We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Declining labor force participation of older men throughout the 20th century and recent increases in participation have generated substantial interest in understanding the effect of public pensions on retirement. The National Bureau of Economic Research's International Social Security (ISS) Project, a long-term collaboration among researchers in a dozen developed countries, has explored this and related questions. The project employs a harmonized approach to conduct within-country analyses that are combined for meaningful cross-country comparisons. The key lesson is that the choices of policy makers affect the incentive to work at older ages and these incentives have important effects on retirement behavior.
There is emerging evidence that glutamatergic system dysfunction might play an important role in the pathophysiology of bipolar depression. This review focuses on the use of glutamate receptor modulators for depression in bipolar disorder.
A key question for any researcher is what to work on. Integral to answering is the method of search for an idea that might become a good paper. This is particularly an issue for many students starting on their theses, particularly after a period without a successful start. When I talk with these students, I spell out multiple ways of getting started that I have used, rather than presenting a dry, abstract list of approaches. Generally, students coming to me are trying to write theory papers, and it is my experience with getting started on theory papers that I relate in this essay.
A key part of that strategic process, and also of the tactics of completing and presenting papers, is trying to figure out how interesting an actual result or a conjectured result might be. My movements across different research areas and between basic applied theory and policy analyses have taught me the ongoing importance of strategic planning. This essay reports my memory of how I have proceeded strategically over the past fifty years, both before and after recognizing a need to think directly about these choices. Over time I have become aware of the diversity of research approaches that work at different times and for different people and the uneven quality of advice I have given on this issue. So this is one researcher’s story, not one researcher’s advice, a potted history from my memory of early conscious and not conscious choices.
In these two lectures, first published in 1994, Peter Diamond explores how time is modelled in theoretical analyses of individual industries and of an entire economy. In the first lecture he considers equilibrium in a single market by examining the distinction between the short run and the long run in Marshallian analysis. He proposes an explicit modelling of time in place of Marshall's use of different atemporal models for different time frames. In the second lecture he turns to models of an entire economy, and begins by considering how and why models of an entire economy should differ from models of a single industry. Both cyclical and seasonal data on the behaviour of macro-economies are examined.
This paper explores the pathways of the determinants of unfavourable birth outcomes, such as premature birth, the size of the baby at birth, and Caesarean section deliveries, in Kenya using graphical log-linear chain models. The results show that a number of factors that do not have direct associations with unfavourable birth outcomes contribute to these outcomes indirectly through intermediate factors. Marital status, the desirability of a pregnancy, the use of family planning and access to health facilities have no direct associations with poor birth outcomes, such as premature births and the small size of the baby at birth, but are linked to these outcomes through antenatal care. Antenatal care is identified as a central link between various sociodemographic or reproductive factors and birth outcomes.
Our observations of H2O masers have detected some high-velocity features and a secular velocity drift of the systemic features in the Seyfert 2 Galaxy IC 2560. The high-velocity features were blue- and red-shifted from the systemic velocity of 220-420 km s−1 and 210-350 km s−1, respectively. The velocity of the systemic features drifted at a secular rate of 2.62 km s−1 yr−1. Assuming the existence of a compact rotating disk as in NGC 4258, IC 2560 possesses a nuclear disk with inner and outer radii of 0.07 pc and 0.26 pc, respectively, and a confined mass of 2.8 × 106M⊙ at the center, making the central density > 2.1 × 109M⊙ pc−3. Such a dense object cannot be a cluster of stars, and this strongly suggests that the central mass is a super-massive black hole. Since the 2-10 keV luminosity of IC 2560 is 1 × 1041 erg s−1, the mass accretion rate of the suggested black hole must be 2 × 10−5M⊙ yr−1.
ABSTRACT. The term money illusion refers to a tendency to think in terms of nominal rather than real monetary values. Money illusion has significant implications for economic theory, yet it implies a lack of rationality that is alien to economists. This paper reviews survey questions, which are designed to shed light on the psychology that underlies money illusion, regarding people's reactions to variations in inflation and prices. We propose that people often think about economic transactions in both nominal and real terms and that money illusion arises from an interaction between these representations, which results in a bias towards a nominal evaluation.
“A nickel ain't worth a dime anymore.”
Yogi Berra
We have standardized every other unit in commerce except the most important and universal unit of all, the unit of purchasing power. What business man would consent for a moment to make a contract in terms of yards of cloth or tons of coal, and leave the size of the yard or the ton to chance? … We have standardized even our new units of electricity, the ohm, the kilowatt, the ampere, and the volt. But the dollar is still left to the chances of gold mining.
Irving Fisher, 1913
The term money illusion refers to a tendency to be influenced by nominal as well as real monetary values in one's thinking about, and the conduct of, economic transactions. Money illusion has significant implications for economic theory, yet it implies a lack of rationality that is alien to economists.
It is an honor to have this opportunity to pay tribute to such a widely respected scholar. Nancy Schwartz was an excellent theorist. She wrote papers that developed models of real world phenomena. Thus it is fitting that I draw on my experience in social insurance as both a theorist and a policy analyst to discuss a topic where theory has been important in informing policy discussion and policy discussions have shaped issues for theoretical analysis. I will use the provision of retirement income as the social insurance issue to be discussed.
Two analytical characteristics particularly distinguish the writings of economists. One is the primary focus on the self as motivation for behavior, with the use of utility maximizing models as the analytical device for modeling this focus. The second is the use of equilibrium constructs to determine the outcomes that follow from individual choices. Analysts of social insurance generally recognize that a critical part of the case for having social insurance is the failure of individuals to adequately look ahead and provide for their own retirements. Thus social insurance analysis is one place where the rationality assumptions of economists are not given as full a reign as in most other areas of economic analysis.
I have been researching the inadequacies of conventional approaches to the modeling of time since 1968. My dissatisfaction with treatments of tatonnement stability led me to think about price adjustments in real time, with individuals aware that they are partaking in a process in real time. This approach to modeling equilibrium resulted first in my 1971 analysis of search equilibrium in a single market. Reading Mortensen (1978) made me realize the power of Poisson processes for developing tractable models of real time activities and moved my concern for real time allocation processes into a more productive phase. These lectures represent an attempt to express the image of the workings of an economy that lies behind much of my research. Being invited to give these lectures pushed me into a reflection on modeling that would not have occurred otherwise.
The book is divided into two lectures; each lecture is divided into two chapters. In the lecture about individual industries, I begin by considering explicit modeling of time in a competitive setting where investment and production are the only decisions by firms; the Walrasian auctioneer handles prices. The thrust of the lecture is how atemporal modeling is (and must be) informed by explicittime thinking and modeling. This is illustrated by a model with uncertainty about the production costs of individual firms and is argued by consideration of data on gross and net employment flows. The second chapter moves beyond this structure by recognizing price setting as a control variable of individual suppliers, dropping the fiction of the Walrasian auctioneer.