Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-5g6vh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T01:01:09.870Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

More Than Anyone Bargained For: Beyond the Welfare Contract

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 September 2012

Extract

From British debates over the 1832 New Poor Law to the near present, the notion of “desert” has long had a clear referent in discussions of social welfare policy. The designation “deserving poor” was reserved for those with legitimate grounds for not supporting themselves through paid employment. Invariably among them were the very young, the very old, and the mentally and physically very disabled—people who literally could not work for a living. Also included were various categories of people who, according to the varying conventions of the day, were socially excused from paid labor—widows in the Victorian era, students in the postwar era, and so on. Anyone who could and should work for a living but refused to do so was traditionally deemed to be among the “undeserving poor.” Those were the people whose “welfare dependency” has long been the target of welfare reformers, most recently Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher, Bill Clinton and Tony Blair.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Carnegie Council for Ethics in International Affairs 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Himmelfarb, Gertrude, The Idea of Poverty (London: Faber & Faber, 1984)Google Scholar. Handler, Joel F. and Hasenfeld, Yeheskel, The Moral Construction of Poverty: Welfare Reform in America (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1991)Google Scholar. Goodin, Robert E., “Social Welfare as a Collective Social Responsibility,” in Social Welfare and Individual Responsibility, edited by Goodin, and Schmidtz, David (New York: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming)Google Scholar.

2 On this new discourse more generally, see Goodin, Robert E., “The End of the Welfare State?” in The Cambridge History of Twentieth-Century Political Thought, edited by Ball, Terence and Bellamy, Richard (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming)Google Scholar.

3 Reich, Charles A., “The New Property,” Yale Law Journal 73 (1964), pp. 733–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Titmuss, Richard M., “Welfare ‘Rights,’ Law and Discretion,” Political Quarterly 42 (1971), pp. 113–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Goodin, Robert E., Reasons for Welfare (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1988), ch. 7Google Scholar. Jo Bane, Mary and Ellwood, David T., Welfare Realities: From Rhetoric to Reform (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994)Google Scholar, ch. 1. Mead, Lawrence M., Beyond Entitlement: The Social Obligations of Citizenship (New York: Free Press, 1986)Google Scholar; The New Politics of Poverty (New York: Basic Books, 1992)Google Scholar; and Citizenship and Social Policy: T. H. Marshall and Poverty,” Social Philosophy & Policy 14 (Summer 1997), pp. 197230CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Derthick, Martha, Uncontrollable Spending for Social Services Grants (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1975)Google Scholar.

4 Hence the image of Social Security pensions as “the third rail of American politics”: like the third rail on an electrified train track, touch it and you are dead. See more generally Pierson, Paul, Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan, Thatcher, and the Politics of Retrenchment (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, ch. 3.

5 Rousseau, Jean-Jacques, The Social Contract, trans. Cole, G. D. H. (1762; London: Everyman/Dent, 1973)Google Scholar, bk. 1, ch. 3.

6 As surveyed by Waldron, Jeremy, “Welfare and the Images of Charity,” Philosophical Quarterly 36 (December 1986), pp. 463–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 43 Elizabeth I, ch. 2. Were it only as easy to buy off the homeless today!

8 Rimlinger, Gaston V., Welfare Policy and Industrialization in Europe, America and Russia (New York: Wiley, 1971)Google Scholar.

9 The “Harvester judgment”—Higgins, H. B., “Ex pane H. V. McKay,” Commonwealth Arbitration Reports 2 1907–8 pp. 317Google Scholar—reprinted in part in The Australian Welfare State: Key Documents and Themes, edited by Wilson, John, Thomson, Jane, and McMahon, Anthony (Melbourne: Macmillan, 1996), pp. 2125Google Scholar. See further Macintyre, Stuart, Winners & Losers: The Pursuit of Social Justice in Australian History (Sydney: Allen & Unwin, 1985)Google Scholar, ch. 3.

10 Middlemas, Keith, Power, Competition and the State (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1991), vol. 3CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Kelley, Paul, The End of Certainty (Sydney: Allen & Unwin, 1992)Google Scholar.

11 Glennerster, Howard, British Social Policy since 1945 (Oxford: Blackwell, 1995), pp. 1012Google Scholar. Jessop, Bob, Bownett, Kevin, Bromley, Simon, and Ling, Tom, “Authoritarian Populism, Two Nations and Thatcherism,” New Left Review 147 (1984), pp. 3260Google Scholar. Middlemas, Power, Competition and the State, vol. 2.

