Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T13:10:14.206Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Capital-Budgeting Systems and Capabilities Investments in U.S. Companies after the Second World War

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 December 2011

Carliss Y. Baldwin
Affiliation:
Carliss Y. Baldwin is William L. White Professor of Business Administration and teaches in the Finance area at theHarvard UniversityGraduate School of Business Administration.
Kim B. Clark
Affiliation:
Kim B. Clark is the Harry E. Figgie, Jr., Professor of Business Administration and chairman of the Technology and Operations Management area at theHarvard UniversityGraduate School of Business Administration.

Extract

The authors of this article argue that companies' high cost of capital or short investment horizons do not explain the decline in global competitiveness of many U.S. industries in the 1970s and 1980s. Instead, they find the source of malaise in the capital-budgeting and financial-planning systems that arose after the Second World War. Although they allowed managers in large companies to evaluate some aspects of their business efficiently and comprehensively, these systems also obscured the value of investment in organizational capabilities, because such investments were hard to quantify—indeed, even to describe—within the financial models in widespread use. As a result, companies often invested vigorously—but in the wrong things. The authors define a set of desirable capabilities and, using case studies, describe both the problems of the recent past and the requirements for successful investment in the future.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The President and Fellows of Harvard College 1994

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Servan-Schreiber, J. J., The American Challenge, trans. Steel, R. (New York, 1968), 29.Google Scholar

2 On the U.S. loss of market dominance, see, for example, Scott, Bruce R. and Lodge, George C., eds., U.S. Competitiveness in the World Economy (Boston, Mass., 1985);Google ScholarDertouzos, Michael L., Lester, Richard K., and Solow, Robert M., Made in America: Regaining the Productive Edge (Cambridge, Mass., 1989)Google Scholar; Franko, Lawrence G., “Global Corporate Competition: Who's Winning, Who's Losing and the R&D Factor as One Reason Why,” Strategic Management Journal 10 (1989): 449–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., “The Competitive Performance of U.S. Industrial Enterprise since the Second World War,” Business History Review 68 (Spring 1994): 172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 On U.S. technological disadvantages, see, for example, Lynn, Leonard H., How Japan Innovates: A Comparison with the U.S. in the Case of Oxygen Steelmaking (Boulder, Colo., 1982)Google Scholar; Jaikumar, Ramchandran, “Japanese Flexible Manufacturing Systems: Impact on the United States,” Japan and the World Economy 1 (March 1989): 113–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Clark, Kim B. and Fujimoto, Takahiro, Product Development Performance: Strategy, Organization, and Management in the World Auto Industry (Boston, Mass., 1991)Google Scholar; Cusumano, Michael, Japan's Software Factories: A Challenge to U.S. Management (New York, 1991)Google Scholar; Flaherty, Therese, “Unexploited Opportunities and an Administrative Disconnect: Causes of and Cures for Malaise in U.S. Semiconductor Manufacturing,” unpub. MS, Harvard Business School, Boston, Mass. (1991).Google Scholar

4 A debate on comparative costs of capital raged throughout the 1980s. See, for example, Hatsopoulos, George N. and Brooks, Stephen H., “The Gap in the Cost of Capital: Causes, Effects, and Remedies,” Technology and Economic Policy, ed. Landau, Ralph and Jorgenson, Dale W. (Cambridge, Mass., 1986), 221–80Google Scholar; Baldwin, Carliss Y., “The Capital Factor: Competing for Capital in a Global Environment,” in Competition in Global Industries, ed. Porter, Michael E. (Boston, Mass., 1986), 185223Google Scholar; Kester, W. Carl and Luehrman, Timothy A., “What Makes You Think U.S. Capital Is So Expensive?Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 5 (Summer 1992): 2941.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

5 Hayes, Robert H. and Abernathy, William A., “Managing Our Way to Economic Decline,” Harvard Business Review 58: (July-August 1980): 6777Google Scholar, were among the first to argue that the capital markets encouraged short-run investment policies among managers. Mechanisms that might cause managerial “myopia” were discussed in Stein, Jeremy C., “Takeover Threats and Managerial Myopia,” Journal of Political Economy 96' (Feb. 1988): 6180CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W., “Equilibrium Short Horizons of Investors and Firms,” American Economic Review 80 (May 1990): 148–53.Google Scholar

6 Our table is extrapolated from the data in Chandler, “The Competitive Performance of U.S. Industrial Enterprises since the Second World War,” 1–72. Chandler's data are based in part on Franko, “Global Corporate Competition.”

7 Jensen, Michael, “The Modern Industrial Revolution: Exit and the Failure of Internal Control Systems,” Journal of Finance 48 (July 1993): 831–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 The idea that organizational capabilities are assets is not new. Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism (Cambridge, Mass., 1990)Google Scholar, showed that large-scale corporations achieved market dominance by being first movers in building capabilities for production, distribution, and marketing. Winter, Sidney G., “Knowledge and Competence as Strategic Assets,” in The Competitive Challenge: Strategies for Industrial Innovation and Renewal, ed. Teece, David J. (Cambridge, Mass., 1987), 159–84Google Scholar, proposed that competence, knowledge, and learned routines are “unconventional” assets that contribute to the value of a company.

9 On the development of profit-planning systems in the United States, see Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambridge, Mass., 1977)Google Scholar and Johnson, H. Thomas and Kaplan, Robert S., Relevance Lost: The Rise and Fall of Management Accounting (Boston, Mass., 1987)Google Scholar. On the development and diffusion of capital-budgeting techniques, see Dulman, Scott P., “The Development of Discounted Cash Flow Techniques in U.S. Industry,” Business History Review 63 (Autumn 1989): 555–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10 IBM's installed systems grew from 29 in 1955 to 738 in 1959. Its primary customers were large companies seeking to automate accounting and transactions processing. Fischer, Franklin, McKie, James, and Mancke, Richard, IBM and the U.S. Data Processing Industry: An Economic History (New York, 1983).Google Scholar

11 One of the prime architects of hierarchical planning systems was Robert Anthony. In the area of decentralized profit and responsibility accounting, he collaborated with John Dearden and Richard Vancil. See, for example, Anthony, Robert N., Planning and Control Systems: A Framework for Analysis (Boston, Mass., 1965)Google Scholar; Anthony, , Dearden, and Vancil, , Management Control Systems: Cases and Readings (Homewood, Ill., 1965).Google Scholar

12 See, for example, Brealey, Richard A. and Myers, Stewart C., Principles of Corporate Finance, 3d ed. (New York, 1988)Google Scholar, or Bierman, Harold and Smidt, Seymour, The Capital Budgeting Decision, 8th ed. (New York, 1988).Google Scholar

13 Dean, Joel, Capital Budgeting (New York, 1951)Google Scholar; Dean, , “Measuring the Productivity of Capital,” Harvard Business Review 32 (Jan.-Feb. 1954): 120–30Google Scholar; Anthony, Robert N., Management Accounting: Text and Cases (Homewood, Ill., 1956)Google Scholar; Dulman, “Development of Discounted Cash Flow Techniques.”

14 Schall, L., Sundem, G., and Geijsbeek, W. Jr., “Survey and Analysis of Capital Budgeting Methods,” Journal of Finance 33 (March 1978): 281–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Financial-planning and capital-budgeting systems in Japan and Europe have not been studied as intensively as those in the United States. The work that has been done suggests that outside the United States 1) the planning process is less structured and rigid; 2) a different concept of valuation is prevalent; and 3) there are dramatically different mechanisms contributing to interfunctional communication and coordination. On Japan, see, for example, Hodder, James E., “Evaluation of Manufacturing Investments: A Comparison of U.S. and Japanese Practices,” Financial Management 12 (Spring 1986): 1724CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Abegglen, James C. and Stalk, George Jr., Kaisha: The Japanese Corporation (New York, 1985)Google Scholar; Aoki, Masahiko, Information, Incentives, and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy (New York, 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On Europe, see Servan-Schreiber, The American Challenge; Clark and Fujimoto, Product Development Performance; Kester, W. Carl, “Governance, Contracting and Investment Horizons: A Look at Japan and Germany,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 5 (Summer 1992): 8398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Bower, Joseph, Managing the Resource Allocation Process (Boston, Mass., 1970).Google Scholar

17 Ibid., chap. 6.

18 Ibid., 47.

19 For descriptions of reorganizations at General Electric and Westinghouse (disguised as Imperial Corporation), see Richard F. Vancil and P. C. Browne, “General Electric Co., Background Note on Management Systems—1981,” Harvard Business School, Case 9-181-111 (1981); Francis J. Aguilar and R. G. Hamermesh, “General Electric: Strategic Position—1981,” Harvard Business School, Case 9-381-174 (1981); and Norman A. Berg, et al., “Imperial Corporation (A) and (B),” Harvard Business School, Cases 380–123 and 380–124 (1980).

