1. Introduction
Social scientists have been discussing the two sides of corruption. Several studies argued that corruption could grease the wheel of development by enhancing efficiency (Huntington, Reference Huntington1968; Leff, Reference Leff1964; Saha and Sen, Reference Saha and Sen2021) and reducing business transaction costs (Jiang and Nie, Reference Jiang and Nie2014). However, many others evidenced that corruption is a sand in the wheel of development. Corruption can hamper economic growth in many ways (Aidt, Reference Aidt2009; Mauro, Reference Mauro1995), such as by distorting governmental expenditures (Reference MauroMauro,1998; Tanzi, Reference Tanzi1998; Tanzi and Davoodi, Reference Tanzi, Davoodi, Shibata and Ihori1998; Zergawu et al., Reference Zergawu, Walle and Giménez-Gómez2020), hindering investment (Hodgson and Jiang, Reference Hodgson and Jiang2007; Zakharov, Reference Zakharov2019), reducing the effectiveness of foreign aid (Princeton Survey Research Associates, 2003), disturbing the efficiency in fiscal policies (Fjeldstad, Reference Fjeldstad2003; Runde and Metzger, Reference Runde and Metzger2020), lowering the quality of bureaucracy (Runde and Metzger, Reference Runde and Metzger2020; Tanzi, Reference Tanzi1998), aggravating poverty and inequality (Gupta et al., Reference Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-Terme2002), reducing competitiveness, and finally lowering the productivity (Ogun, Reference Ogun, Hamada and Wok2019).
Organizational corruption in public institutions and private corporations transform into many formations including bribery, kickbacks from public procurement, lobbying, extortive and evasive bribes,Footnote 1 cronyism, nepotism, patronage, graft, embezzlement of public funds, etc. (Bardhan, Reference Bardhan2006; Kaymak and Bektas, Reference Kaymak and Bektas2015). These forms of corruption spread quite easily within and across public and private sectors while impeding economic development directly and indirectly through many channels, such as increasing cost and level of private investment (Kaymak and Bektas, Reference Kaymak and Bektas2015; Liu and Feng, Reference Liu and Feng2015; Mauro, Reference Mauro1995, Reference Mauro1998; Tanzi, Reference Tanzi1998). To expand international business, companies would pay a large amount of bribes to obtain local government contracts, permission to access the market, or government subsidies. Thus, corruption is not only an issue that exists within a single country or region but also a contagion that is spatially spreading between foreign governments and domestic private sectors through international business transactions (Attila, Reference Attila2008; Becker et al., Reference Becker, Egger and Seidel2009; Hodgson and Jiang, Reference Hodgson and Jiang2007). In addition, Adomako et al. (Reference Adomako, Ahsan, Amankwah-Amoah, Danso, Kesse and Frimpong2021) find that institutional networking positively mediates the relationship between perceived corruption and small–medium enterprise growth.
Many countries jointly combat corruption in international business transactions by implementing laws and regulations. In a recent scandal, Walmart was fined $282 million according to the US Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) after exercising corruption activities in Brazil, India, and Mexico. However, the anticorruption actions have not effectively alleviated the coexistence of global corruption and development. According to the World Bank estimates, businesses and individuals worldwide pay $1.5 trillion in bribes each year, making up 2% of global GDP and 10 times the total official development assistance (Runde and Metzger, Reference Runde and Metzger2020). Two-thirds of countries faced severe corruption issues, and most countries had minimal or no progress in tackling corruption over time (CPI 2019 Report, 2019).
While we have argued that corruption may traverse borders, we are more interested in the mechanism in which efficiency spreads between nations and the part that corruption control plays in this mechanism. To link the spatial interactions of countries' technical efficiencies and control of corruption, we estimate the efficiencies via a spatial autoregressive (SAR) stochastic frontier model using 102 countries' data from 1996 to 2014. In particular, technical efficiency measures the managerial effectiveness in terms of maximizing outputs conditional on a country's production technology, which describes the production possibilities of a country, and inputs (i.e. labor, capital, and energy). Since our measure of technical efficiency is conditional on the level of technology, a country with advanced production technology in production may still be inefficient if it does not use its technological advantage effectively. To our knowledge, our work fills the gap in the economic literature that captures the effect of corruption control on technical efficiency spillovers using the stochastic frontier model. Particularly, the model includes the distribution of the inefficiency as a function of the control of corruption variable. Our results show that control of corruption in a country would improve the efficiency of the country, which in turn helps reduce inefficiencies of neighbors through efficiency spillovers. In line with this idea, we obtain both country-specific average efficiency estimates and efficiency losses due to other countries not being fully efficient. Moreover, we estimate the averages of direct and indirect marginal effects of corruption control on efficiency. Here, the direct marginal effect refers to the counterfactual effect of corruption control on the efficiency of a country if there were no spillovers. The indirect marginal effect refers to the counterfactual effect of corruption control on the efficiency of a country only through spillovers (excluding the direct effect). Our findings indicate that control of corruption has a significant effect on a country's efficiency as well as other neighboring countries.
