Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-10-30T13:07:50.945Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Cigarettes, dollars and bitcoins – an essay on the ontology of money

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 October 2015

J. P. SMIT*
Affiliation:
Department of Philosophy, University of Stellenbosch, Stellenbosch, South Africa
FILIP BUEKENS*
Affiliation:
Hoger Instituut voor Wijsbegerte, KU Leuven, Leuven, BelgiumInstitute for Logic and Philosophy of Science, Tilburg University, Tilburg, Netherlands
STAN DU PLESSIS*
Affiliation:
Department of Philosophy, University of Stellenbosch, Stellenbosch, South Africa

Abstract

What does being money consist in? We argue that something is money if, and only if, it is typically acquired in order to realise the reduction in transaction costs that accrues in virtue of agents coordinating on acquiring the same thing when deciding what thing to acquire in order to exchange. What kinds of things can be money? We argue against the common view that a variety of things (notes, coins, gold, cigarettes, etc.) can be money. All monetary systems are best interpreted as implementing the same basic protocol. Money, i.e. the thing that we coordinate on acquiring in order to lower our transaction costs, is, in all cases, a set of positions on an abstract mathematical object, namely a relative ratio scale. The things that we ordinarily call ‘money’ are merely records of positions on such a scale.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Darby, D. (1996), ‘Review of “The Construction of Social Reality”’, Mind, 105 (420): 716719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furness, W. H. (1915), ‘The Island of Stone Money’, The Economic Journal, 25 (98): 281283.Google Scholar
Gintis, H. (2009), The Bounds of Reason, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Goldberg, D. (2005), ‘Famous Myths of “Fiat Money”’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37 (5): 957967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, K. (2013), ‘Federal Judge Rules Bitcoin is Real Money’, Forbes, available at: http://www.forbes.com/sites/kashmirhill/2013/08/07/federal-judge-rules-bitcoin-is-real-money/Google Scholar
Katz, M. L., and Shapiro, C. (1986), ‘Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility’, American Economic Review, 75 (3): 424440.Google Scholar
Kocherlakota, N. R. (2002), ‘What's the Question and Why Should we Care About the Answer?’, American Economic Review, 92 (2): 5861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, B., Ford, R., and Nowrasteh, A. (2008), ‘Somalia After State Collapse: Chaos or Improvement?’, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 67 (3–4): 657670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radford, R. A. (1945), ‘The Economic Organisation of a P.O.W. Camp’, Econometrica, 12 (48): 189201.Google Scholar
Scheck, J. (2008), ‘Mackerel Economics in Prison Leads to Appreciation for Oily Fillets’, The Wall Street Journal, available at: http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB122290720439096481Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. [1908] (1980), ‘Der MethodoIogische Individualismus. Chapter VI of Joseph A. Schumpeter (1908)’, English translation by von Notten, M. (ed.), Methodological Individualism, Brussels: Institutum Europaeum.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. (1995), The Construction of Social Reality, London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. (2005), ‘What is an Institution?’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 1 (1): 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searle, J. R. (2010), Making the Social World: The Structure of Human Civilisation, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smit, J. P., Buekens, F., and du Plessis, S. (2011), ‘What is Money? An Alternative to Searle's Institutional Facts’, Economics and Philosophy, 27 (1): 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smit, J. P., Buekens, F., and du Plessis, S. (2014), ‘Developing the Incentivized Action View of Institutional Reality’, Synthese, 191 (8): 18131830.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, B. (2008), ‘Searle and de Soto: The New Ontology of the Social World’, in Smith, B., Mark, D. and Ehrlich, I. (eds.), The Mystery of Capital and the Construction of Social Reality, Chicago: Open Court, pp. 3551.Google Scholar
Smith, B. (2014), ‘Document Acts’, in Konzelmann-Ziv, A. and Schmid, H. B. (eds.), Institutions, Emotions, and Group Agents. Contributions to Social Ontology, Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 1931.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, B. and Searle, J. R. (2003), ‘The Construction of Social Reality: An Exchange’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 62 (2): 285309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stevens, S. (1946), ‘On the Theory of Scales of Measurement’, Science, 103 (2684): 677680.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Storti, C. C. and De Grauw, P. (2002), Electronic Money and the Optimal Size of Monetary Unions, London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper No. 33.Google Scholar
Van Hove, L. (1999), ‘Electronic Money and the Network Externalities Theory: Lessons for Real Life’, Netnomics, 1 (2): 137171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, S. D. (1999), ‘Private money’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 31 (3): 469491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar