Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-14T14:44:20.001Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

L'EFFETTO MANCATO DELLA RIFORMA MAGGIORITARIA: IL VOTO STRATEGICO

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2018

Extract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

La riforma elettorale tra speranze e scetticismo

Al tempo della campagna in favore dell'adozione del principio maggioritario di rappresentanza in Italia, la speranza di molti era che il nuovo sistema elettorale potesse produrre effetti simili a quelli delle democrazie anglosassoni cui intendeva ispirarsi, ossia che strutturasse la competizione partitica in termini bipolari – se non bipartitici – e favorisse quindi l'alternanza dei governi.

Sebbene siano trascorsi ormai più di tre anni da allora e, soprattutto, abbiano avuto luogo due elezioni, è ancora presto per dire se le nuove regole abbiano prodotto gli effetti desiderati. La transizione politica italiana è un processo ancora lontano dall'approdo finale e non consente ad oggi valutazioni definitive. Certo è che i sistemi elettorali introdotti nel 1993 sono stati caricati da molti di attese taumaturgiche, nonostante i moniti lanciati dal mondo scientifico sulla necessità di una modifica ben più incisiva dell'architettura istituzionale del sistema politico italiano. Qualunque sistema elettorale, infatti, costituisce di per sé solo una struttura di vincoli e di opportunità, dunque di vincoli più o meno stringenti e di opportunità che possono essere colte o meno. Inoltre, riguardo all'effettiva configurazione della normativa elettorale approvata dal Parlamento nell'agosto del 1993, la cautela sulle prospettive del cambiamento muoveva dalla considerazione che le nuove regole incarnavano entrambi i principi maggioritario (pur prevalente) e proporzionale di rappresentanza, quindi due logiche distinte di competizione e di voto sulla combinazione delle quali era difficile fare previsioni.

Summary

Summary

The goal of this essay is to investigate the existence of strategic voting in the electoral behaviour of Italian voters in both the 1994 and 1996 elections and its effects on the restructuring of the party system.

Strategic voting is a topic discussed in the literature for many years. In the context of the effects of electoral systems, the term strategic voting is normally used to describe the district-by-district phenomenon of third party supporters under the plurality rule voting for one of the two major parties. This is due to the tendency of such electoral systems to discourage voters from wasting their vote (minor parties are in fact sistematically underrepresented). As a consequence, «winner-takes-all» electoral laws tend to produce two-party systems, but only if the two major parties are the same in every constituency.

On this theoretical basis, the Italian electoral reforms of 1993 with the introduction of a predominantly majoritarian system were expected to offer new incentives toward strategic voting in the single-member districts and therefore toward a bipolarization of the party system, provided that the pattern of competition was the same nationwide. However, empirical tests based on district-level data show that strategic voting has not significantly occurred either in the 1994 or in the 1996 elections.

The heritage of the old proportional electoral system, a slow learning process of the new rules, the persistence of ideological voting and also the contradictory incentives deriving from the mixed proportional and majoritarian nature of the new electoral system (especially for the Senate) are all reasons for the lack of strategic voting.

Nevertheless, the Italian party system, emerging out of the electoral transition shows a bipolar tendency. In other words, party élites have successfully negotiated appropriate coalitions at the system level replacing the effects produced by strategic voting at the mass level.

Type
Elezioni Polltiche 1996
Copyright
Copyright © Societ Italiana di Scienza Politica 