20 Fruhan, William E. Jr., Revitalizing Businesses: Shareholder/Workforce Conflicts (Boston, Mass., 1985)Google Scholar, and Baker, George P. III, “Beatrice: A Study in the Creation and Destruction of Value,” Journal of Finance 47 (July 1992): 1081–119CrossRefGoogle Scholar, each describe financial restructurings that recombined business units into new corporations. On the concept and methods of “break-up valuation,” see Copeland, Thomas E., Koller, Tim, and Murrin, Jack, Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies (New York, 1990).Google Scholar

21 Porter, Michael E., Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors (New York, 1980).Google Scholar

22 David Teece, Gary Pisano, and Amy Shuen, “Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management,” Working Paper 90–8, Consortium on Competitiveness and Cooperation, Berkeley, Calif. (Dec. 1992), provides a useful overview of these models.

23 Chandler (in this volume) argues that the rise of an active market for whole companies (and banks specializing in such transactions) was a critical historical development that distinguished the 1980s from earlier periods. See Kaufman, Allen and Englander, Ernest, “Kohlberg Kravis Roberts & Co. and The Restructuring of American Capitalism,” Business History Review 67 (Spring 1993): 5297CrossRefGoogle Scholar, on the emergence of KKR, a merchant bank that specialized in buying and selling companies.

24 On the role of the corporation's central office, see Goold, Michael and Campbell, Andrew, Strategies and Styles: The Role of the Centre in Managing Diversified Corporations (Oxford, England, 1987)Google Scholar and Chandler, Scale and Scope. For a highly critical view of top management in U.S. corporations, see Jensen, Michael, “The Eclipse of the Public Corporation,” Harvard Business Review 67 (Sept.-Oct. 1989): 6174.Google Scholar

25 On the preeminence of discounted cash flow in corporate valuation, see Rappaport, Alfred, Creating Shareholder Value: The New Standard for Business Performance (New York, 1986)Google Scholar, or Copeland, Koller, and Murrin, Valuation.

26 Bierman, Harold, Implementing Capital Budgeting Techniques, rev. ed. (Cambridge, Mass., 1988)Google Scholar, surveyed 102 chief financial officers on the problems of implementing capital-budgeting analysis. Difficulty in incorporating strategic considerations was the problem most frequently cited.

27 Donaldson, Gordon, Managing Corporate Wealth: The Operation of a Comprehensive Financial Goals System (New York, 1984)Google Scholar. The importance of financial measures also varies greatly across companies. Morone, Joseph and Paulson, Albert, “Cost of Capital: The Managerial Perspective,” Califiornia Management Review 33 (Summer 1991): 932CrossRefGoogle Scholar, provide a recent survey of top managers' use of financial criteria in strategic investment decisions.

28 Theoretical explanations of this structure based on human fallibility or asymmetric information can be found in Sah, Raaj Kumar and Stiglitz, Joseph E., “The Architecture of Economic Systems: Hierarchies and Polyarchies,” American Economic Review 76 (Sept. 1986): 716–27Google Scholar; Bull, C. and Ordover, Janusz A., “Market Structure and Optimal Management Organizations,” Rand Journal of Economics 18 (Winter 1987): 480–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Thakor, Anjan V., “Investment ‘Myopia’ and the Internal Organization of Capital Allocation Decisions,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 6 (Spring 1990): 129–48.Google Scholar

29 Bower, Managing Resource Allocation, chap. 5.

30 Kaplan, Robert S., “Must CIM Be Justified by Faith Alone?Harvard Business Review 64 (March-April 1986): 8795.Google Scholar

31 Hertenstein, Julie H. and Borowitz, N. S., “Lex Service PLC,” Harvard Business School Publications Division (Boston, Mass., 1985).Google Scholar

32 The most famous technology rule was Moore's Law, which stated that the number of devices on a semiconductor “chip” would double every twelve months. Semiconductor firms geared capital spending to this “law” from the early 1960s to the mid-1980s, when the doubling interval was increased to two years. Braun, Ernest and Macdonald, Stuart, Revolution in Miniature: The History and Impact of Semiconductor Electronics, 2d ed. (New York, 1981)Google Scholar. For a discussion of the economic rationale behind such rules, see Baldwin, Carliss Y., “How Capital Budgeting Deters Innovation—And What To Do about It,” Research-Technology Management 34 (Nov.-Dec. 1991): 3945.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

