Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-2lccl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T04:57:39.431Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Political Economy of Customary Law in the Former British Territories of Africa

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2009

Extract

In assessing customary law two quite contradictory tendencies exist. Some approach customary law deferentially, even reverently. This constitutes “our” law. It expresses “our” values. We must nurture it. Others take precisely the opposite perception. Customary law constitutes the law of primitive tribes; we aim to become modern; ergo, we must do away with customary law. How to choose between these quite conflicting perspectives?

We argue that to understand customary law, we must understand its political economy, that is, the function it performs in existing socio-economic and political structures, particularly with respect to the class interests involved. We undertake here to put forward our understanding of the political economy of customary law in the English-speaking countries of Africa. To do that, we describe, first, the difficulties which require explanation and solution, that is, the poverty and vulnerability of the mass of Africa's people; second, for that poverty, we attempt an explanation, which takes the legal order as the manipulable variable; and, finally, we suggest briefly options for reform and change.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Oriental and African Studies 1984

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See generally Seidman, A., Comparative Development Strategies in East Africa (Nairobi, East African Publishing House, 1972) 53.Google Scholar

2 See generally Seidman, R. B., State, Law and Development (London, Croom-Helm, 1978)Google Scholar.

3 Dorner, P., “Needed Redirections in Economic Analysis for Agricultural Development Policy” in Domer, P. (ed.), Land Reform in Latin America (Madison, Wisconsin, Land Economics, 1972) 5.Google Scholar

4 Seidman, R. B., “A Note on the Construction of the Gold Coast Reception Statute.” 13 JAL 45 (1969)Google Scholar.

5 Gold Coast: Supreme Court Ordinance, 1876.

6 See generally Allott, A., Essays in African Law (London, Butterworth 1960) 197201Google Scholar.

7 Seidman, , supra n.-2, at 8487Google Scholar; Palmer, R., “The Agricultural History of Zimbabwe” in Palmer, R. and Parsons, Q. N. (eds), The Roots of Rural Poverty in Central and Southern Africa (London, Heinemann, 1977), 228Google Scholar.

8 Phimister, I., “Peasant Production and Underdevelopment in Southern Rhodesia, 1890–1914, with particular reference to Victoria Distant,” in Palmer and Parsons supra n. 8 at 221Google Scholar.

9 [To be supplied; in Palmer and Parsons, supra n. 8].

10 Proc No. 55 of 1910, sec. 14.

11 See generally Seidman, R. B., “The Individual in African Law: Zimbabwe's New Primary Courts”, paper delivered at a Conference on the Individual in African Law, Swaziland, 1981 and published in the Conference's ProceedingsGoogle Scholar.

12 See generally Seidman, R. B., “Rules of Recognition in the Primary Courts of Zimbabwe: On Lawyers' Reasoning and Customary Law”, 32 ICLQ 871 (1983)Google Scholar.

13 Alt. Gen for Nyasaland v Jackson, [1957] R and N.L.R. 443Google Scholar.

14 Asante, S. K. B., “Interests in Land in the Customary Law of Ghana: A New Appraisal”, 74 Yale L.J. 848 (1964)Google Scholar.

15 Seidman, supra n. 2.

16 Williams, D., “The Authoritarianism of African Legal Orders: A Review Article of Seidman, The State, Law and Development,” Contemporary Crises, (1980)Google Scholar.

17 Kidder, R. L., Connecting Law and Society: An Introduction to Research and Theory (Englewood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice-Hall, (1983), Ch. 6Google Scholar.