Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-qxdb6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T16:02:03.265Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Balancing between competition and regulation in healthcare markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 December 2023

Maria Trottmann*
Affiliation:
Department of Health Services Research, SWICA, 8401 Winterthur, Switzerland
Piet Stam
Affiliation:
School of Business and Economics, Ethics, Governance and Society, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands Equalis Strategy & Modeling B.V., Utrecht, The Netherlands
Johan Visser
Affiliation:
Zorginstituut Nederland, 1112 ZA, Diemen, The Netherlands
Shuli Brammli-Greenberg
Affiliation:
Braun School of Public Health Faculty of Medicine, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Jerusalem, Israel
*
Corresponding author: Maria Trottmann; Email: maria.trottmann@swica.ch
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Systems of managed competition naturally seek the middle ground between competition and regulation. This debate essay makes the case for adjusting the level of regulation according to the characteristics of the submarket in question. We first develop a theoretical framework that can be used to identify the services in which relatively free competition will be beneficial. The framework is grounded in the economic literature and consists of eight criteria. Targeted regulatory tools are then discussed that can be used to structure submarkets in which these criteria are not (fully) met. Applying this framework and targeted interventions, regulators gain the flexibility to react to potential market failures, without foregoing the benefits of managed competition where it works well. This analysis is highly relevant for countries in transition to managed competition. Regulators can identify potential failure in submarkets for medical services, and apply the necessary regulatory tools to prepare for a smooth transition.

Type
Debate Essay
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Even in countries with relatively free market economies, the debate over the desirable level of competition in healthcare markets is far from settled. Proponents of competitive healthcare systems usually stress the advantages of innovation (in processes and in technology) and of responsiveness to consumer preferences. They also claim that centrally planned healthcare systems are inefficient, in the sense that too little service is produced for a given budget, and the types of services provided may be those preferred by central planners rather than consumers (van de Ven, Reference Van de Ven1996). In contrast, critics of competition stress that there are specific features of the healthcare market (especially information asymmetries) which make it susceptible to rent seeking, supplier-induced demand and reward risk selection. Moreover, price setting is usually not competitive nor is there free entry and exit in healthcare, which can lead to duplication of infrastructure and inefficient resource allocation (e.g. the concentration of providers in more lucrative services, rather than where they are most needed). If moral hazard on the consumer and provider sides cannot be curbed, competition may also lead to the excess provision of services, with focus on more profitable types of services which are provided to the wealthiest patients.

The health economics literature has shown that both sides of the argument have merit. Based on an extensive analysis of the literature on competition among healthcare providers, the European Commission Expert Panel on Effective Ways of Investing in Health (EXPH) came to the following conclusion:

Neither economic theory nor empirical evidence support the conclusion that competition should be promoted for all health services. As a result, policy makers need to think carefully about where, when and how to introduce or increase competition. (Barros et al., Reference Barros, Brouwer, Thomson and Varkevisser2016: 231, first paragraph)

In what follows, we provide a framework for ‘thinking carefully’ about this issue. The proposed framework is intended to help regulators identify medical services that are most suited to competition and those in which competition might cause the system to underperform.

The analysis is tailored to systems with managed competition in social health insurance (Enthoven, Reference Enthoven1978a, Reference Enthoven1978b). Central characteristics of managed competition include the following elements: (i) governments mandate insurance coverage for a ‘basic’ basket of medical services, (ii) citizens make periodic choices among health insurers, (iii) individual insurers are primarily responsible for delivering or purchasing care and (iv) providers compete for patients as well as for contracts with insurers (Van de Ven et al., Reference Van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Schokkaert, Schut, Shmueli and Wasem2013). The rationale of this arrangement is to stimulate insurers and providers to improve efficiency in healthcare production and to respond to consumer's preferences (van de Ven et al., Reference van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Chernichovsky, Gardiol, Holly, Lamers, Schokkaert, Shmueli, Spycher, Van de Voorde, Van Vliet, Wasem and Zmora2003). Nonetheless, this broad definition of managed competition includes arrangements in which insurance and service delivery are fully integrated as well as arrangements where health care purchasing is done by individual insurers (also termed ‘selective contracting’). This is not without controversy, especially in European countries where insurers traditionally have been much more passive, submitting themselves to collective agreements between insurers' and providers' associations, accompanied by extensive government regulation of prices, quantities and budgets (Shmueli et al., Reference Shmueli, Stam, Wasem and Trottmann2015).

