Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-25wd4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T16:57:52.764Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Imposition et Mobilisation du Surplus Agricole a l'Epoque Stalinienne

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 July 2017

Robert C. Allen*
Affiliation:
The University of British Columbia

Extract

Le développement de l'économie soviétique dans les années 1930 a été soutenu par un important essor de l'investissement. L'allocation des ressources au secteur des biens de production s'est soldée par des niveaux d'investissement de plus en plus élevés et par une croissance rapide de la production non agricole. Parallèlement à l'essor de l'investissement, la comptabilité nationale indique une hausse proportionnelle de l'épargne. Quelle est ainsi la source de cette épargne ? L'hypothèse la plus répandue en fait le produit de la « mobilisation » de l'excédent agricole grâce à la collectivisation et au système étatisé d'approvisionnement. Preobrazhensky (1926) est connu pour avoir suggéré que l'État finance ses investissements en achetant à bas prix leurs produits aux fermiers et en leur vendant cher les produits manufacturés.

Summary

Summary

Did the collectivization of agriculture contribute to Soviet capital formation by mobilizing the agricultural surplus? While many historians have supported this view, it has been challenged by revisionists who claim that there was never a net flow of commodities from agriculture to the rest of the economy and that agriculture's terms of trade actually improved during the First Five Year Plan since the inflation of prices on the collective farm market outweighed the effects of the low prices paid for state procurements. This paper proposes new calculations of agriculture's trade balance that show that it was, indeed, a net supplier of resources and that those resources financed the investment drive of the 1930s. A computable general equilibrium model is used to assess intersectoral linkages. These simulations show that rapid industrialization would have been possible without collectivization, but that collectivization did accelerate industrial growth by depressing peasant incomes and increasing the rate of rural urban migration. The key contribution of collectivization was the mobilization of labour surplus, not surplus grain.

Type
L'Historiographie Économique Américaine
Copyright
Copyright © Les Éditions de l’EHESS 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Références Bibliographiques

