Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-03T16:07:37.641Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Technological Dimension of Decision Making: The Case of the Aswan High Dam

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Robert W. Rycroft
Affiliation:
Modernization, and International Studies Program, Graduate School of International Studies, University of Denver
Joseph S. Szyliowicz
Affiliation:
Modernization, and International Studies Program, Graduate School of International Studies, University of Denver
Get access

Abstract

This study examines the role of technological variables in the decisions by Egypt, the World Bank, and the United States regarding the selection and financing of the Aswan High Dam project. Three major decision-making models-rational choice, incremental, and organizational process-are assessed according to their appropriateness for and applicability to the “technological dimension.” This dimension is defined in terms of three major components-design, impact, and management issues. Despite a tendency of the literature to associate the rational-choice model with highly technical decisions, this study illustrates the dominance of “satisficing,” “muddling through,” and “bounded rationality” behavior for each of the major participants. The technological dimension is found to be important, but clearly secondary to the primacy of politics.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 1980

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See Nelkin, Dorothy, Technological Decisions and Democracy: European Experiments in Public Participation (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1977)Google Scholar, and Nelkin, , ed., Controversy: The Politics of Technical Decisions (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1979)Google Scholar, for works that explicitly address the internal dynamics of decisions with significant technological components.

2 See Basiuk, Victor, Technology, World Politics and American Policy (New York: Columbia University Press, 1977)Google Scholar, for an exception to this rule.

3 Zeckhauser, Richard and Schaefer, Elmer, “Public Policy and Normative Economic Theory,” in Bauer, Raymond A. and Gergen, Kenneth J., eds., The Study of Policy Formation (New York: Free Press, 1968), 27101.Google Scholar

4 See Conrad, Thomas, “Rationality and Political Science: A Critical Analysis of the Consumer-Choice Model,” Polity, 11 (Summer 1970), 479–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

5 Simon, , Administrative Behavior, 2d ed. (New York: Free Press, 1957), xxiii–xxvii.Google Scholar

6 March, James G. and Simon, Herbert A., Organizations (New York: Wiley, 1958)Google Scholar; Cyert, Richard M. and March, James G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1963).Google Scholar

7 Lindblom, , “The Science of Muddling Through,” Public Administration Review, XIX (Spring 1959), 7988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar In our discussion of models of decision making, we have avoided the use of the term “bureaucratic model” as a distinct approach because the works of such theorists as Simon and Lindblom often are included within a bureaucratic politics category. And, as this discussion illustrates, these are clearly different approaches to decision making. For a good case study in which different labels are attached to these models, see Allison, Graham T., Essence of Decision (Boston: Little, Brown, 1971).Google Scholar

8 Lindblom, Charles E., The Intelligence of Democracy: Decision-Making Through Mutual Adjustment (New York: Free Press, 1965)Google Scholar, and Lindblom, , The Policy Making Process (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1968).Google Scholar

9 See Dror, Yehezkel, “Muddling Through—‘Science’ or Inertia?Public Administration Review, XXIV (September 1964), 153–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10 See Baker, Robert F., Michaels, Richard M., and Preston, Everett S., Public Policy Development: Linking the Technical and Political Processes (New York: Wiley, 1975).Google Scholar

11 See Lindsay, Robert B., The Role of Science in Civilization (New York: Harper & Row, 1963). 224–34.Google Scholar

1 Waterbury, , Hydropolitics of the Nile Valley (Syracuse, N.Y.: Syracuse University Press, 1979), 4.Google Scholar

13 Braybrooke, David and Lindblom, Charles E., A Strategy of Decision (New York: Free Press, 1963), 78.Google Scholar

14 Bereano, Philip L., Technology as a Social and Political Phenomenon (New York: Wiley, 1976), 441.Google Scholar

15 Braybrooke and Lindblom (fn. 13), 126.

16 See Nelkin, Dorothy, “Technology and Public Policy,” in Spiegel-Rosing, Ina and Price, Derek de Solla, eds., Science, Technology and Society: A Cross-Disciplinary Perspective (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1977), 417–30.Google Scholar

17 Little, Tom, High Dam at Aswan: The Subjugation of the Nile (New York: John Day, 1965), 71.Google Scholar For details of the Hochtief-Egyptian relationship, we have relied upon data supplied by Mr. H. Graefe, Chief Engineer, Overseas Department, Hochtief Aktiengesellschaft, August 30, 1978, September 28, 1978, and November 8, 1978. We have supplemented these data with information contained in Wheelock, Keith, Nasser's New Egypt (London: Stevens and Sons, 1960), 179–80.Google Scholar

18 See Guarizon, Giorgio and others, “Management of the Aswan High Dam: Operational Considerations,” mimeo (Egyptian Academy of Science and Technology, 1978), 10Google Scholar; and Wheelock, (fn. 17), 179.Google Scholar

19 Little (fn. 17), 73.

20 This discussion relies on the correspondence with Hochtief, and on Little (fn. 17), 69–92, who emphasizes the role of the P.C.D.N.P. and Egyptian experts. See also Hatem, M. A., The High Dam and Its Effects (Cairo: Al Ahram al-Iktisadi, 1976), 78.Google Scholar

21 Mason, Edward S. and Asher, Robert E., The World Bank Since Bretton Woods (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1973), 629.Google Scholar

22 Ibid., 629–30.

23 Ibid., 632.

24 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, “Preliminary Report on the Sadd El-Aali Project,” I.B.R.D. Restricted Document, February 28, 1956, p. i.Google Scholar See also International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, “Egypt—Sadd El-Aali (High Dam) Project,” I.B.R.D. Confidential Document, December 16, 1955, p. 2.Google Scholar

25 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Policies and Operations: The World Bank, IDA and IFC (Washington, D.C.: World Bank Headquarters, 1971), 33.Google Scholar See also King, John R. Jr,, Economic Development Projects and Their Appraisal: Cases and Principles from the Experience of the World Bank (Baltimore, Md.: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1967), 45.Google Scholar

26 “Preliminary Report …” (fn. 24), 72.

27 Little (fn. 17), 77–78.

28 “Preliminary Report …” (fn. 24), i–iii.

29 Brown, Waldo G., “Construction Begins on Aswan—Russian Style,” Engineering News-Record, Vol. 166 (February 23, 1961), 3234.Google Scholar See also Selim, Mohamed A., “A Basic Step Towards Full Utilization of the River Nile,” Civil Engineering, XXVIII (August 1958), 5657.Google Scholar

30 Personal communication from H. Graefe, November 8, 1978.

31 These benefits are based on data contained in Shibl, Yusuf A., The Aswan High Dam: Benefit and Cost Analysis (Beirut: Arab Institute for Research and Publishing, 1971), 4850Google Scholar; Waterbury, John, “The Nile Stops at Aswan, Part III: Domestic Hydro-politics,” American Universities Field Staff, North African Series, XXII (No. 3, 1977), 23Google Scholar; Le Haut Barrage (Cairo: Ministère de la Culture, 1972), 46–49. See also Sabban, Gamil El, “The Aswan High Dam,” Middle Eastern Affairs, VI (December 1955), 383–89.Google Scholar

32 Mabro, Robert, The Egyptian Economy, 1952–1972 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1974), 101Google Scholar; Waterbury, (fn. 31), 18; Shibl (fn. 31), 5366.Google Scholar

33 See al-Barawy, Rashed, Economic Development in the United Arab Republic (Egypt) (Cairo: Anglo-Egyptian Bookshop, 1970), 8790.Google Scholar

34 Waterbury, John, “The Nile Stops at Aswan, Part II: International Hydropolitics,” American Universities Field Staff, North African Series, XXII (No. 2, 1977), 11.Google Scholar See also Mabro (fn. 32), 88.

35 “Preliminary Report …” (fn. 24), 38–42.

36 Ibid., 66.

37 Mason, and Asher, (fn. 21), 235–59Google Scholar; King, (fn. 25), 58.Google Scholar

38 Mason, and Asher, (fn. 21), 259.Google Scholar See also Hirschman, Albert O., Development Projects Observed (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1967), 1517.Google Scholar

39 Kinawy, Ibrahim Z. and Shenouda, William K., “Ecological, Social and Economic Impacts of Damming the Nile at Aswan,” paper presented at a Special Session on Environmental Control for Irrigation, Drainage, and Flood Control Projects of the International Commission on Irrigation and Drainage (Moscow, 1975), 291.Google Scholar See also Benedick, Richard E., “The High Dam and the Transformation of the Nile,” Middle East Journal, XXXIII (Spring 1979), 136–37.Google Scholar

40 Waterbury, (fn. 31), 812.Google Scholar

41 Waterbury, (fn. 31), 22Google Scholar; Benedick, (fn. 39), 138Google Scholar; Kinawy, and Shenouda, (fn. 39), 289.Google Scholar

42 Kinawy, and Shenouda, (fn. 39), 279.Google Scholar

43 Benedick, (fn. 39), 135.Google Scholar

44 Waterbury, (fn. 31), 14.Google Scholar

45 “The High Dam or the Final Round,” Egyptian Economic and Political Review. IV (January 1956), 33–45, and “The High Dam,” Egyptian Economic and Political Review, VI (October 1958), 24–30.

46 Kinawy, and Shenouda, (fn. 39), 279–81.Google Scholar

47 Rabie, Mohammed A., “The Impact of the Aswan High Dam on the Economic Development of the UAR,” Ph.D. diss. (Department of Economics, University of Houston, 1970), 110–12.Google Scholar

48 Mason and Asher (fn. 21), 635.

49 On Nasser's reaction to the Western offer and his subsequent discussions with Black, see “Nasser's Narrow Path,” The Economist, Vol. 178 (February 18, 1956), 455.

50 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, The Economic Development of Egypt, I.B.R.D. Restricted Document, August 25, 1955, ii–iv.Google Scholar

51 “Preliminary Report …” (fn. 24), 66.

52 Dougherty, James E., “The Aswan Decision in Perspective,” Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 74 (March 1959), 38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

53 Berkowitz, Morton, Bock, P. G., and Fuccillo, Vincent J., The Politics of American Foreign Policy: The Social Context of Decisions (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1977), 88.Google Scholar

54 Alix Fathy, quoted in Waterbury, John, “The Nile Stops at Aswan, Part I: The Development of the Nile River System,” American Universities Field Staff, North African Series, XXII (No. 1, 1977), 1.Google Scholar

55 See Baldwin, David A., “The International Bank in Political Perspective,” World Politics, XVIII (October 1965), 69.Google Scholar

56 See Allison (fn. 7).

57 Mason, and Asher, (fn. 21), 641–42.Google Scholar

58 Barber, James D., The Presidential Character: Predicting Performance in the White House (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1972), 13Google Scholar, and Barber, , “The Interplay of Presidential Character and Style: A Paradigm and Five Illustrations,” in Wildavsky, Aaron, ed., Perspectives on the Presidency (Boston: Little, Brown, 1975), 80.Google Scholar

59 See Holsti, Ole R., “Cognitive Dynamics and Images of the Enemy,” Journal of International Affairs, XXI (No. 1, 1967), 1639Google Scholar; Finer, Herman, Dulles Over Suez (Chicago: Quadrangle Books, 1964).Google Scholar

60 Waterbury, (fn. 12), 119–25.Google Scholar

61 Hirschman, (fn. 38), 18.Google Scholar