Careful regulation is necessary to avoid the well-known problems of risk selection and service-level distortion. Van de Ven et al. (Reference Van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Schokkaert, Schut, Shmueli and Wasem2013) and Henriquez et al. (Reference Henriquez, Van de Ven, Paolucci, Armstrong and Melia2022) identify preconditions that must be fulfilled to a satisfactory degree for managed competition to lead to efficient and affordable care for all citizens. Their analysis applies to the market for social health insurance as a whole (i.e. all services that are a part of the basic benefit package), and it has been used as a blueprint for health reform in many countries. In this debate essay, we argue that regulators should extend their analysis to a more detailed level: even within a legal setting that generally fulfils the preconditions, specific submarkets might be identified for which the competitive system can be expected to underperform. We propose a framework to identify such submarkets, and we suggest specific regulatory tools to target these issues. Applying such tools gives regulators additional flexibility to fine tune the balance between competition and regulation.Footnote 1 Such regulatory tools are widely used in practice (McGuire and van Kleef, Reference McGuire and van Kleef2018), but have been less discussed in the literature.

The paper is structured as follows: In section 2, we develop a theoretical framework that can be used to identify the services in which relatively free competition will be beneficial. In section 3, we discuss additional regulatory tools that can be used to structure submarkets. Section 4 includes the limitations and section 5 concludes.

2. The framework

The core of the proposed conceptual framework is grounded in the rich literature on competition in markets for health insurance and healthcare services (Arrow, Reference Arrow1963; Enthoven, Reference Enthoven1986; Gaynor and Town, Reference Gaynor and Town2011; Van de Ven et al., Reference Van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Schokkaert, Schut, Shmueli and Wasem2013; Barros et al., Reference Barros, Brouwer, Thomson and Varkevisser2016; McGuire and van Kleef, Reference McGuire and van Kleef2018).

Broadly speaking, the framework consists of eight criteria for identifying services in which competition will be beneficial, which are grouped into the following five main categories:

  • C 1–2: Multiple competing providers;

  • C 3: Limited incentives for risk selection by insurers;

  • C 4–5: Consumer information on providers and insurers is ‘sufficient’, such that a ‘large enough’ proportion of consumers make trade-offs between price and quality;

  • C 6: Externalities;

  • C 7–8: Insurer and provider markets are characterised by non-increasing returns to scale/scope.

We now describe the eight criteria in detail, though not necessarily in order of importance.

  • C 1: Sufficient patient numbers to sustain multiple providers in a relevant geographic area

Competition relies on the availability of multiple buyers and sellers. This criterion might not be fulfilled in the case of specialised medical services used by a small number of patients. This problem of small numbers is worsened for services with high fixed costs and those that require specialised knowledge, because then the efficient patient volume per provider organisation is larger (EXPH, 2015). For example, it has been repeatedly shown that in the case of complex surgical procedures, quality improves with patient volume per operating team (Institute of Medicine, 2000).

Another relevant factor is the geographic area in which providers can be regarded as competitors. This geographic area is smaller the smaller patient willingness/ability to travel is.

  • C 2: Sufficient numbers of competitors in the provider market

Without a sufficient number of competitors in the provider market, selective contracting is not possible. In this situation, purchasing negotiations by individual insurers might lead to less efficient outcomes than collective negotiations (possibly by government agencies).

There are different reasons why (quasi-)monopolistic provider markets exist. First, patent laws might be in place to incentivise private sector investment. This typically applies to pharmaceuticals and medical products. Second, shortages of trained specialists combined with limited education opportunities or strict professional licensing can lead to substantial market power of providers. Third, historically grown strong market positions, for example, by public hospitals, can be difficult to change.