Allen, (Robert C ), 1997a, « Agricultural Marketing and the Possibilities for Industrialization in the Soviet Union in the 1930s », Explorations in Economic History, vol. 34, n° 4, oct. 1997, pp. 387410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, (Robert C), 1997b, « The Standard of Living in the Soviet Union, 1928-1940 », UBC Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 97-18.Google Scholar
Allen, (Robert C), 1997c, « A Multisector Simulation Model of Soviet Economic Development », UBC Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 97-19.Google Scholar
Allen, (Robert C), « Capital Accumulation, the Soft Budget Constraint, and Soviet Industrialization », European Review of Economic History, à paraître 1998.Google Scholar
(Paul), Baran, 1962, The Political Economy of Growth, New York, Monthly Review, Inc. Google Scholar
Barsov, (A. A.), «Sel'skoe hoziajstvo i istočniki socialističeskogo nakopleniia v gody pervoj piatiletki (1928-1933) », Istoriia SSSR, 1968, pp. 64-82.Google Scholar
Barsov, (A. A.), 1969, Balans stoimostnyh obmenov meždu gorodom i derevnej, Moscou, Nauka.Google Scholar
(Abram), Bergson, 1953, Soviet National Income and Product in 1937, New York, Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
(Abram), Bergson, 1961, The Real National Income of Soviet Russia since 1928, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chambers, (E. J.), Gordon, (D. F.), 1966, « Primary Products and Economic Growth: An Empirical Measurement », Journal of Political Economy, vol. 74, pp. 315332.Google Scholar
Chapman, (Janet G.), 1963, Real Wages in Soviet Russia since 1928, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Darity, (William A.), 1982, « A General Equilibrium Model of the Eighteenth-Century Atlantic Slave Trade: A Least-Likely Test for the Caribbean School », Research in Economic History, vol. 7, pp. 287326.Google Scholar
Davies, (R. W.), (Mark), Harrison, et Wheatcroft, (S. G.), 1994, The Economic Transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913-1945, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dixon, (Peter B.), Parmenter, (Brian R.), et Powell, (Alan A.), 1992, Notes and Problems in Applied General Equilibrium Economics, Amsterdam, North-Holland.Google Scholar
(Michael), Ellman, 1975, « Did the Agricultural Surplus Provide the Resources for the Increase in Investment in the USSR During the First Five Year Plan ? », Economic Journal, vol. 85, pp. 844863.Google Scholar
(Michael), Ellman, 1978, « On a Mistake of Preobrazhensky and Stalin », Journal of Development Studies, vol. 14, pp. 353356.Google Scholar
Erlich, (A.), 1960, The Soviet Industrialization Debate 1924-1928, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
(Ronald), Findlay, 1993, « The “Triangular Trade” and the Atlantic Economy of the Eighteenth Century: A Simple General-Equilibrium Model », dans Findlay, Ronald, Trade Development and Political Economy, Aldershot, Hants, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, pp. 321351.Google Scholar
(Sheila), Fitzpatrick, 1994, The Russian Revolution, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, (Robert W.), 1964, Railroads and American Economic Growth, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Fogel, (Robert W.), 1967, « The Specification Problem in Economic History », Journal of Economic History, vol. 27, pp. 283308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregory, (Paul R.) et Stuart, (Robert C), 1986, Soviet Economic Structure and Performance, New York, Harper & Row, Publishers Inc. Google Scholar
Harley, (C. Knick), 1992, « The Antebellum American Tariff: Food Exports and Manufacturing », Explorations in Economic History, vol. 29, pp. 375500.Google Scholar
Harley, (C. Knick), 1993, « Reassessing the Industrial Revolution: A Macro View », dans Mokyr, Joel ed., The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, Boulder, Colorado, Westview Press, pp. 171226.Google Scholar
(Mark), Harrison, 1996, Accounting for War: Soviet Production Employment and the Defence Burden 1940-1945, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hoeffding (Oleg), 1954, Soviet National Income and Product in 1928, New York, Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Holzman, (Franklyn D.), 1955, Soviet Taxation, Cambridge, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
(Glenn), Hueckel, 1973, « War and the British Economy, 1793-1815: A General Equilibrium Approach », Explorations in Economic History, vol. 10, pp. 365396.Google Scholar
Hunter (Holland) et Szyrmer (Janusz M.), 1992, Faulty Foundations: Soviet Economic Policies 1928-1940, Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
James, (J.), 1978, « The Welfare Effects of the Antebellum Tariff: A General Equilibrium Analysis », Explorations in Economic History, vol. 15, pp. 231256.Google Scholar
James, (J.), 1981, « The Optimal Tariff in Antebellum United States », American Economic Review, vol. 71, pp. 726-724.Google Scholar
James, (J.), 1984, « The Use of General Equilibrium Analysis in Economic History », Explorations in Economic History, vol. 21, pp. 231253.Google Scholar
