Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-22dnz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T23:57:24.724Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Behavioral Economics, Happiness Surveys, and Public Policy1

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 May 2016

Abstract

Two important developments in recent policy analysis are behavioral economics and subjective-well-being (SWB) surveys. What is the connection between them? Some have suggested that behavioral economics strengthens the case for SWB surveys as a central policy tool, e.g., in the form of SWB-based cost-benefit analysis. This article reaches a different conclusion. Behavioral economics shows that individuals in their day-to-day, “System 1” behavior are not expected utility (EU-) rational – that they often fail to comply with the norms of rationality set forth by EU theory. Consider now that the standard preference-based view of individual well-being looks to individuals’ rational preferences. If the findings of behavioral economics are correct, an individual’s answer to a question such as “How satisfied are you with your life?” is not going to tell us much about her rational (EU-compliant) preferences. Behavioral economics, by highlighting widespread failures of EU rationality, might actually argue for an objective-good (non-preference-based) view of well-being. However (except in the limiting case of an objective-good view positing a single mentalistic good, happiness), SWB surveys will not be strong evidence of well-being in the objective-good sense. In short, SWB surveys are no “magic cure” for the genuine difficulties in inferring rational preferences and measuring well-being underscored by behavioral economics.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, Matthew D. (2012). Well-Being and Fair Distribution: Beyond Cost-Benefit Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. (2013). Happiness Surveys and Public Policy: What’s the Use? Duke Law Journal, 62, 15091601.Google Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. (2014). Extended Preferences and Interpersonal Comparisons. Economics and Philosophy, 30, 123162.Google Scholar
Adler, Matthew D., Dolan, Paul & Kavetsos, Georgios(2015). Would You Choose to Be Happy? Tradeoffs between Happiness and the Other Dimensions of Life in a Large Population Survey. CEP Discussion Paper No. 1366. http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/dp1366.pdf.Google Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth (1993). Value in Ethics and Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Anscombe, F. J. & Aumann, R. J. (1963). A Definition of Subjective Probability. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 34, 199205.Google Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony B. (2009). Economics as a Moral Science. Economica, 76, 791804.Google Scholar
Benjamin, Daniel J., Heffetz, Ori, Kimball, Miles S. & Rees-Jones, Alex (2012). What Do You Think Would Make You Happier? What Would You Choose? American Economic Review, 102, 20832110.Google Scholar
Benjamin, Daniel J., Heffetz, Ori, Kimball, Miles S. & Rees-Jones, Alex (2014). Can Marginal Rates of Substitution be Inferred from Happiness Data? Evidence from Residency Choices. American Economic Review, 104, 34983528.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas (2009). Behavioral Welfare Economics. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7, 267319.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas (2016). The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly: A Unified Approach to Behavioral Welfare Economics. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas & Rangel, Antonio (2009). Beyond Revealed Preference: Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 51104.Google Scholar
Beshears, John, Choi, James J., Laibson, David & Madrian, Brigitte C. (2008). How are Preferences Revealed? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 17871794.Google Scholar
Bronsteen, John, Buccafusco, Christopher & Masur, Jonathan S. (2015). Happiness and the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin F., Loewenstein, George & Rabin, Matthew(Eds.) (2004). Advances in Behavioral Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cartwright, Edward (2011). Behavioral Economics. New York, NY: Routledge.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj (2015). Behavioral Economics and Public Policy: A Pragmatic Perspective. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 105, 133.Google Scholar
Clark, Andrew E., Frijters, Paul & Shields, Michael (2008). Relative Income, Happiness, and Utility: An Explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and Other Puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 95144.Google Scholar
Clark, Andrew E., Senik, Claudia & Yamada, Katsunori(2015). When Experienced and Decision Utility Concur: The Case of Income Comparisons. IZA Discussion Paper No. 9189. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/114057.Google Scholar
Congdon, William J., Kling, Jeffrey R. & Mullainathan, Sendhil (2011). Policy and Choice: Public Finance through the Lens of Behavioral Economics. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