  • C 3: Limited incentives for risk selection by insurers

It has long been known that competitive health insurance markets are prone to adverse selection by consumers and/or risk selection by insurers (Van de Ven and Ellis, Reference Van de Ven and Ellis2000). Adverse selection can lead to situations in which a competitive equilibrium in the insurance market either doesn't exist (‘death spirals’) or some consumers cannot obtain the coverage they want (Rothshild and Stiglitz, Reference Rothshild and Stiglitz1976; Newhouse, Reference Newhouse1996; Cutler and Reber, Reference Cutler and Reber1998). Risk selection activities by insurers lead to an inefficient allocation of resources for at least three reasons:

Within systems of managed competition, strong incentives for risk selection in the insurance market also have negative implications for medical providers. First, insurers might design remuneration schemes that pass on these incentives to providers (such as strict capitation with insufficient risk adjustment). Second, providers with the best reputation for treating unprofitable patient groups might not be contracted, reducing the incentives to acquire such a reputation (van de Ven et al., Reference van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Chernichovsky, Gardiol, Holly, Lamers, Schokkaert, Shmueli, Spycher, Van de Voorde, Van Vliet, Wasem and Zmora2003).

  • C 4: Public information on quality and cost

Many theorists have stressed the importance of available information on insurer and provider quality in order to achieve effective competition (Van de Ven et al., Reference Van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Schokkaert, Schut, Shmueli and Wasem2013). Information must be relevant (in the sense that they tell people what they need to know), valid, reliable, objective, transparent and easily understandable. Introducing purchaser competition without providing the population with sufficient information on quality may lead to substantial problems of quality stinting (Hibbard et al., Reference Hibbard, Slovic and Jewett1997). The EXPH raised the important point that providing meaningful information on provider quality that will facilitate the comparison among competitors is not always feasible, even under the premise that legal and technical issues (such as data protection) can be resolved (EXPH, 2015).

  • C 5: Sufficient demand-side pressure to refrain from quality stinting

It is the promise of managed competition that people's opportunity to vote with their feet will create enough demand-side pressure for insurers to refrain from quality stinting (if incentives for risk selection are limited and sufficient information is available). Van de Ven and Schut raise the important question whether demand-side pressure is sufficient for all types of care (Van de Ven and Schut, Reference Van de Ven and Schut1994). The authors present two potential reasons for low demand-side pressure: first, when choosing an insurance contract, a large proportion of enrolees may be indifferent to the quality of a specific service if their own probability in using that service during the contract period is close to zero. For example, only a small number of consumers might look for specific quality measures concerning services to those with severe mental disorders. Second, the typical service user might not be in a strong position to calculate trade-offs between prices and quality or to articulate his/her preferences. The second argument by Van de Ven and Schut (Reference Van de Ven and Schut1994) is certainly more controversial, and it is probably only relevant in combination with the first argument: if a service is used by a relatively small patient group, and this group – for whatever reason – is particularly vulnerable to quality stinting, targeted interventions might be warranted to protect these patients.

  • C 6: Limited influence of externalities

Medical care has benefits that don't necessarily accrue to the health insurer who finances them.Footnote 2 This holds for various reasons. First, since conventional risk adjustment allocates funds among insurers according to current or past year population health status, it does not (fully) reward preventive efforts that improve population health, even if those efforts are cost saving for society as a whole (Eggleston et al., Reference Eggleston, Ellis and Lu2012). Second, regulation usually purports 1-year contract periods and open enrolment, so investments in patients' long-term compliance or self-management skills might benefit a competitor (Zweifel and Breuer, Reference Zweifel and Breuer2006). Third, investments in health influence future earning capacities (Powell and Seabury, Reference Powell and Seabury2018; Goodman-Bacon, Reference Goodman-Bacon2021). By designing the basic benefit package, regulators can rule out the most severe forms of underinvestment in services with positive externalities. Still, additional interventions might be warranted to incite sufficient investments by competing insurers.

