eds. (2010), 347–359
Myers, Ransom A. and Worm, Boris, (2003), “Rapid Worldwide Depletion of Predatory Fish Communities,” Nature 423: 280–283CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Devine, Jennifer A., Baker, Krista D., and Haedrich, Richard L., (2006), “Fisheries: Deep-Sea Fishes Qualify as Endangered,” Nature 439: 29CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grainger, Corbett and Costello, Christopher (2011), “The Value of Secure Property Rights: Evidence from Global Fisheries,” NBER Working Paper 17019, Cambridge: NBER, where they examine the impact of insecure fishery quota rights on quota values across countries
Fina, Mark and Kade, Tyson (2012), “Legal and Policy Implications of the Perception of Property Rights in Catch Shares,” Washington Journal of Environmental Law and Policy 2: 283–328Google Scholar
Singh, Rajesh, Weninger, Quinn, and Doyle, Matthew, (2006), “Fisheries Management with Stock Growth Uncertainty and Costly Capital Adjustment,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 52(2): 582–599; 595CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann, Mark and Criddle, Keith (2006), “An Econometric Market Model for the Pacific Halibut Fishery,” Marine Resource Economics 21: 129–158CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×