33 Avishai, Bernard, “A CEO's Common Sense of CIM: An Interview with J. Tracy O'Rourke,” Harvard Business Review 67 (Jan.-Feb. 1989): 110–17.Google Scholar

34 Hayes, Robert H., Wheelwright, Steven C., and Clark, Kim B., Dynamic Manufacturing: Creating the Learning Organization (New York, 1988).Google Scholar

35 Chandler, “Competitive Performance of U.S. Industrial Enterprise.”

36 Halberstam, David, The Reckoning (New York, 1986)Google Scholar, depicts the growing conflict between finance and production managers at the Ford Motor Company in the 1970s. This book was instrumental in educating the American public about the differences between Japanese and U.S. production practices.

37 Hayes and Abernathy, “Managing Our Way to Economic Decline.”

38 Hayes, Robert H. and Garvin, David A., “Managing as if Tomorrow Mattered,” Harvard Business Review 60 (May-June 1982): 7179.Google Scholar

39 Myers, Stewart C., “Finance Theory and Financial Strategy,” Interfaces 14 (Jan.-Feb. 1984): 126–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

40 The studies cited in this article focus on manufactured products. However, capabilities can be used to enhance service-based and financial products as well.

41 Garvin, David A., Managing Quality: The Strategic and Competitive Edge (Boston, Mass., 1988).Google Scholar

42 Clark and Fujimoto, Product Development Performance.

44 For descriptions of complex design processes, see von Hippel, Eric, “Task Partitioning: An Innovation Process Variable,” Research Policy 19 (Oct. 1990): 407–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar, or Eppinger, S. E., et al. , “Organizing the Tasks in Complex Design Projects,” unpub. MS, MIT, Cambridge, Mass. (1990).Google Scholar

45 Jaikumar, “Japanese Flexible Manufacturing Systems.”

46 Jaikumar, , “Hitachi Seiki,” Harvard Business School, Case 9-686-104 (1986).Google Scholar

47 On the value of modularity in product design, see Eppinger, et al., “Organizing the Tasks in Complex Design Projects”; Ulrich, Karl, “The Role of Product Architecture in the Manufacturing Firm,” Working Paper 3483-92-MSA, Sloan School of Management, MIT, Cambridge, Mass. (1992)Google Scholar; Sanchez, R. A., “Strategic Flexibility, Real Options and Product-Based Strategy” (Ph.D. diss., Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1991)Google Scholar, and Baldwin, Carliss Y. and Clark, Kim B., “The Benefits and Costs of Modularity-in-Design,” unpub. MS, Harvard Business School, Boston, Mass. (March 1993).Google Scholar

48 Jaikumar, Ramchandran, “An Architecture for a Process Control Costing System,” Measures for Manufacturing Excellence, ed. Kaplan, Robert S. (Boston, Mass., 1990), 193222Google Scholar; Upton, David, “Process Range in Manufacturing: An Empirical Study of Flexibility,” Working Paper 93-071, Harvard Business School, Boston, Mass. (April 1993)Google Scholar; Mishina, Kazuhiro, “A Study of Toyota's Approach to Product Variety,” Working Paper 93-076, Harvard Business School, Boston, Mass. (May 1993).Google Scholar

49 Krafcik, John F., “Triumph of the Lean Production System,” Sloan Management Review 30 (Fall 1988): 4152Google Scholar; Krafcik, and MacDuffie, John P., “Explaining High Performance Manufacturing: The International Automotive Assembly Plant Study,” MIT Working Paper, Cambridge, Mass. (May 1989).Google Scholar

50 Jaikumar, “Architecture for a Process Control Costing System.” For an analysis of the value of learning and experimentation based on the theory of real options, see Kogut, Bruce and Kulatilaka, Nalin, “What Is a Critical Capability?” paper presented at the meeting of the Joseph A. Schumpeter Society, Kyoto, Japan, Aug. 1992.Google Scholar

51 Bohn, Roger E. and Jaikumar, Ramchandran, “The Development of Intelligent Systems for Industrial Use: An Empirical Investigation,” Research on Technological Innovation, Management and Policy, ed. Rosenbloom, Richard S., 3 (Greenwich, Conn., 1986), 213–62.Google Scholar

52 Graham, Margaret M. B., “Learning Lost: The Problem of Not Accounting for R&D,” unpub. MS, Boston University, Boston Mass. (Sept. 1990).Google Scholar