  • C 7: No need for substantial reserve capacity

If there is a good that provides benefits to individuals even if they do not consume it, economists refer to it as an ‘option good’ (Breyer et al., Reference Breyer, Zweifel and Kifmann2013). Medical infrastructure for treating patients can be viewed as such a good. As long as demand is predictable for an enrolee population as a whole, infrastructure can be adjusted to expected demand, and competitive purchasing should lead to sufficient provision. However, if demand is unpredictable even for large populations, some capacity must be left idle, which generates extra costs (Lovell et al., Reference Lovell, Rodríguez-Álvarez and Wall2009; Widmer et al., Reference Widmer, Trottmann and Zweifel2018). Governments might choose to pool this extra cost over the whole population, for two main reasons: first, for urgent services, it is unfeasible to refuse treatment to patients on the ground that their insurer didn't contribute sufficiently to capacity building, which creates a free-rider problem. Second, pooling the risk over the whole population might simply be the least expensive way of risk pooling.

  • C 8: No strong complementarity with other collective goods

In his seminal paper on the principle of fiscal equivalence, Olson discusses which type of government or institution should perform activities that require collective action (Olson, Reference Olson1969). He argues that there should be a separate governmental institution for every collective good that has a unique boundary, in order to achieve a match between those who benefit from the good and those who pay for it (‘fiscal equivalence’). This generally supports the delegation of healthcare purchasing to health insurers, as the premiums paid for health care services are transparent and not mingled with general taxation. Olsen then argues that this conclusion only holds if complementarity with other goods is not overly strong, in the sense that if the government provides one collective good then it cannot provide a second one at a lower cost. This caveat is relevant in the case of basic health insurance since some healthcare services (e.g. long-term care, mental healthcare, preventive medicine and vaccinations) are closely related to social care, which is typically provided by local authorities. If the complementarity between these services is strong, then it is doubtful that having a separate government entity purchase each of them is an optimal setup.

3. Applications of the framework within managed-competition type health care systems

A simplified picture of the managed-competition model is depicted in Figure 1. The solid lines represent the core pillars of the managed competition model. The regulator defines a standardised basket of benefits, which all insurers must offer and all citizens must purchase. Insurers are obliged to accept all applicants (open enrolment) and to charge all enrolees the same premium for the same coverage (community rating). A system of risk adjustment is in place to mitigate incentives for risk selection. Insurers take an active role in purchasing or delivering care. They either contract with providers or negotiate the content of contracts (e.g. prices, quality, capacity and services), or reduce contracting costs by internalising them through vertical integration (Van de Ven et al., Reference Van de Ven, Beck, Buchner, Schokkaert, Schut, Shmueli and Wasem2013).

Figure 1. The managed competition model (solid line) and additional regulatory tools (dashed line).

Within a system of managed competition, the regulator has a broad set of additional regulatory tools with which to organise the market (McGuire and van Kleef, Reference McGuire and van Kleef2018). These additional regulatory tools can be applied to the market as a whole, or to specific submarkets. They give the regulator the flexibility to fine tune the balance between competition and regulation, and to react to potential market failures related to specific types of care.

The dashed lines in Figure 1 represent such regulatory tools, which can be grouped into four categories. We discuss the four categories together with real-world examples, and argue why these tools are needed based upon our framework. These examples are provided in an anecdotic style and serve to illustrate potential future applications of the framework. It is beyond the scope of this short essay to thoroughly analyse each submarket in various countries, and assess the extent to which the criteria are fulfilled.

3.1 Carve-outs

If services are ‘carved out’ of the regular insurance contract, governments or local authorities take on the role of the insurer and either provide services themselves or purchase them from private providers. In the latter case, the result is a small number of providers (local monopolies). Providers might still compete for the market in periodic tenders, or be compared to similar providers which puts them under quasi-competitive pressure (known as yardstick regulation; Shleifer, Reference Shleifer1985).

Examples

In the Netherlands, the state directly provides and finances mental health care for convicted criminal offenders (van der Wolf, Reference van der Wolf2021). This carve-out can be related to several criteria in our framework. First, this type of care isn't at the forefront of attention for most consumers when choosing an insurer, so competing insurers might experience limited demand-side pressure to refrain from quality stinting (C5). Second, this type of care has strong positive externalities for public safety and social reintegration (C6). Third, integrating this type of care with other services that the state offers might create efficiency gains (C8).

In the US, Medicaid agencies in some states carve out treatment for substance use disorder (SUD) from the main insurance contract. The state then directly contracts and finances SUD services, while other Medicaid services are delivered by competing managed care organisations who receive capitated payments (Auty et al., Reference Auty, Cole and Wallace2022). This carve-out is related to the fact that it is very difficult to find good risk adjustors for SUD treatment, so incentives for risk selection can't be sufficiently neutralised (C3). SUD treatment also has strong positive externalities for public safety and social reintegration (C6). In addition, there is a shortage of SUD treatment facilities in many areas, which questions the effectiveness of selective contracting by competing managed care organisations (C2).

3.2 Ex-post risk sharing (i.e. eliminating or limiting financial risk for insurers)

Ex-post risk sharing reduces the financial responsibility of insurers. Insurers are responsible for providing or contracting a service, but they are entitled to targeted ex-post compensation for volume.

Examples

In the Netherlands, there exists a risk-sharing arrangement in the form of individual-level cost-based compensations for 90 per cent of annual mental healthcare spending equal to and above a certain threshold. The threshold is set at a national level such that the risk-sharing pool consists of 0.5 per cent of those individuals with highest mental healthcare expenditures. Risk sharing was introduced in 2020, because mental healthcare clients with very high costs were substantially and structurally undercompensated despite ex-ante risk equalisation. The main policy benefit of cost-based compensation is to reduce insurers' exposure to cost risk and to mitigate incentives to discriminate against persons with severe mental disorders (McGuire et al., Reference McGuire, van Kleef and van Veen2020). This is related to C3 in the framework.

In Germany, 80 per cent of an annual expenditure above 100,000 euros per person is reimbursed ex-post from a high-risk pool (McGuire et al., Reference McGuire, Schillo and van Kleef2021). Ex-post risk sharing is mainly a way to reduce incentives for risk selection against this subgroup with exceptional health care expenditures (C3 in our framework). Even though Germany had introduced an elaborate, morbidity-based risk adjustment scheme in 2009, substantial underpayments were observed for a small group of very high spenders. This incited regulators and health policy advisers to seek out alternative arrangements, such as ex-post risk pooling (Schillo et al., Reference Schillo, Lux, Wasem and Buchner2016).

3.3 Regulation of contracts

Contracts between insurers and providers play a central role in the managed competition model. Apart from insurer-owned facilities, contracts are the main way in which insurers can adjust healthcare provision, with the goal of ensuring the desired balance between quality and cost. Governments often regulate contracts for such medical services by defining acceptable ranges for prices, quantities or terms of provision.

Examples

In the Dutch hospital sector, services are defined by a standardised classification system (diagnosis/treatment combinations). The regulator collects and publishes benchmarking data based on this system (Krabbe-Alkemade et al., Reference Krabbe-Alkemade, Groot and Lindeboom2017). Similarly, Swiss regulation purports the use of a standardised, DRG-based catalogue for paying inpatient care in hospitals. A governmental agency collects and publishes data based on this schedule (Widmer et al., Reference Widmer, Trottmann and Zweifel2018). These interventions can be seen as a way to improve information on quality and cost (C4).

3.4 Collective bargaining

For a specific set of services, governments may restrict the insurers' freedom to contract selectively. Insurers will still reimburse providers, but subject to a specific set of rules negotiated collectively by the insurers or by government agencies.

Examples

Prime examples are the prices for brand name drugs, which are often negotiated by a government agency (as in e.g. the Netherlands, Switzerland and Israel). Without sufficient competition among providers, selective contracting by individual insurers is unlikely to be more efficient than purchasing by the state, who as more bargaining power. This corresponds to C2 in our framework.

3.5 Government involvement in the provider market

Governments may also play an active role in the provider market, either as the owners of medical facilities, or by contracting out specific services. In these cases, health insurers might reimburse medical facilities, but they are not responsible for delivering or purchasing care.

Examples

Many Swiss hospitals are owned by cantons (states) and they must be contracted by all insurers. Using our framework, state involvement in the provider market can be justified for specific types of services. First, demand for some highly specialised hospital services might be too small to sustain several competing providers. If there is only one monopolistic provider, public ownership or strict public oversight is necessary to avoid abuses of market power (C1). Second, some specific services require sizeable reserve capacity, which is underprovided in competitive settings (C7). Examples could be preparedness for mass casualty incidences, especially those with multiple burn insured patients (Hughes et al., Reference Hughes, Almeland, Leclerc, Ogura, Hayashi, Mills, Norton and Potokar2021). Another example is emergency care in the case of pandemics. During the 2020/2021 surge of COVID-19, many governments centralised capacity planning, and/or reached agreements with private providers to access their capacities in case of need (Mercille et al., Reference Mercille, Turner and Lucey2022).

4. Limitations

This short essay has a number of limitations. First, we don't provide a ranking of the criteria according to their importance, which should be done in each country according to local preferences. Second, we don't provide a method to directly assess/quantify the criteria in practice, which will require further research. Some of the criteria can be quantified with reasonable effort, such as the incentives for risk selection (see e.g. Beck et al., Reference Beck, Trottmann and Zweifel2010; van Kleef et al., Reference van Kleef, McGuire, van Vliet and van de Ven2017). With respect to the other criteria, the literature on the industrial organisation of healthcare markets offers insights into the expected behaviour of providers and insurers in different regulatory settings (Dranove and Satterthwaite, Reference Dranove and Satterthwaite2000; Gaynor et al., Reference Gaynor, Ho and Town2015). Cross-country comparisons provide additional information, especially if similar reforms have been implemented across a number of countries (EXPH, 2015). The analysis of these contexts should be based on local market data and country-specific knowledge. Third, we don't make explicit suggestions on which scores on our criteria justify which type of regulation. Our framework is useful to identify submarkets of concern, and we broadly discuss regulatory tools that can be used to structure those submarkets. The potential to map the criteria in the framework to specific regulatory tools should be explored in future research.

5. Conclusions

The desired level of competition in healthcare markets remains a subject of debate, and there is theoretical and empirical evidence to support both sides. We have proposed a framework to help structure the debate, relying on eight criteria that are based on the market competition literature.

Clearly, the various criteria will be fulfilled to different degrees across types of health services, and therefore, competition in healthcare markets should not be managed in a ‘one-size-fits-all’ manner. Rather, the expected benefit of competition in each (sub-)market needs to be taken into consideration and expected market failures need to be mitigated by specific regulatory tools.

Competing interest

Maria Trottmann is employed at SWICA, a major Swiss health insurer. Piet Stam is employed at Equalis Strategy & Modeling, a management consulting firm of health economists and part of the Vintura group. Johan Visser is employed at Zorginstituut Nederland. Zorginstituut Nederland is responsible for various tasks related to health insurance, quality standards and the reimbursement of medical treatments and pharmaceuticals.

Footnotes

1 We thank anonymous reviewer 2 for pointing this out.

2 We thank anonymous reviewer 1 for pointing this out.

References

Arrow, KJ (1963) Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. The American Economic Review 53, 941973.Google Scholar
Auty, SG, Cole, MB and Wallace, J (2022) Association between Medicaid managed care coverage of substance use services and treatment utilization. JAMA Health Forum 3, e222812. https://doi.org/10.1001/jamahealthforum.2022.2812Google Scholar
Barros, PP, Brouwer, WBF, Thomson, S and Varkevisser, M (2016) Competition among health care providers: helpful or harmful? The European Journal of Health Economics 17, 229233. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-015-0736-3Google Scholar
Beck, K, Trottmann, M and Zweifel, P (2010) Risk adjustment in health insurance and its long-term effectiveness. Journal of Health Economics 29, 489498. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2010.03.009CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Breyer, F, Zweifel, P and Kifmann, M (2013) Gesundheitsökonomik, 6th Edn. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cutler, D and Reber, S (1998) Paying for health insurance: the trade-off between competition and adverse selection. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 433466.Google Scholar
Dranove, D and Satterthwaite, MA (2000) The industrial organization of health care markets. In Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 10931139. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0064(00)80033-5Google Scholar
Eggleston, K, Ellis, RP and Lu, M (2012) Risk adjustment and prevention. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’économique 45, 15861607. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5982.2012.01747.xGoogle Scholar
Enthoven, AC (1978a) Consumer-choice health plan – a national-health-insurance proposal based on regulated competition in the private sector. New England Journal of Medicine 298, 709720.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Enthoven, AC (1978b) Consumer-choice health plan – inflation and inequity in health care today: alternatives for cost control and an analysis of proposals for National Health Insurance. New England Journal of Medicine 298, 650658.Google Scholar
Enthoven, AC (1986) Managed competition in health care and the unfinished agenda. Health Care Financing Review 1986(Suppl), 105–119.Google Scholar
EXPH (2015) Competition among health care providers: investigating policy options in the European Union. Opinion adopted at the 10th plenary meeting after public consultation. Luxembourg: Expert Panel on Effective Ways of Investing in Health.Google Scholar
Frank, RG, Glazer, J and McGuire, TG (2000) Measuring adverse selection in managed health care. Journal of Health Economics 19, 829854. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-6296(00)00059-XGoogle Scholar
Gaynor, M and Town, RJ (2011) Competition in health care markets. In Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 2. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 499637. https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-53592-4.00009-8Google Scholar
Gaynor, M, Ho, K and Town, RJ (2015) The industrial organization of health-care markets. Journal of Economic Literature 53, 235284. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.53.2.235CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman-Bacon, A (2021) The long-run effects of childhood insurance coverage: Medicaid implementation, adult health, and labor market outcomes. American Economic Review 111, 25502593. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20171671CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henriquez, J, Van de Ven, WPMM, Paolucci, F, Armstrong, J and Melia, A (2022) The roads to managed competition for mixed public-private health systems: a conceptual framework. Working Paper. Newcastle, Australia: The University of Newcastle.Google Scholar
Hibbard, JH, Slovic, P and Jewett, JJ (1997) Informing consumer decisions in health care: implications from decision-making research. The Milbank Quarterly 75, 395414. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0009.00061CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hughes, A, Almeland, SK, Leclerc, T, Ogura, T, Hayashi, M, Mills, J-A, Norton, I and Potokar, T (2021) Recommendations for burns care in mass casualty incidents: WHO Emergency Medical Teams Technical Working Group on Burns (WHO TWGB) 2017–2020. Burns: Journal of the International Society for Burn Injuries 47, 349370. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.burns.2020.07.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Institute of Medicine (2000) Interpreting the Volume-Outcome Relationship in the Context of Health Care Quality: Workshop Summary. Washington, DC: National Academies Press. https://doi.org/10.17226/10005Google Scholar
Krabbe-Alkemade, Y, Groot, T and Lindeboom, M (2017) Competition in the Dutch hospital sector: an analysis of health care volume and cost. The European Journal of Health Economics 18, 139153. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-016-0762-9CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Layton, TJ, Ellis, RP, McGuire, TG and van Kleef, R (2017) Measuring efficiency of health plan payment systems in managed competition health insurance markets. Journal of Health Economics 56, 237255. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2017.05.004Google Scholar