12 Korpi, Walter, The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1983)Google Scholar.

13 Rawls, John, A Theory of Justice (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971), sec. 86Google Scholar.

14 See various reports by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development: The Future of Social Protection, OECD Social Policy Studies no. 6 (Paris: OECD, 1988)Google Scholar, chs. 3–4; Reforming Public Pensions, Social Policy Studies no. 5 (Paris: OECD, 1988)Google Scholar; New Orientations for Social Policy, Social Policy Studies no. 12 (Paris: OECD, 1994)Google Scholar. See also World Bank, Averting the Old Age Crisis: Policies to Protect the Old and Promote Growth (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994)Google Scholar.

15 Daniels, Norman, Am I My Parents' Keeper? (New York: Oxford University Press, 1988), ch. 7Google Scholar. Chand, Sheetal K. and Jaeger, Albert et al. , Aging Populations and Public Pension Schemes, IMF Occasional Paper no. 147 (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Aaron, Henry J., Bosworth, Barry P., and Burtless, Gary T., Can America Afford to Grow Old? Paying for Social Security (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1989)Google Scholar. Henry J. Aaron and Barry P. Bosworth, “Preparing for the Baby Boomers' Retirement,” in Setting National Priorities: Budget Choices for the Next Century, edited by Robert D. Reischauer, pp. 263–302.

16 Walker, Alan, The New Generational Contract: Intergenerational Relations, Old Age and Welfare (London: UCL Press, 1996)Google Scholar. See similarly: Laslett, Peter, “The Conversation Between the Generations,” in Philosophy, Politics & Society, 5th series, edited by Laslett, Peter and Fishkin, James S. (Oxford: Blackwell, 1979), pp. 3656Google Scholar; and Laslett, Peter and Fishkin, James S., eds., Justice Between Generations (Oxford: Blackwell, 1992)Google Scholar.

17 Lewis, Jane and Glennerster, Howard, Implementing the New Community Care (Buckingham: Open University Press, 1996)Google Scholar. Garon, Sheldon, Molding Japanese Minds: The State in Everyday Life (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997)Google Scholar.

18 Goodin, , Protecting the Vulnerable: A Reanalysis of Our Social Responsibilities (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1985), pp. 7983Google Scholar.

19 Cf. Wolfe, Alan, Whose Keeper? Social Science and Moral Obligations (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989)Google Scholar, ch. 5.

20 Townsend, Peter, The Family Life of Old People (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1957)Google Scholar.

21 OECD, Reforming Public Pensions and New Orientations for Social Policy. World Bank, Averting the Old Age Crisis.

22 Diamond, Peter and Valdes-Prieto, Salvador, “Social Security Reform,” in The Chilean Economy, edited by Bosworth, Barry, Dornbushch, Rudiger, and Laban, R. (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1994), pp. 257320Google Scholar. World Bank, Averting the Old Age Crisis. Fazio, Hugo and Riesco, Manuel, “The Chilean Pension Fund Associations,” New Left Review 223 (1997), pp. 91100Google Scholar.

23 Smith, Steven Rathgeb and Lipsky, Michael, Non-Profits for Hire: The Welfare State In an Age of Contracting (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1993)Google Scholar. Gilbert, Neil, Welfare Justice: Restoring Social Equality (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1995), ch. 5Google Scholar. Johnson, Norman, ed., Private Markets in Health and Welfare: An International Perspective (Oxford: Berg, 1995)Google Scholar. Handler, Joel F., Down from Bureaucracy: The Ambiguity of Privatization and Empowerment (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1996), ch. 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24 Klein, Rudolf and Millar, Jane, “Do-It-Yourself Social Policy: Searching for a New Paradigm?” Social Policy & Administration 29 (1995), pp. 303–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 Challis, David and Davies, Bleddyn, Case Management in Community Care: An Evaluated Experiment in the Home Care of the Elderly (Aldershot: Gower, 1986)Google Scholar.

26 Le Grand, Julian, “Quasi-Markets and Social Policy,” Economic Journal 101 (1991), pp. 1256–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Le Grand, Julian and Bartlett, Will, eds., Quasi-Markets and Social Policy (London: Macmillan, 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 Olsson, Sven E., “Decentralization and Privatization: Strategies against a Welfare Backlash in Sweden,” in Testing the Limits of Social Welfare, edited by Morris, Robert (Hanover, N.H.: University Press of New England, for Brandeis University Press, 1988), pp. 6095Google Scholar, esp. pp. 81–83. Rothstein, Bo, Just Institutions Matter: On the Moral & Political Logic of the Universal Welfare State (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), ch. 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Etzioni, Amitai, Ann Glendon, Mary, Galston, William, et al. , “The Responsive Communitarian Platform: Rights and Responsibilities,” reprinted in Etzioni, The Spirit of Community: Rights, Responsibilities and the Communitarian Agenda (London: Fontana, 1995), pp. 251–67Google Scholar.

29 Ann Glendon, Mary, Rights Talk (New York: Free Press, 1991)Google Scholar. Lawrence Mead makes the same arguments against welfare entitlements in particular: see his Beyond Entitlement: The New Politics of Poverty; and “Citizenship and Social Policy.” In this, he is echoing many before him, most especially Alexis de Tocqueville's 1835 “Memoir on Pauperism,” reprinted in The Public Interest 70 (1983), pp. 102–20Google Scholar; see especially pp. 105–20.

30 Mead, , Beyond Entitlement and “Citizenship and Social Policy.” Amitai Etzioni, The New Golden Rule (New York: Basic Books, 1996)Google Scholar.

31 Gilbert, Welfare Justice, pp. 68–69. See further Collins, Mary, “A Guaranteed Minimum Income in France,” Social Policy & Administration 24 (1990), pp. 120–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 Mead, “Citizenship and Social Policy,” p. 221. See similarly Reischauer, Robert D., “The Welfare Reform Legislation: Directions for the Future,” in Welfare Policy for the 1990s, edited by Cottingham, Phoebe H. and Ellwood, David T. (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1989), pp. 1040Google Scholar.

33 Handler and Hasenfeld, The Moral Construction of Poverty, pp. 215–16.

34 Originally entitled the Welfare Reform Act of 1996, subsequently retitled the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996, Public Law 104–93 (H.R. 3734) August 22, 1996, 110 Stat. 2105.

35 Clinton, William J., “Acceptance Speech to the Democratic National Convention, Chicago, 29 August 1996,” Congressional Quarterly Weekly Report 54 (August 31, 1996), pp. 2485–89Google Scholar, at p. 2487. This is a recurring motif. A week earlier, when signing the act into law on August 22, 1996, President Clinton had referred to it as part of “America's basic bargain of providing opportunities and demanding in return responsibilities.”

36 Gingrich, Newt, Armey, Dick, and the House Republicans, Contract with America (New York: Times Books, 1994), p. 75Google Scholar.

37 See, generally, Atiyah, P. S., The Rise and Fall of Freedom of Contract (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1979)Google Scholar.

38 One such duty is the principle of tort law that providers have a duty of care toward those dependent upon them; see Atiyah, P. S., Accidents, Compensation and the Law, 3rd edition (London: Weidenfeld & Nicholson, 1980), ch. 3, sec. 1, pp. 6569Google Scholar. Also see the discussion of ultra vires in de Smith, Stanley and Brazier, Rodney, Constitutional and Administrative Law, 6th edition (Harmondsworth, Middlesex: Penguin, 1989), ch. 29Google Scholar.

39 In Whose Keeper? chs. 1–3, Alan Wolfe develops many of these themes.

40 Nozick, Robert, Anarchy, State & Utopia (Oxford: Blackwell, 1974), p. 160Google Scholar.

41 Williamson, Oliver E., The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting (New York: Free Press, 1985)Google Scholar.

42 Gilligan, Carol, In a Different Voice: Psychological Theory and Women's Development (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1982)Google Scholar.

43 Titmuss, Richard M., The Gift Relationship (London: Allen & Unwin, 1971)Google Scholar. Margalit, Avishai, The Decent Society (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1996)Google Scholar.

44 Goodin, Protecting the Vulnerable.

45 Cf. OECD, The Future of Social Protection, p. 30. Elsewhere I argue that reliance rather than promise is what grounds contractual obligations themselves; see Goodin, Protecting the Vulnerable, pp. 42–52.

46 Among whom he specifically mentioned “children and battered wives”; William J. Clinton, “Statement upon Signing H.R. 3734,”US Code, Congressional & Administrative News, 104th Congress—Second Session, 1996, vol. 5, pp. 2891–93, at pp. 2892–93.

47 Himmelfarb, Gertrude, The De-Moralization of Society: From Victorian Values to Modern Values (New York: Knopf, 1994)Google Scholar.

48 Tocqueville, “Memoir on Pauperism,” p. 113 (punctuation modernized). See further Himmelfarb, The Idea of Poverty, ch. 6.

49 Beveridge, William H., Social Insurance and Allied Services, Cmnd. 6404 (London: HMSO, 1942)Google Scholar. Glennerster, British Social Policy since 1945, chs. 2–3. Atkinson, A. B., Incomes and the Welfare State (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), pt. 3Google Scholar, esp. chs. 12, 15. Atkinson, A. B., “The Case for a Participation Income,” Political Quarterly 67 (1996), pp. 6770CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at p. 68.

50 Bane and Ellwood, Welfare Realities. King, Desmond, Actively Seeking Work? The Politics of Unemployment Policy in the United States and Great Britain (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995)Google Scholar. Rothstein, Bo, The Social Democratic State: The Swedish Model and the Bureaucratic Problem of Social Reforms (Pittsburgh, Pa.: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1996), ch. 6Google Scholar.

51 Gouldner, Alvin W., “The Norm of Reciprocity,” American Sociological Review 25 (1960), pp. 161–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Homans, George C., Social Behaviour (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1961)Google Scholar. Walster, Elaine, Walster, G. William, Berscheid, Ellen, et al. , Equity: Theory and Research (Boston: Allyn & Bacon, 1978)Google Scholar.

52 Dean, Hartley and Taylor-Gooby, Peter, Dependency Culture: The Explosion of a Myth (Kernel Hempstead: Harvester-Wheatsheaf, 1992), pp. 183, 192, 195Google Scholar.

53 Feinberg, Joel, “The Nature and Value of Rights,” Journal of Value Inquiry 4 (1970), pp. 243–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

54 Marshall, T. H., “Citizenship and Social Class,” Class, Citizenship and Social Development (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1963), pp. 70134Google Scholar; cf. Mead, “Citizenship and Social Policy.”

55 Mead, Beyond Entitlement and “Citizenship and Social Policy.”

56 As was the interwar origin of maternity benefits and child allowances in Scandinavia, France, and Britain. See, respectively: Tilton, Timothy A., The Political Theory of Swedish Social Democracy (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990)Google Scholar, and Wolfe, Whose Keeper? ch. 5; Lenoir, Remi, “Family Policy in France since 1938,” in The French Welfare State, edited by Ambler, John S. (New York: New York University Press, 1991), pp. 144–86Google Scholar; and Pederson, S., “Gender, Welfare and Ctizenship in Britain during the Great War,” American Historical Review 95 (1990), pp. 9831006CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

57 A. B. Atkinson, Incomes and the Welfare State, ch. 15; Atkinson, , Public Economics in Action: The Basic Income/Flat Tax Proposal (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995)Google Scholar; and Atkinson, “The Case for a Participation Income.” This is in contrast to the case for absolutely unconditional basic income presented by, e.g., Van Parijs, Philippe, “Why Surfers Should be Fed: The Liberal Case for an Unconditional Basic Income,” Philosophy and Public Affairs 20 (1991), pp. 101–31Google Scholar.

58 Jahoda, Marie, Lazarsfeld, Paul F, and Zeisel, Hans, Marienthal: The Sociography of an Unemployed Community, trans, by the authors with Reginait, John and Elsaesser, Thomas (1933; Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1971)Google Scholar. Eisenberg, P. and Lazarsfeld, Paul, “The Psychological Effects of Unemployment,” Psychological Bulletin 35 (1938), pp. 358–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Jahoda, Marie, Employment and Unemployment: A Social-Psychological Analysis (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982)Google Scholar.

59 Rawls, A Theory of Justice, sec. 67.

60 Elster, Jon, “Self-Realization in Work and Politics: The Marxist Conception of the Good Life,” in Alternatives to Capitalism, edited by Elster, Jon and Moene, Karl Ove (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), pp. 127–58Google Scholar. Arneson, Richard J., “Is Work Special? Justice and the Distribution of Employment,” American Political Science Review 84 (1990), pp. 1127–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6I OECD, The Future of Social Protection, p. 25.

62 That is more true in some sorts of societies than others. Jerry Hart describes Texas during the boom of the early 1980s as a place “where money wasn't money, but just a means of keeping count”; quoted in Maraniss, David, “John Connally Loses It All,” in Washington Post National Weekly Edition 5 (January 25–31, 1988), p. 10Google Scholar. But, tellingly, slaves' sense of self-worth was tied to their market value even in antebellum Virginia: “A thousand-dollar slave felt superior to an eight-hundred-dollar slave,” reports Kenneth Stampp in his The Peculiar Institution (New York: Knopf, 1956), pp. 338–39Google Scholar.

63 Goodin, “The End of the Welfare State?”

64 AFDC (Aid to Families with Dependent Children) itself has now tellingly been relabeled “TANF”: Temporary Assistance for Needy Families.

65 Mead, Lawrence M., ed., The New Paternalism: Supervisory Approaches to Poverty (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1997)Google Scholar.

66 See, for example, the rhetorical question posed by Mead in Beyond Entitlement, p. 84: “Why should unwilling workers be bribed to work when many other Americans, not on welfare, do ‘dirty’ jobs every day?”

67 The participation wage will be means-tested indirectly, of course, insofar as it constitutes taxable income. But no one thinks that it is humiliating to have a low tax bill in the way that most people think it is humiliating to receive means-tested public assistance. Logically there may be no difference here, but psychologically there is; and it is the psychology that matters, insofar as people's self-esteem and consequent work effort are concerned.

68 Maine, Henry Sumner, Ancient Law, 17th edition (London: John Murray, 1901)Google Scholar.