53 Flaherty, “Unexploited Opportunities.”

54 Barnett, Donald F. and Schorsch, Louis, Steel: Upheaval in a Basic Industry (Cambridge, Mass., 1983).Google Scholar

55 Lynn, How Japan Innovates.

56 Baldwin, Carliss Y., Tribendis, Joseph J., and Clark, Joel P., “The Evolution of Market Risk in the U.S. Steel Industry and Implications for Required Rates of Return,” journal of Industrial Economics 33 (Sept. 1984): 7398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

57 Tiffany, Paul A., The Decline of American Steel (New York, 1988).Google Scholar

58 Schumpeter, Joseph A., Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New York, 1942)Google Scholar. On cannibalism, see, for example, the finance texts of Brealey and Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance, chaps. 6 and 11, or Ross, Stephen A., Westerfield, Randolph W., and Jaffe, Jeffrey F., Corporate Finance, 2d ed. (Homewood, Ill., 1988)Google Scholar, chap. 7. Crandall, Robert W., The U.S. Steel Industry in Recurrent Crisis: Policy Options in a Competitive World (Washington, D.C., 1981)Google Scholar, applied this logic to the U.S. steel industry, arguing that it was not cost-effective for integrated companies in the 1960s to adopt new technology in existing plants.

59 Foster, Richard N., Innovation: The Attacker's Advantage (New York, 1986).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

60 Star, Steven H. and Urban, Glen L., “The Case of the Test Market Toss-Up,” Harvard Business Review 66 (Sept.-Oct. 1988): 412.Google Scholar

61 Ferguson, Charles H., “American Microelectronics in Decline: Evidence, Analysis and Alternatives” (Ph.D. diss., Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1987).Google Scholar

62 Henderson, Rebecca and Clark, Kim, “Generational Innovation: The Reconfiguration of Existing Systems and the Failure of Established Firms,” Administrative Sciences Quarterly 35 (March 1990): 930.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

63 Gilbert, Richard J. and Newbery, D. M. G., “Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly,” American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 514–26Google Scholar; Baldwin, Carliss Y., “Strategic Capital Budgeting: The Case of New Product Introductions,” Working Paper 90-037, Harvard Business School, Boston, Mass. (Nov. 1989).Google Scholar

64 Tushman, Michael L. and Anderson, Philip, “Technological Discontinuities and Organizational Environments,” Administrative Sciences Quarterly 31 (1986): 439–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

65 Specifically, external integration reduces product risk. Internal integration increases the frequency of opportunities. Flexibility increases the range of options associated with a given investment. The capacity to experiment allows systematic improvement and thus increases value over time. Finally, the capacity to cannibalize deters entry and thus increases the value of a company's market position in the long run. See Kogut, Bruce and Kulatilaka, Nalin, “Options Thinking and Platform Investments: Investing in Opportunity,” unpub. MS, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 1992.Google Scholar

66 On the consequences of increasing returns for economic equilibria, see Arthur, W. Brian, “Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-in by Historical Events,” Economic Journal 99 (March 1989): 116–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

67 Technically, capabilities have the property of supermodularity. See Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John, “The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy, and Organization,” American Economic Review 80 (June 1990): 511–28.Google Scholar

68 Wheelwright, Steven C. and Clark, Kim B., Revolutionizing Product Development: Quantum Leaps in Speed, Efficiency, and Quality (New York, 1992).Google Scholar

69 See, for example, Stalk, George Jr., “Time—The Next Source of Competitive Advantage,” Harvard Business Review 66 (July-Aug. 1988): 4151Google Scholar; Stalk, and Hout, Thomas M., Competing Against Time: How Time-Based Competition Is Reshaping Global Markets (New York, 1990)Google Scholar; Eisenhardt, Kathleen M., “Speed and Strategic Choice: How Managers Accelerate Decision-Making,” California Management Review 32 (1990): 116CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Sanderson, S. W., “Cost Models for Evaluating Virtual Design Strategies in Multicycle Product Families,” Journal of Engineering and Technology Management 8 (1991): 339–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

70 Chandler, Scale and Scope.

71 In general, increasing returns to any type of investment make the long-run equilibrium sensitive to actions by a first mover. For elaboration of the economic arguments, see Arthur, “Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns,” or Sutton, John, Sunk Costs and Market Structure: Price Competition, Advertising, and the Evolution of Concentration (Cambridge, Mass., 1991).Google Scholar