Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-01T18:01:41.225Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Are There Causal Relations Among Dependent Variables?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 April 2022

Daniel Hausman*
Affiliation:
Committee on the History and Philosophy of Science University of Maryland

Abstract

This paper makes explicit and takes issue with the bizarre view, which is unfortunately prevalent among social scientists, that causal relations are features of models only. There are some good reasons to represent causal factors with independent variables. But the association between causes and independent variables is only a desideratum in model construction. It is not a criterion for judging which things are causes and which are effects.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 1983 by the Philosophy of Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The research for this paper was generously supported by the National Science Foundation (Grant # SES 8007385). Douglas Ehring provided invaluable assistance in thinking through related problems concerning causal asymmetry. Raymond Martin, Martin Osborne, Herbert Simon and Paul Thagard made helpful criticisms. Susan Byers provided expert research assistance.

References

Ando, A. (1963), “Introduction” in Ando, A., Fisher, F. and Simon, H. (eds.), Essays on the Structure of Social Science Models. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press: 14.Google Scholar
Asher, H. (1976), Causal Modeling. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. (1964), “Markets with a Continuum of Traders”, Econometrica 32: 3950.10.2307/1913732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basmann, R. (1963), “The Causal Interpretation of Non-Triangular Systems of Economic Relations”, Econometrica 31: 439448.10.2307/1909983CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beauchamp, T. and Rosenberg, A. (1981), Hume and the Problem of Causation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bentzel, R. and Hansen, B. (1954–55), “On Recursiveness and Interdependency in Economic Models”, Review of Economic Studies 22: 153168.10.2307/2295873CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blalock, H. (1964), Causal Inferences in Non-Experimental Research. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Blalock, H. (1968), “Theory Building and Causal Inferences”, in H. Blalock and A. Blalock (eds.). Methodology in Social Research. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Blalock, H. (1971), Causal Models in the Social Sciences. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
Blalock, H. & Costner, H. (1972), “Scientific Fundamentalism and Scientific Utility: A Reply to Gibbs”, Social Science Quarterly 52: 827844.Google Scholar
Bliss, C. (1975), Capital Theory and the Distribution of Income. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Brand, M. (1976), The Nature of Causation (ed.). Urbana: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Bunge, M. (1959), Causality—the Place of the Causal Principle in Modern Science. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bunzl, M. (forthcoming), “A Causal Model for Causal Priority”, Synthese.Google Scholar
Cartwright, N. (1979), “Causal Laws and Effective Strategies”, Nous 13: 419437.10.2307/2215337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collingwood, R. (1940), An Essay on Metaphysics, pp. 285–327, rpt. in Brand (1976), pp. 167211.Google Scholar
Fisher, F. (1966), The Identification Problem in Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Fisher, F. (1969), “Causation and Specification in Economic Theory and Econometrics”, Synthese 20: 489500.10.1007/BF00869931CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garb, G. (1964), “The Problem of Causality in Economics”, Kyklos 17: 594611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardiner, M. (1979), “Realism and Instrumentalism in Nineteenth Century Atomism”, Philosophy of Science 46: 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gasking, D. (1955), “Causation and Recipes”, rpt. in Brand (1976), pp. 215223.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1979), “Methods in Economic Science”, Journal of Economic Issues 13: 317328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, L. (1967), “Theory in Anthropology: Developmental or Causal”, in L. Gross (1967), pp. 153180.Google Scholar
Granger, C. (1969), “Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods”, Econometrica 37: 424438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, L. (1967), Sociological Theory: Inquiries and Paradigms (ed.). New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. (1981), Capital, Profits and Prices. An Essay in the Philosophy of Economics. New York: Columbia University Press.10.7312/haus90554CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. (forthcoming a) “Causal Priority”, Nous.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. (forthcoming b) “Does the Wage Depend on the Marginal Productivity of Labor?Google Scholar
Hicks, J. (1979), Causality in Economics. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Hood, W. and Koopmans, T., eds. (1953), Studies in Econometric Method. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (1748), An Inquiry Concerning Human Understanding. rpt. New York: Bobbs-Merrill, 1955.Google Scholar
Jaffé, W. (1954), “Translator's Notes”, In L. Walras, Elements of Pure Economics. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Kaplan, A. (1965), “Noncausal Explanation”, in D. Lerner (1965), pp. 144155.Google Scholar
Koopmans, T. (1953), “Identification Problems in Economic Model Construction” in Hood and Koopmans (1953), pp. 2748.Google Scholar
Lerner, D. (1965), Cause and Effect (ed.). New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Mackie, J. (1974), The Cement of the Universe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Marschak, J. (1950), “Statistical Inference in Economics: An Introduction”, pp. 1–50 of T. Koopmans (ed.). Statistical Inference in Dynamic Economic Models. New York: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Marschak, J. (1953), “Econometric Measurements for Policy and Prediction”, in Hood and Koopmans (1953), pp. 126.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Miller, A. (1971), “Logic of Causal Analysis: from Experimental to Non-Experimental Design”, in Blalock (1971), pp. 273294.Google Scholar
Morgenbesser, S. (1969) “The Realist-Instrumentalist Controversy”, in S. Morgenbesser, P. Suppes and M. White (eds.). Philosophy, Science and Method. New York: St. Martin's: 200218.Google Scholar
Nagel, E. (1961), The Structure of Science. New York: Harcourt Brace & World.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orcutt, G. (1952), “Actions, Consequences and Causal Relations”, Review of Economics and Statistics 34: 305313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, D. (1956), Money, Interest and Prices. Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson & Co.Google Scholar
Puu, T. (1969), “Causal Versus Teleological Explanation in Economics”, Swedish Journal of Economics 71: 111126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quine, W. (1969), “Epistemology Naturalized”, in Ontological Relativity and Other Essays. New York: Columbia University Press: 6990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. (1965), “Causality and Teleology in Economics”, in D. Lerner (1965), pp. 99143.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1954), History of Economic Analysis (ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1953), “Causal Ordering and Identifiability”, rpt. in Simon (1977), pp. 5380.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1954), “Spurious Correlation: A Causal Interpretation”, rpt. in Simon (1977), pp. 93106.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (1955), “Causality and Econometrics: Comment”, Econometrica 23: 193195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. (1977), Models of Discovery and Other Topics in the Methods of Science. Dordrecht: D. Reidel.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strotz, R. (1960), “Interdependence as a Specification Error”, Econometrica 28: 428442.10.2307/1907732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strotz, R. and Wold, H. (1960), “Recursive vs. Non-Recursive Systems: An Attempt at Synthesis”, Econometrica 28: 417427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suppe, F. (1977), The Structure of Scientific Theories, 2nd ed. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Theodorson, G. (1967), “The Uses of Causation in Sociology”, in L. Gross (1967), pp. 131153.Google Scholar
van Fraassen, B. (1980), The Scientific Image. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/0198244274.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Wright, G. (1975), Causality and Determinism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1949), The Methodology of the Social Sciences. tr. and ed. E. Shils and H. Finch. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wold, H. (1954), “Causality and Econometrics”, Econometrica 22: 162177.10.2307/1907540CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wold, H. (1955), “Causality and Econometrics: Reply”, Econometrica 23: 196197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wold, H. (1960), “A Generalization of Causal Chain Models”, Econometrica 28: 443463.10.2307/1907733CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wold, H. (1969), “Mergers of Economics and Philosophy of Science”, Synthese 20: 427482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfson, R. (1970), “Points of View, Scientific Theories and Econometric Models”, Philosophy of Science 37: 249260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar