Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vfjqv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T16:17:27.323Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Economics of the “Second Land Reform” in China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 February 2009

Extract

For peasants who have been collectivized for nearly three decades, the national campaign initiated by the Party Central Committee's Document No. 1, 1984 to promote the reparcellization of collective farmland, by extending the peasants' leasehold right to over 15 years (para. 3–1), is certainly not less spectacular than the land reform of 1949–52, when land was confiscated from the rich for redistribution among poor peasant families. This “second land reform” has now firmly consolidated the long-fought policy of Deng Xiaoping for a decentralized approach towards rural management. All the cats – “black or white” – seem to have now been totally unleashed to run after their best catch. This stands in sharp contrast to the uneasy equilibrium of the “two-line struggle,” which existed throughout the entire 20-year period following the abortive communization drive of 1958/1959. Nevertheless, while probably no Chinese leader today can afford to play the role of Mao's Liu cum Deng, one wonders whether, for economic reasons, the present rural institutional solution as envisaged in Document No. 1 will mark the end of the perennial Chinese search for an “optimum” level of decentralization. In a way, the agricultural reform of recent years has begun with the drastic increases, decreed in 1979, in state farm procurement prices, averaging 25 per cent. For a regime very much obsessed with the value imperative of modernization, the farm price increases should clearly be construed as income incentives for promoting agricultural production to ease the economic constraints on industrialization. This is nothing new but is exactly the policy developed by the prominent Chinese economist, Ma Yinchu, some 25 years ago in his then much condemned “balanced growth model” for China. Thus the strategy fits in well with a western analytical model formulated by Chiang and Fei in 1966, for a “maximum-speed development through austerity.” The model postulates that under socialism, a consumption policy which imposes an “optimum” rather than maximum degree of austerity, may induce greater labour effort and thus an output growth more than proportionate to the required marginal consumption expenditure. It follows that not only will the rate of capital accumulation not be depressed by increased consumption, but it may even accelerate and thus help to sustain a higher overall income growth rate.

Type
Recent Developments
Copyright
Copyright © The China Quarterly 1985

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. See Walker, Kenneth R., “Ideology and economic discussion in China: Ma Yin-ch'u on development strategy and his critics,” in Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. XI, No. 2, Pt. 1 (01 1963), pp. 113–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2. Chiang, Alpha C. and Fei, John C. H., “Maximum-speed development through austerity,” in Adelman, Irma and Thorbecke, E. (eds.), The Theory and Design of Economic Development (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1966), pp. 6792.Google Scholar

3. Kueh, Y. Y., “China's new agricultural-policy program: major economic consequences, 1979–1983,” in Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 8, No. 4 (12 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The amount is of course partly purported to be for rural self investments as well.

4. Note that in the similar decrees in 1979, baochan daohu was explicitly prohibited; see Zhongguo nongye nianjian 1980 (Chinese Agricultural Yearbook 1980) (Beijing: Nongye chubanshe), p. 58Google Scholar. And in the so-called Document No. 75 of September 1980, only a negligible number of production teams regarded as poor were allowed to practise baochan daohu: see Zhongguo nongye nianjian 1981, pp. 409411.Google Scholar

5. See Eckstein, Alexander, China's Economic Development: The Interplay of Scarcity and Ideology (Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press, 1975), pp. 268–72Google Scholar, for a good discussion about the relationship between mass mobilization and communization, and the role played by the Maoist ideology.

6. Kueh, Y. Y., Economic Planning and Local Mobilization in Post-Mao China, No. 7, Research Notes and Studies Series, Contemporary China Institute, School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London, 1985.Google Scholar

7. Kueh, Y. Y., “Foodgrain production instability in China and the world grain trade,” paper presented at the Seventh World Congress of the International Economic Association, 5–9 09 1983, Madrid, Spain.Google Scholar

8. Chinese Communist Party Central Committee, “Some problems of current rural economic policy” (Document No. 1, 1983)Google Scholar, in Zhongguo nongmin bao (China Peasants Daily), 10 04 1983, pp. 12.Google Scholar

9. For details see for example, Nongcun gongzuo tongxun (Rural Work Bulletin), No. 3 (1984), pp. 13 and 15Google Scholar, and No. 8 (1984), p. 5.

10. Ibid. No. 2 (1984), p. 7.

11. Ibid. No. 7 (1984), pp. 30 and 33.

12. Ibid. No. 8 (1984), p. 14.

13. Ibid. No. 2 (1984), p. 45; see also No. 8 (1984), p. 5. The custom is for the men to be “married into” and live with the wife's family.

14. Nongye jingji wenti (Problems of Agricultural Economics), No. 8 (1984), p. 42Google Scholar. See also Nongcun gongzuo tongxin, No. 6 (1984), pp. 3435.Google Scholar

15. See, e.g., Noncun gongzuo tongxun, No. 8 (1984), p. 12.Google Scholar

16. For the best account of this see Perkins, Dwight, Market Control and Central Planning in China (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965), pp. 2842.Google Scholar

17. Johnson, D. Gale, “Agriculture in the centrally planned economies,” in American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 64, No. 5 (12 1982), p. 845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

18. Nongcun gongzuo tongxun, No. 8 (1984), p. 12.Google Scholar

19. Ibid. No. 8 (1984), p. 4. See also No. 3 (1984), p. 12.

20. Kueh, Y. Y., “A weather index for analysing grain yield instability in China, 1952–81,” The China Quarterly, No. 97 (03 1984).Google Scholar

21. Xinhua yuebao (New China Monthly), No. 1 (1984), pp. 117–18.Google Scholar

22. Ibid. p. 117.