DellaVigna, Steffano (2009). Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315372.Google Scholar
Dolan, Paul & Kahneman, Daniel (2008). Interpretations of Utility and their Implications for the Valuation of Health. Economic Journal, 118, 215234.Google Scholar
Finnis, John (1988). Natural Law and Natural Rights. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Fujiwara, Daniel & Dolan, Paul (2016). Happiness-Based Policy Analysis. In Adler, Matthew D. & Fleurbaey, Marc (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Well-Being and Public Policy (pp. 286317). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gibbard, Allan (1990). Wise Choices, Apt Feelings: A Theory of Normative Judgment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak (2009). Theory of Decision Under Uncertainty. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak, Postlewaite, Andrew & Schmeidler, David (2012). Rationality of Belief: Or, Why Savage’s Axioms are Neither Necessary nor Sufficient for Rationality. Synthese, 187, 1131.Google Scholar
Graham, Carol (2016). Subjective Well-Being in Economics. In Adler, Matthew D. & Fleurbaey, Marc (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Well-Being and Public Policy (pp. 424450). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Griffin, James (1986). Well-Being: Its Meaning, Measurement, and Moral Importance. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Griffin, James (1997). Value Judgment: Improving Our Ethical Beliefs. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Jeffrey, Richard C. (1983). The Logic of Decision. (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Joyce, James M. (1999). The Foundations of Causal Decision Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Joyce, James M. (2004). Bayesianism. In Mele, Alfred R. & Rawling, Piers (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Rationality (pp. 132155). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel & Tversky, Amos(Eds.) (2000). Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Wakker, Peter, P. & Sarin, Rakesh (1997). Back to Bentham: Explorations of Experienced Utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 375405.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis & Shavell, Steven (2002). Fairness versus Welfare. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Keeney, Ralph L. & Raiffa, Howard (1993). Decisions with Multiple Objectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M. (1988). Notes on the Theory of Choice. Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Layard, Richard (2011). Happiness: Lessons from a New Science. (Revised edition). London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Machina, Mark (2014). Ambiguity Aversion with Three or More Outcomes. American Economic Review, 104, 38143840.Google Scholar
Madrian, Brigitte C. (2014). Applying Insights from Behavioral Economics to Policy Design. Annual Review of Economics, 6, 663688.Google Scholar
Mas-Collel, Andreu, Whinston, Michael D. & Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nozick, Robert (1974). Anarchy, State and Utopia. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha (2000). Women and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Perez-Truglia, Ricardo (2015). A Samuelsonian Validation Test for Happiness Data. Journal of Economic Psychology, 49, 7483.Google Scholar
Robinson, Lisa A. & Hammitt, James K. (2011). Behavioral Economics and the Conduct of Cost-Benefit Analysis: Towards Principles and Standards. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2, 151.Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. (1954). The Foundations of Statistics. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Sher, George (1997). Beyond Neutrality: Perfectionism and Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Strotz, R. H. (1956). Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization. Review of Economic Studies, 23, 165180.Google Scholar
Sumner, L. Wayne (1996). Welfare, Happiness, and Ethics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. (2016). Cost-Benefit Analysis: Who’s Your Daddy? Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis.Google Scholar
Temkin, Larry S. (2012). Rethinking the Good: Moral Ideals and the Nature of Practical Reasoning. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard & Sunstein, Cass (2009). Nudge. New York, NY: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos & Kahneman, Daniel (1988). Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions. In Bell, David E., Raiffa, Howard & Tversky, Amos (Eds.), Decision Making: Descriptive, Normative, and Prescriptive Interactions (pp. 167192). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos & Kahneman, Daniel (1992). Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297323.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip & Gayer, Ted (2016). Rational Benefit Assessment for an Irrational World. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis.Google Scholar
von Winterfeldt, D. & Edwards, W. (1986). Decision Analysis and Behavioral Research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar