Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-2pzkn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-13T08:43:50.618Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

10 - The copper curse and forest degradation in Zambia

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2013

Pieter J. H. van Beukering
Affiliation:
Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam
Elissaios Papyrakis
Affiliation:
Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam
Jetske Bouma
Affiliation:
Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam
Roy Brouwer
Affiliation:
Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Amongst the most striking empirical relationships uncovered over the last ten to fifteen years has been the negative causal link between several measures of resource dependence and economic development. Resource-based economic development has not proven to be a great success amongst developing nations; as a matter of fact, poor nations deprived of minerals, fertile land and forests performed better compared to their resource-rich counterparts. Recent empirical evidence and theoretical work provide strong support to a resource curse hypothesis; i.e. natural wealth tends to retard rather than promote economic growth (Auty 1994, Gylfason 2000, 2001a,b, Leite and Weidmann 1999, Papyrakis and Gerlagh 2004, Rodriguez and Sachs 1999, Sachs and Warner 1995 1997, 1999a,b, 2001). The most prominent example is certainly the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) with a disappointing annual growth rate of –1.3% on average between 1965 and 1998 despite the significant injections of petrodollars into their local economies from the oil extractive industries (Gylfason 2001a). The expectations of many early development economists (Nurkse 1953, Rostow 1960, Watkins 1963) that resource endowments could potentially support economic expansion by attracting funds from foreign creditors, channelling the primary sector rents into productive investment and escaping ‘poverty traps’ proved to be unrealistic. Similarly, any positive linkages between resource abundance and economic prosperity observed during the origins of the industrial revolution in Great Britain, Germany and the United States or more recently in countries such as Botswana, Norway and Iceland appear to be exceptional cases rather than belonging to a general applicable rule (Sachs and Warner 1995, Wright 1990).

Type
Chapter
Information
Nature's Wealth
The Economics of Ecosystem Services and Poverty
, pp. 217 - 233
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Auty, R. M. (1994). Industrial policy reform in six large newly industrializing countries: the resource curse thesis. World Development, 22: 11–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J. –M. and Francois, P. (2000). Rent-seeking and resource booms. Journal of Development Economics, 61: 527–542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, E. L. (1974). Labour, Race, and Colonial Rule: The Copperbelt from 1924 to Independence. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Chidumayo, E. N. (1997). Management of Miombo Woodlands in Zambia Copperbelt. Ndola, Zambia: Provincial Forestry Action Programme.Google Scholar
Dzioubinski, O. and Chipman, R. (1999). Trends in consumption and production: selected minerals. DESA Discussion Paper No. 5, United Nations.Google Scholar
Elíasson, L. and Turnovsky, S. J. (2004). Renewable resources in an endogenously growing economy: balanced growth and transitional dynamics. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48: 1018–1049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FAO (2002). Zambia. Special Report, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Economic and Social Department, June 2002.
Gylfason, T. (2000). Resources, agriculture, and economic growth in economies in transition. Kyklos, 53: 545–580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gylfason, T. (2001a). Natural resources, education, and economic development. European Economic Review, 45: 847–859.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gylfason, T. (2001b). Nature, power and growth. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 48: 558–588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harvey, C. (1972). Tax reform in the mining industry. In Bostock, M. and Harvey, C. (eds.), Economic Independence and Zambian Copper: A Case Study of Foreign Investment. New York: Praeger Publishers.Google Scholar
IMF (2002). Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper: Zambia. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.
Kalumiana, M. (1997). Demand and Supply of Firewood and Charcoal, Copperbelt Province. Ndola, Zambia: Provincial Forestry Action Programme.Google Scholar
Leite, C. and Weidmann, J. (1999). Does Mother Nature corrupt? Natural resources, corruption and economic growth. IMF Working Paper No 99/85. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.CrossRef
Meebelo, H. S. (1971). Reaction to Colonialism: A Prelude to the Politics of Independence in Northern Zambia 1893–1939. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Navine, T. R. (1978). Copper Mining and Management. Tuscon, AZ: University of Arizona Press.Google Scholar
New York Times (2002). World briefing, Africa. Zambia: Too many eggs in copper basket. New York Times, 14 February.Google Scholar
Nurkse, R. (1953). Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Papyrakis, E. and Gerlagh, R. (2004). The resource curse hypothesis and its transmission channels. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32: 181–193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Republic of Zambia (1985). National Conservation Strategy. Lusaka, Zambia: Government Printer,.Google Scholar
Roberts, A. (1976). A History of Zambia. London: Africana Publishing.Google Scholar
Rodriguez, F. and Sachs, J. D. (1999). Why do resource-abundant economies grow more slowly?Journal of Economic Growth, 4: 277–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, M. L (2001). Extractive sectors and the poor. Oxfam America Report, Boston, MA.
Rostow, W. W. (1960). The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1995). Natural resource abundance and economic growth. NBER Working Paper No 5398. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.CrossRef
Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1997). Fundamental sources of long-run growth. American Economic Review, 87: 184–188.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1999a). The big push, natural resource booms and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 59: 43–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, J. D., and Warner, A. M. (1999b). Natural resource intensity and economic growth. In Mayer, J., Chambers, B. and Ayisha, F. (eds.), Development Policies in Natural Resource Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. D. and, Warner, A. M. (2001). Natural resources and economic development: the curse of natural resources. European Economic Review, 45: 827–838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sibande, S. (1996). Forest Resource Management. Lusaka, Zambia: Zambia Forestry Action Programme.Google Scholar
van Beukering, P. J. H., Cesar, H. S. J. and Janssen, M. A. (2003). Economic valuation of the Leuser National park on Sumatra, Indonesia. Ecological Economics, 44: 43–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watkins, M. H. (1963). A staple theory of economic growth. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29: 142–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, G. (1990). The origins of American industrial success, 1789–1940. American Economic Review, 80: 651–668.Google Scholar
Yakovleva, N. (2005). Corporate Social Responsibility in the Mining Industries. Hampshire, UK: Ashgate.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×