(Naum), Jasny, 1949, The Socialized Agriculture of the USSR: Plans and Performance, Stanford, Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Johnston, (Bruce F.) et Mellor, (John W.), 1961, « The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development », American Economic Review, vol. 51, pp. 566593.Google Scholar
Kaplan, (Norman M.) et Moorsteen, (Richard H.), 1960, Index of Soviet Industrial Output, Rand Corporation, Research Memorandum RM-2495.Google Scholar
Kelley, (A. C.) et Williamson, (J. G.), 1974, Lessons from Japanese Development: An Analytical Economic History, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Khanin, (G. I.), 1991, Dinamika ekonomi č eskogo razvitija SSSR, Novosobirsk.Google Scholar
Leontief, (W. W.), 1941, The Structure of the American Economy 1919-1929, New York, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lewin, (M.), 1968, Russian Peasants and Soviet Power, Londres, Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
(Frank), Lewis, 1975, « The Canadian Wheat Boom and Per Capita Income: New Estimates », Journal of Political Economy, vol. 83, pp. 12491257.Google Scholar
(Frank), Lewis, 1979, « Explaining the Shift of Labor From Agriculture to Industry in the US », Journal of Economic History, vol. 39, pp. 681698.Google Scholar
Lorimer, (F.), 1946, The Population of the Soviet Union, Geneve.Google Scholar
Malafeyev, (A. N.), 1964, Istorija Cenoobrazovanija v SSSR, Moscou, Mysl'.Google Scholar
Merl, (S.), 1980, Der Agrarmarkt unddie Neue Ökonomische Politik. Die Anfange staatlicher Lenkung der Landwirtschaft in der Sowjetunion 1925-1928, Munich, Oldenbourg Verlag.Google Scholar
Merl, (S.), 1990, « Socio-Economic Differentiation of the Peasantry », dans From Tsarism to the New Economic Policy, R. W. Davies, ed., Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire, MacMillan Academic and Professional Ltd, pp. 4763.Google Scholar
(James), Millar, 1974, « Mass Collectivization and the Contribution of Soviet Agriculture to the First Five-Year Plan: A Review Article », Slavic Review, vol. 33.Google Scholar
(James), Millar, 1976, « What's Wrong with the “ Standard Story ” ? », Problems of Communism. Google Scholar
Moorsteen, (R.) et Powell, (R. P.), 1966, The Soviet Capital Stock 1928-1962, Homewood Ill., Richard D. Irwin, Inc. Google Scholar
Nicholls, (William H.), 1964, « The Place of Agriculture in Economic Development », dans Eicher, Carl K. et Witt, Lawrence W. éds, Agriculture in Economic Development, New York, pp. 1144.Google Scholar
(Alec), Nove, 1990, An Economic History of the USSR, Londres, Penguin Books.Google Scholar
(Alec), Nove et (David), Morrizon, 1982, « The Contribution of Agriculture to Accumulation in the 1930s », dans Bettelheim, Charles éd., L'industrialisation de I'URSS dans les ann é es trente, Paris, Éditions de l'École des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, pp. 47 63.Google Scholar
Nutter, (G. Warren), 1962, Growth of Industrial Production in the Soviet Union, Princeton, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
(Kevin), O'Rourke, 1991, « Rural Depopulation in a Small Open Economy: Ireland, 1856- 1876 », Explorations in Economic History, vol. 28, pp. 409432.Google Scholar
Percy, (M. B.), Norrie, (K. H.) et Johnston, (R. G.), 1982, Explorations in Economic History, vol. 19, pp. 409443.Google Scholar
Preobrazhensky, (E.), 1965, The New Economics, 1926, traduit par Brian Pearce, Oxford, Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Roberts, (Bryan W.) et (Alvardo), Rodriguez, 1997, « Economic Growth under a Self- Interested Central Planner and Transition to a Market Economy », Journal of Comparative Economics, vol. 24, pp. 121139.Google Scholar
Tauger, (M.), 1991, « The 1932 Harvest and the Famine of 1933 », Slavic Review, vol. 50.Google Scholar
(Peter), Temin, 1966, « Labor Scarcity and the Problem of American Industrial Efficiency in the 1850s », Journal of Economic History, vol. 26, pp. 361379.Google Scholar
(Peter), Temin, 1971a, « General Equilibrium Models in Economic History », Journal of Economic History, vol. 31, pp. 5875.Google Scholar
(Peter), Temin, 1971b, « Labor Scarcity in America », Journal of Interdisciplinary History, vol. 1, pp. 251264.Google Scholar
Vyltsan, (M. A.), 1966, « Obščestvenno-ekonomičeskij stoj kolhoznoj derevni v 1933-1940 gg. », Istoria SSSR, n° 2, pp. 4465.Google Scholar
(Léon), Walras, 1974, Éléments d'économie politique pure, Lausanne, Imprimerie L. Corbaz & Cie Éditeurs.Google Scholar
Wilbur, (Charles K.), 1969, « The Role of Agriculture in Soviet Economic Development », Land Economics, vol. 45, pp. xx.Google Scholar
Williamson, (J. G.), 1974, Late Nineteenth Century American Development: A General Equilibrium History, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, (J. G.), 1985, Did British Capitalism Breed Inequality ?, Boston, Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Williamson, (J. G.) et Lindert, (P. H.), 1980, American Inequality: A Macroeconomic History, New York, Academic Press.Google Scholar
(Eugene), Zaleski, 1955, « Les fluctuations des prix de detail en Union sovietique », Etudes et conjonctures, pp. 329384.Google Scholar
(Eugene), Zaleski, 1984, La planification stalinienne : croissance et fluctuations economiques en URSS 1932-1952, Paris, Economica.Google Scholar