Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-02T15:35:28.641Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Théorie des jeux et genèse des institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Bernard Walliser*
Affiliation:
École Nationale des Ponts et Chaussées, Paris
Get access

Résumé

Les institutions, conçues comme des entités collectives autonomes contribuant à la régulation du système socio-économique, ont été progressivement endogénéisées d’abord par la théorie économique, puis par la théorie des jeux. Elles ont pour rôle de résoudre des problèmes de coordination entre les agents, en particulier ceux qui découlent de l’absence, de la multiplicité ou de la non optimalité des équilibres spontanés. Pour ce faire, elles peuvent d’abord multiplier le nombre d’équilibres possibles, ensuite sélectionner l’un d’entre eux, en étant autant que possible auto-validées par les agents et non imposées de l’extérieur. Cependant, même si l’institution peut soutenir un équilibre spécifique, il faut rendre compte de sa genèse sinon par le pur raisonnement des agents, du moins par un processus d’apprentissage ou d'évolution.

Summary

Summary

Considered as autonomous collective entities contributing to the regulation of socio-economic system, institutions were progressively endogenized by economic theory and by game theory afterwards. Their rôle is to resolve agent’s coordination problems, which stem either from absence, multiplicity or non optimality of spontaneous equilibria. To this end, institutions extend the set of available equilibria first, then they select one of them, while remaining as much as possible selfvalidating and not externally compelling. However, although an institution can sustain a specific equilibrium, its concrete emergence has to be explained, if not by a pure reasoning of the agents, at least by a learning or an evolution process.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1989 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

BIBLIOGRAPHIE

Abreu, D. et Rubinstein, A. (1984), The Structure of Nash Equilibria in Repeated Games with Finite Automata, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Akerlop, G. (1984), An Economic Theorist’s Book of Tales, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. (1950), Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory, Journal of Political Economy, 53(3).Google Scholar
Arrow, K (1974), The Limits of Organization, Norton.Google Scholar
Aumann, R.J. et Sorin, S. (1989), Cooperation and Bounded Rationality, Games and Economic Behavior.Google Scholar
Aumann, R.J. (1987), Correlated Equilibrium as an Expression of Bayesian Rationality, Econometrica, 55(1), pp. 118, janvier.Google Scholar
Aumann, R.J. (1988), Irrationality in game theory, Mimeo, IMSS Summer Seminar on Economic Theory.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1986), An Evolutionary Approach to Norms, American Political Science Review, 80.Google Scholar
Backus, D. et Drifill, J. (1985), Rational Expectations et Policy Credibility following a Change in Regime, Review of Economic Studies, janvier.Google Scholar
Bardhan, P. (ed.) (1988), The Economic Theory of Agragarian Institutions, chap. 1, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. et Gordon, D.B. (1983), Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12.Google Scholar
Benoit, J. P. et Krishna, V. (1985), Finitely Repeated Games, Econometrica, 53(4), July.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B.D. (1986), Axiomatic Characterizations of Rational Choice in Strategic Environments, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 88(3).Google Scholar
Binmore, K.G. (1987–88), Modeling Rational Players, Economics and Philosophy, 3.Google Scholar
Bray, M. (1982), Learning, Estimation and the Stability of Rational Expectations, Journal of Economic Theory.Google Scholar
Buchanan, G. (1975), The Limits of Liberty, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, D. et Sowden, N. (eds.) (1985), Paradoxes of Rationality and Cooperation, University of British Columbia Press.Google Scholar
Chiappori, P.A. (1984), Sélection naturelle et rationalité absolue des entreprises, Revue Économique, 35(1).Google Scholar
Dupuy, J.P. (1988), Convention et Common Knowledge, Revue Économique, 40(2), mars.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1988), The Cement of Society, Mimeo, Université de Chicago.Google Scholar
Favereau, O. (1989), Marchés internes, marchés externes, Revue Économique, 40(2), mars.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D. et Maskin, E. (1986), The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or With Incomplete Information, Econometrica, 54(3).Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. (1986), Morals by Agreement, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gilbert, M. (1981), Game Theory and Convention, Synthèse, 46.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. (1975), Advances in Understanding Rational Behavior, in: Harsanyi, J. (ed.), Essays on Ethics, Social Behavior and Scientific Explanation, Reidel, 1976.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. (1987), The Tracing Procedure, a Self-correcting Reasoning Procedure, Theory and Decision, 23.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J. C. et Selten, R. (1988), A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1973–76–79), Law, Legislation and Liberty, Routledge et Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, L. (1972), On Informationally Decentralized Systems, in: Mcguire, D. et Radner, R. (eds.), Decision and Organization, North Holland.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, L. (1973), The Design of Mechanisms for Resource Allocation, American Economic Review, mai.Google Scholar
Kalai, E. (1988), Bounded Rationality and Strategic Complexity in Repeated Games, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Kalai, E. et Stanford, W. (1988), Finite Rationality and Interpersonal Complexity in Repeated Games, Econometrica, 56(2).Google Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1937), The General Theory of Employment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51.Google Scholar
Kraines, D. et Kraines, V. (1989), Pavlov and the Prisoner’s Dilemma, Theory and Decision, 26.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. et Wilson, R. (1982), Reputation and Imperfect Information, Journal of Economic Theory, 27.Google Scholar
Kreps, D., P. Milgrom, J. ROBERTS et Wilson, R. (1982), Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma, Journal of Economic Theory, 27.Google Scholar
Lesourne, J. (1985), Le marche et l’auto-organisation, Economie Appliquée, 38(34).Google Scholar
Lewis, D.K. (1965), Convention, a Philosophical Study, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Mc kelvey, R.D. (1988), Evolutionary Explanation of Rationality Paradoxes, Mimeo, IMSS Summer Seminar on Economic Theory.Google Scholar
Marx, K. (1859), A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, Londons.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. (1982), Evolution and the Theory of Games, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Megiddo, N. et Wigderson, A. (1986), On Plays by Means of Computing Machines, in: Halpern, J.Y. (ed.), Reasoning about Knowledge, Kaufman Publishers.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. et Roberts, J. (1982), Predation, Reputation and Entry Deterrence, Journal of Economic Theory, 27.Google Scholar
Muth, J. (1961), Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements, Econometrica, 29(4), July.Google Scholar
Nelson, P. et Winter, S. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Neyman, A. (1985), Bounded Rationality justifies Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner’s Dilema, Economic Letters, 19.Google Scholar
Novshek, W. et Sonnenschein, H. (1978), Cournot and Walras Equilibrium, Journal of Economic Theory, 19.Google Scholar
Nozick, R. (1974), Anarchy, State and Utopia, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Orlean, A. (1988), Contagion mimétique et bulles spéculatives, Mimeo, CREA.Google Scholar
Radner, R. (1980), Collusive Behavior in non Cooperative epsilon Equilibria in Oligopolies with Long but Finite Lives, Journal of Economic Theory, 22.Google Scholar
Radner, R. (1986), Can Bounded Rationality Resolve the Prisoner’s Dilemma?, in: Mas-Collel, A. et Hildenbrand, W. (eds.), Essays in Honour of Gerard Debreu, North Holland.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1955), Two Concepts of Rules, Philosophical Review, janvier.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, A. (1982), Games of Perfect Information, Predatory Pricing et the Chain-store Paradox, Journal of Economic Theory, 25.Google Scholar
Rubin, P. H. et Zerbe, R. O. (eds.) (1988), Evolutionary models in Economics and Law, vol. 4, JAI Press.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (1986), Finite Automata play the Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma, Journal of Economic Theory, 39.Google Scholar
Salais, R. et Thevenot, L. (eds.) (1968), The Strategy of Conflict, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schotter, A. (1981), The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schotter, A. (1983), Why Take a Game Theoretical Approach to Economics? Institutions, Economics and Game Theory, Economie Appliquée, 36(4).Google Scholar
Shubik, K. (1975), Mathematical Models for a Theory of Money and Financial Institutions, in: Day, R. et Groves, D. (eds.), Adaptive Economic Models, Academic Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1976), From Substantive to Procedural Rationality, in: Latsis, S. (ed.), Method and Appraisal in Economics, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smale, S. (1980), The Prisoner’s Dilemma and Dynamical Systems Associated to non-Cooperative Games, Econometrica, 48.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1989), Deliberational Dynamics, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Smith, A.C. (1976), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, trad.: Recherches sur la nature et les causes de la richesse des nations, Guillaumin.Google Scholar
Sudgen, R. (1986), The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare, Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Tan, T.C. et Werlang, S.R. (1988), The Bayesian Foundations of Solution Concepts of Games, Journal of Economic Theory, 45, août.Google Scholar
Taylor, M. (1987), The Possibility of Cooperation, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Thevenot, L. (ed.) (1985), Conventions économiques, CEE, Presses Universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Ullman-Margalit, E. (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Vanberg, V. (1986), Spontaneous Market Orders and Social Rules, Economics and Philosophy, 2.Google Scholar
Vega, F. (1988), Bayesian Boundedly Rational Agents Play the Finitely Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma, Mimeo, Université de Barcelone.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, J. et Morgenstern, O. (1944), Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, Princeton University Press, 1953.Google Scholar
Walliser, B. (1988), A simplified Taxonomy of 2 × 2 Games, Theory and Decision, 25.Google Scholar
Walliser, B. (1989), Instrumental Rationality and Cognitive Rationality, Theory and Decision.Google Scholar
Watkins, J. (1985), Self-interest and Morality, in: Campbell, R. et Sowden, L. (eds.), Paradoxes of Rationality et Cooperation, University of British Columbia Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies, Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, Free Press.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. (1988), Learning to Believe in Sunspots, Mimeo, Université de Chicago.Google Scholar