Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-mwx4w Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-16T04:54:25.351Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The institutional roots of Great Britain's ‘big problem of small change’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 September 2009

GEORGE SELGIN*
Affiliation:
Terry College of Business, University of Georgia, Athens 30602, USA, Selgin@uga.edu
Get access

Abstract

Thomas Sargent and François Velde (2002) argue that it took government authorities centuries to solve the ‘big problem of small change’ because those authorities were constrained, first by the lack of a sound theory of small change, and then by the lack of adequate technology for implementing the theory. British experience suggests, however, that institutions also played a crucial part. In particular, the monopolistic nature of Great Britain's official coinage arrangements undermined incentives for establishing a sound system of small change even after theoretical and technological constraints were no longer present. The institutional perspective offered here helps to explain a number of historical facts that are otherwise puzzling, including the fact that a relatively successful private-sector small-change system anticipated Great Britain's official solution to the small-change problem by two decades.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © European Historical Economics Society 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anonymous. (1771). A letter to the Members of Parliament on the present state of the coinage. London.Google Scholar
Ashton, T. S. (1955). An Economic History of England: The 18th Century. New York: Barnes & Noble.Google Scholar
British Library (1788). Additional Manuscript 38421, f. 221.Google Scholar
Buttrick, J. (1952). The inside contract system. Journal of Economic History, 12 (3) (Summer), pp. 205–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlile, W. W. (1901). The Evolution of Modern Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Challis, C. E. (1989). The introduction of coinage machinery by Eloy Mestrell. British Numismatic Journal, 59, pp. 256–62.Google Scholar
Challis, C. E. (1992a). Lord Hastings and the Great Silver Recoinage. In Challis, C. E. (ed.), A New History of the Royal Mint. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 179397.Google Scholar
Challis, C. E. (ed.) (1992b). A New History of the Royal Mint. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cipolla, C. M. (1956). Money, Prices, and Civilization in the Mediterranean World, Fifth to Seventeenth Century. New York: Gordian Press.Google Scholar
Colquhoun, P. (1800). A Treatise on the Police of the Metropolis, 6th edn.London: H. Baldwin and Son.Google Scholar
Craig, J. (1953). The Mint: A History of the London Mint from AD 287 to 1948. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, K. (2001). The development of 16th century machine coining technology and the career of Eloye Mestrelle in England. The Journal of the Classical & Medieval Numismatic Society, 2 (3), pp. 111–27.Google Scholar
De Toqueville, A. (2000 [1840]). Democracy in America, vol. 2. Trans. Mansfield, Harvey C. and Winthrop, Delba. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, G. and Gasper, P. (1992). Reform, the new technology and Tower Hill, 1700-1966. In Challis, C. (ed.), A New History of the Royal Mint. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Great Britain, House of Commons (1849). Report of the commissioners appointed to inquire into the constitution, management, and expenses of the Royal Mint. Parliamentary Papers, 1026, vol. XXVIII.Google Scholar
Great Britain, House of Commons (1852). Copy of reports detailing the changes that have been made to the management of the Mint. British Parliamentary Papers, 76, vol. XXVIII.Google Scholar
Great Britain, Public Record Office (1787). PRO PC1/37/114 (December).Google Scholar
Grenfell, J. (1814). Observations on the Expediency and Facility of a Copper Coinage of Uniform Weight and a Standard Value etc. London: J. Asperne and J. Hatchard.Google Scholar
Griffiths, D. T. (2004). The big problem of forecasting small change. Applied Economics, 36, pp. 2195–207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, pp. 324–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, B. and Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal−agent analyses: incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7, pp. 2452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jevons, W. S. (1882). Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. New York: D. Appleton and Company.Google Scholar
Kellenbenz, H. (1974). Technology in the age of the scientific revolution, 1500–1700. In Cipolla, C. (ed.), The Fontana Economic History of Europe, vol. 2, pp. 177–272.Google Scholar
Maitland, J. (eighth Earl of Lauderdale) (1813). Further Considerations on the State of the Currency. Edinburgh: printed for A. Constable.Google Scholar
Mathias, P. (1979). The people's money in the eighteenth century: the Royal Mint, trade tokens and the economy. In Mathias, P., The Transformation of England: Essays in the Economic and Social History of England in the Eighteenth Century. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 190208.Google Scholar
Mayhew, H. (1967 [1851]). London Labour and the London Poor. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Mays, J. O'D. (1991). Tokens of Those Trying Times: A Social History of Britain's 18th Century Silver Tokens. Burley, Ringwood: New Forrest Leaves.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (1994). Progress and inertia in technological change. In James, J. and Thomas, M. (eds.), Capitalism in Context: Essays in Honor of R. M. Hartwell. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 230–54.Google Scholar
Moser, J. (1798). Thoughts on the provincial token coin. The European Magazine, 23. In three parts: I (March), pp. 153–6; II (April), pp. 232–8; and III (May), pp. 303–8.Google Scholar
Parente, S. L. and Prescott, E. C. (2000). Barriers to Riches. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pye, C. (1801). A Correct and Complete Representation of All the Provincial Copper Coins, Tokens of Trade, and cards of Address, on Copper etc. 2nd edn.Birmingham: R. Jabet et al.Google Scholar
Redish, A. (2000). Bimetallism: An Economic and Historical Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ruding, R. (1819). Annals of the Coinage of Britain and Its Dependencies, 2nd edn.London: Lackington, Hughes, Harding, Mavor and Jones.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. and Velde, F. (2002). The Big Problem of Small Change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selgin, G. (2003). Steam, hot air, and small change: Matthew Boulton and the reform of Britain's coinage. Economic History Review, 61 (3) (August), pp. 478509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selgin, G. (2008). Good Money: Birmingham Button Makers, the Royal Mint, and the Beginnings of Modern Coinage, 1775–1821. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press and the Independent Institute.Google Scholar
Selgin, G. and White, L. H. (1994). How would the invisible hand handle money? Journal of Economic Literature, 32 (December), pp. 1718–49.Google Scholar
Sharp, T. (1834). A Catalogue of Provincial Copper Coins, Tokens, Tickets, and Medalets. London: J. B. Nichols and Son.Google Scholar
Stone, K. (1974). The origins of job structure in the steel industry. Review of Radical Political Economics, 6 (Summer), pp. 113–73.Google Scholar
Sweeney, J. O. (1981). A Numismatic History of the Birmingham Mint. Birmingham: The Birmingham Mint.Google Scholar
Usher, A. P. (1943). The Early History of Deposit Banking in Mediterranean Europe. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Withers, P. and Withers, B. R. (1999). British Copper Tokens, 1811–1820. Llanfyllin, Powys: Galata Print.Google Scholar