References

Riferimenti bibliografici

Bartolini, S. e D'Alimonte, R. (a cura di) (1995), Maggioritario ma non troppo. Le elezioni politiche del 1994, Bologna, Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Bensel, R.F. e Sanders, M.E. (1979), The Effect of Electoral Rules on Voting Behavior: The Electoral College and Shift Voting, in «Public Choice», vol. 34, pp. 6985.Google Scholar
Black, J.H. (1978), The Multicandidate Calculus of Voting: Application to Canadian Elections, in «American Journal of Political Science», vol. 22, pp. 609638.Google Scholar
Blais, A. e Carty, R.K. (1991), The Psychological Impact of Electoral Laws: Measuring Duverger's Elusive Factor, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 21, pp. 7993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowler, S. e Lanoue, D.J. (1992), Strategic and Protest Voting for Third Parties: The Case of the Canadian NDP, in «Western Political Quarterly», vol. 45, pp. 485499.Google Scholar
Cain, B. (1978), Strategic Voting in Britain, in «American Journal of Political Science», vol. 22, pp. 639655.Google Scholar
Corbetta, P., Parisi, A. e Schadee, H. (1996), Elezioni in Italia. Struttura e tipologia delle consultazioni politiche, Bologna, Il Mulino, nuova edizione.Google Scholar
Cox, G.W. (1994), Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Nontransferable Vote, in «American Political Science Review», vol. 88, pp. 608621.Google Scholar
Cox, G.W. (1997), Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World's Electoral Systems, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, di prossima pubblicazione.Google Scholar
D'Alimonte, R. e Bartolini, S. (1995), Il sistema partitico italiano: una transizione difficile, in Bartolini e D'Alimonte, pp. 429466.Google Scholar
D'Alimonte, R. e Chiaramonte, A. (1993), Il nuovo sistema elettorale italiano: quali opportunità?, in «Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica», vol. 23, pp. 513547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, G.W. (1995), Il nuovo sistema elettorale italiano: le opportunità e le scelte, in Bartolini e D'Alimonte, pp. 3781.Google Scholar
Di Virgilio, A. (1995), Dai partiti ai poli: la politica delle alleanze, in Bartolini e D'Alimonte, pp. 177232.Google Scholar
Duverger, M. (1951), Les partis politiques, Paris, Colin; trad. it. I partiti politici, Milano, Comunità, 1970.Google Scholar
Duverger, M. (1986), Duverger's Law: Forty Years Later, in Grofman, B. e Lijphart, A. (a cura di), Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences, New York, Agathon Press inc., pp. 6984.Google Scholar
Evans, G. e Heath, A. (1993), A Tactical Error in the Analysis of Tactical Voting: A Response to Niemi, Whitten and Franklin, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 23, pp. 131137.Google Scholar
Farquharson, R. (1969), Theory of Voting, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Felsenthal, D.S. (1990), Topics in Social Choice. Sophisticated Voting, Efficacy, and Proportional Representation, New York-London, Praeger.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. e Fiorina, M. (1975), Closeness Counts Only in Horseshoes and Dancing, in «American Political Science Review», vol. 69, pp. 920925.Google Scholar
Franklin, M., Niemi, R. e Whitten, G. (1994), The Two Faces of Tactical Voting, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 24, pp. 549557.Google Scholar
Green, D.P. e Shapiro, I. (1994), Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory. A Critique of Application in Political Science, New Haven-London, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Grumm, J.G. (1958), Theories of Electoral Systems, in «Midwest Journal of Political Science», 2, pp. 357376.Google Scholar
Heath, A. e Evans, G. (1994), Tactical Voting: Concepts, Measurement and Findings, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 24, pp. 557661.Google Scholar
Niemi, R, M. Franklin e Whitten, G. (1992), Constituency Characteristics, Individual Characteristics and Tactical Voting in the 1987 British General Elections, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 22, pp. 229254.Google Scholar
Duverger, M. (1993), People Who Live in Glass Houses: A Response to Evans and Heath's Critique of our Note on Tactical Voting, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 23, pp. 549563.Google Scholar
Palfrey, T. (1989), A Mathematical Proof of Duverger's Law, in Ordershook, P.C. (a cura di), Models of Strategic Choice in Politics, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Rae, D.W. (1967, 19712), The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1982), The Two-Party System and Duverger's Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science, in «American Political Science Review», vol. 76, pp. 753766.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1986), The Art of Political Manipulation, New Haven-London, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1968), Political Development and Political Engineering, in Montgomery, J.D. e Hirschman, A.O. (a cura di), Public Policy, Cambridge, Harvard University Press, vol. XVII, pp. 261298; trad. it. Ingegneria politica e sistemi elettorali, in G. Sartori, Teoria dei partiti e caso italiano, Milano, Sugarco, 1982, pp. 97128.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1987), Sistemi elettorali, in G. Sartori, Elementi di teoria politica, Bologna, Il Mulino, pp. 237264.Google Scholar
Shively, W.P. (1970), The Elusive «Psychological Factor», in «Comparative Politics», vol. 3, pp. 115125.Google Scholar
Shugart, M.S. (1985), The Two Effects of District Magnitude: Venezuela as a Crucial Experiment, in «European Journal of Political Research», vol. 13, pp. 353364.Google Scholar
Spafford, D. (1972), Electoral Systems and Voters’ Behavior, in «Comparative Politics», vol. 5, pp. 129134.Google Scholar
Taagepera, R. e Shugart, M.S. (1989), Seats & Votes. The Effects and Determinants of Electoral Systems, New Haven-London, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. (1986), A General Model of Tactical and Inverse Tactical Voting, in «British Journal of Political Science», vol. 16, pp. 395404.Google Scholar