Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-16T00:15:18.618Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Storage Utilization in a Deficit Region

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

Wayne A. Boutwell
Affiliation:
Marketing Development Division, Economic Research Service, USDA
David E. Kenyon
Affiliation:
Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University
Get access

Extract

During the past two decades corn production has increased in the South Atlantic region defined as Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, and Georgia but not as rapidly as total U. S. production. The region accounted for 6.7 percent of the U. S. corn production in 1950 compared with 3.7 percent in 1970. During the same period soybean production has increased in the South Atlantic relative to other areas, accounting for 5.3 percent of U. S. production in 1970, up from 2.9 percent in 1950.

The major consumer of both corn and soybeans is the livestock industry. During the past twenty years this industry has expanded in the South Atlantic. In terms of grain consuming animal units (GCAU), the region accounted for 7.4 percent of U. S. production in 1953 compared with 9.1 percent in 1970. As a result the area is a deficit producer of both corn and soybeans, although with the relative increase of soybean production, the soybean deficit is expected to decrease.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 1973

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

[1]Boutwell, Wayne A., “Analysis of Storage in a Deficit Area,” Dissertation Manuscript, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Blacksburg.Google Scholar
[2]Brennen, M. J., “The Supply of Storage,” American Economic Review, Vol.48, No. 1, 1958.Google Scholar
[3]Hadley, G., Nonlinear and Dynamic Programming, Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley Publishing Co., 1964.Google Scholar
[4]International Business Machines Corporation, Data Processing Division, Mathematical System 360 Linear and Separable Programming - User's Manual, White Plains, New York, 1968.Google Scholar
[5]Samuelson, P. A., “Intertemporal Price Equilibrium: A Prologue to the Theory of Speculation,” Reprinted in Stiglitz, J. E., ed., The Collected Scientific Papers of P. A. Samuelson, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1966.Google Scholar
[6]Takayama, T. and Judge, G. G., “An Intertemporal Price Equilibrium Model,” Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 46, No. 2, 1964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7]Takayama, T., and Judge, G. G., “Spatial Equilibrium and Quadratic Programming,” Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 46, No. 1, 1964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]U. S. Department of Agriculture, Crop Production, Washington, D.C: Statistical Reporting Service, Crop Reporting Board, 1969.Google Scholar
[9]U. S. Department of Agriculture, Costs of Storing and Handling Grain in Commercial Elevators, 1964-1965, Pub. No. ERS-288, Washington, D.C.: Economic Research Service, April 1966.Google Scholar
[10]U. S. Department of Agriculture, Costs of Storing and Handling Grain in Commercial Elevators, Pub. No. ERS-288, Washington, D.C.: Economic Research Service, 1969.Google Scholar
[11]U. S. Department of Agriculture, Stocks of Grain, Washington, D.C.: Statistical Reporting Service.Google Scholar