Lovell, CAK, Rodríguez-Álvarez, A and Wall, A (2009) The effects of stochastic demand and expense preference behaviour on public hospital costs and excess capacity. Health Economics 18, 227235. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.1352Google Scholar
McGuire, TG and van Kleef, R (2018) Regulated competition in health insurance markets: paradigms and ongoing issues. In Risk Adjustment, Risk Sharing and Premium Regulation in Health Insurance Markets – Theory and Practice, vol. 1, 1st Edn. London: Elsevier Inc., pp. 3–20.Google Scholar
McGuire, TG, van Kleef, RC and van Veen, SHCM (2020) Paying for mental health care in private health insurance in the Netherlands: some lessons for the United States. Psychiatric Services 71, 538539. https://doi.org/10.1176/appi.ps.202000104Google Scholar
McGuire, TG, Schillo, S and van Kleef, RC (2021) Very high and low residual spenders in private health insurance markets: Germany, The Netherlands and the U.S. marketplaces. The European Journal of Health Economics 22, 3550. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-020-01227-3CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mercille, J, Turner, B and Lucey, DS (2022) Ireland's takeover of private hospitals during the COVID-19 pandemic. Health Economics, Policy and Law 17, 232237. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744133121000189Google Scholar
Newhouse, J (1996) Reimbursing health plans and health providers: efficiency in production versus selection. Journal of Economic Literature 34, 12361263.Google Scholar
Olson, M (1969) The principle of ‘fiscal equivalence’: the division of responsibilities among different levels of government. American Economic Review 59, 479487.Google Scholar
Powell, D and Seabury, S (2018) Medical care spending and labor market outcomes: evidence from workers’ compensation reforms. American Economic Review 108, 29953027. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150912CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rothshild, M and Stiglitz, J (1976) Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: an essay on the economics of imperfect information. Quarterly Journal of Economics 90, 629649.Google Scholar
Schillo, S, Lux, G, Wasem, J and Buchner, F (2016) High cost pool or high cost groups – how to handle high(Est) cost cases in a risk adjustment mechanism? Health Policy 120, 141147. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2016.01.003CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shleifer, A (1985) A theory of yardstick competition. Rand Journal of Economics 16, 319327.Google Scholar
Shmueli, A, Stam, P, Wasem, J and Trottmann, M (2015) Managed care in four managed competition OECD health systems. Health Policy 119, 860873. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2015.02.013Google Scholar
Van de Ven, WP (1996) Market-oriented health care reforms: trends and future options. Social Science & Medicine 43, 655666. https://doi.org/10.1016/0277-9536(96)00111-6Google Scholar
Van de Ven, WPMM and Ellis, R (2000) Risk adjustment in competitive health plan markets. In Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 755845.Google Scholar
Van de Ven, WP and Schut, E (1994) Should catastrophic risk be included in a regulated competitive health insurance markets? Social Science & Medicine 39, 14591472.Google Scholar
van de Ven, WPMM, Beck, K, Buchner, F, Chernichovsky, D, Gardiol, L, Holly, A, Lamers, LM, Schokkaert, , Shmueli, A, Spycher, S, Van de Voorde, C, Van Vliet, R, Wasem, J and Zmora, I (2003) Risk adjustment and risk selection on the sickness fund insurance market in five European countries. Health Policy 65, 7598. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0168-8510(02)00118-5CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Van de Ven, WP, Beck, K, Buchner, F, Schokkaert, E, Schut, FT, Shmueli, A and Wasem, J (2013) Preconditions for efficiency and affordability in competitive healthcare markets: are they fulfilled in Belgium, Germany, Israel, the Netherlands and Switzerland? Health Policy 109, 226245. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2013.01.002Google Scholar
van der Wolf, M (2021) The Netherlands: ‘Going Dutch’ – taking care of forensic mental healthcare. Expert Insights. 17 June 2021. https://www.prisonstudies.org/Google Scholar
van Kleef, RC, McGuire, TG, van Vliet, RCJA and van de Ven, WPPM (2017) Improving risk equalization with constrained regression. The European Journal of Health Economics 18, 11371156. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-016-0859-1Google Scholar
Widmer, PK, Trottmann, M and Zweifel, P (2018) Choice of reserve capacity by hospitals: a problem for prospective payment. The European Journal of Health Economics 19, 663673. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-017-0909-3Google Scholar
Zweifel, P and Breuer, M (2006) The case for risk-based premiums in public health insurance. Health Economics, Policy and Law 1, 171188. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744133105001064Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The managed competition model (solid line) and additional regulatory tools (dashed line).