We then visualize the efficiency spillover effects by transferring the data into maps. The maps indicate that many countries in Southeast Asia and Europe have the highest average efficiency in the period of 1996–2014. In order to study dynamic changes of efficiencies, we split our sample into three periods following the business cycle expansions and contractions: 1994–2002, 2002–2008, and 2008–2014. The results show that global efficiency slightly increased in the second period compared to the first period. Only eight countries' efficiencies declined in the second period compared to 10 countries in the first period. However, we find that 57 countries' efficiencies decreased in the third period compared to the first period.
2. Background
Corruption not only distorts the market, but it also reduces capital and efficiencies in both public and private sectors. Corruption in the privatization of firms could intensify public capital loss (Tanzi, Reference Tanzi1998). Many government-controlled firms were highly likely to file for bankruptcy with the inefficient allocation of resources (Kaufmann and Siegelbaum, Reference Kaufmann and Siegelbaum1997). Hence, if corruption control is a determinant of efficiency, it may help reduce the probability of bankruptcy. Corruption also negatively associates with government revenue (Kaymak and Bektas, Reference Kaymak and Bektas2015) by reducing the efficiency of government projects, distorting tax structure (Liu and Feng, Reference Liu and Feng2015), and increasing uncertainty while reducing the expected returns of the investment outcome (Mauro, Reference Mauro1995). In addition, corruption increases income inequality by reducing the progressivity of the tax system while intensifying evasive and extortive tax (Gupta et al., Reference Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-Terme2002). Corruption also leads to trade-taxing extortion that increases the magnitude of bribes and reduces foreign producers' incentives for exports (Dutt and Traca, Reference Dutt and Traca2010).Footnote 2 Aside from direct economic effects, many conflicts have manifested by corruption, which further indirectly impedes economic growth. The uncertainty associated with corruption can possibly escalate to political violence, including revolutions, coups, and assassinations (Clammer, Reference Clammer, Barcham, Hindess and Larmous2012).
Corruption can be traced to a more granular level, which discourages employees from improving their skills while reducing productivity (Acemoglu and Verdier, Reference Acemoglu and Verdier1998; Ogun, Reference Ogun, Hamada and Wok2019). Employees follow their colleagues after they observe the acquiescence and ignorance of corruption from managers. In the long run, it generates a culture of corruption in the firm, then further spreads it to firms in their supply chains and the entire industry.Footnote 3 To control the spillover effect of corruption through foreign business transactions, multinational corporations (MNCs) chose a collaboration structure with their local partners in highly corrupt countries that consequently minimize the uncertainty and inefficiency generated by corruption (Sartor and Beamish, Reference Sartor and Beamish2020). In particular, MNCs are more likely to invest through a joint venture rather than a wholly owned subsidiary in highly corrupt countries.
The global battle against corruption started in the late 90's. In 1997, OECD countries held Anti-Bribery Convention to prohibit private-sector bribery (Levine, Reference Levine2019). To continue with the convention, in 2003, the United Nations General Assembly adopted the ‘UN Convention Against Corruption’, which is a landmark of the international anticorruption treaty. Individual countries and regions also recognize the importance of anticorruption programs and legislation, such as the UK Bribery Act of 2010, and China's Anticorruption and Build a Clean Government program (Alonso et al., Reference Alonso, Palma and Simon-Yarza2022; Fayissa and Nsiah, Reference Fayissa and Nsiah2013; Runde and Metzger, Reference Runde and Metzger2020). However, these anticorruption actions have not effectively alleviated the coexistence of global corruption and development.
Besides the existing studies that examine the interplay between corruption and efficiency, many others investigate the pattern of corruption spillover effect. Tanzi (Reference Tanzi1998) highlights that corruption cumulates in individual institutions and then resembles the spreading of a contagious disease. The contagion of corruption would not only spread within the country but also spread to other countries (Hodgson and Jiang, Reference Hodgson and Jiang2007). Using the data from low- and middle-income countries, Ugur and Dasgupta (Reference Ugur and Dasgupta2011) show that corruption is a problem that exists in both developing and developed countries. Becker et al. (Reference Becker, Egger and Seidel2009) apply a spatial econometric model to capture the regional dependency of corruption. The average level of corruption in one country's neighbor would positively affect the level of national corruption. Thus, low-corrupt countries are more likely to be in a lower-level corruption region. However, the link between spatial interactions of countries' technical efficiencies and control of corruption is missing. We will address this issue from a SAR stochastic frontier model in the next section.
3. Model and estimation
3.1. Data
In this study, we are interested in the mechanism in which efficiency spreads between nations and the role of corruption control plays in this mechanism. To conduct the study, we utilize the control of corruption variable in ‘Worldwide Governance Indicators’ from The World Bank. The control of corruption captures how much public power affects private gain, as well as the elites and private interests (WGI 2020 Data Source, 2020). The variable was generated by many resources, including corruption among public officials, the public trust of politicians, and the corruption index, etc. Our SAR stochastic frontier model links technical efficiencies and control of corruption by considering the spatial spillover effect. To build the model, we first retrieved the country and year-specific production input and output variables from the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB) websites. We consider balanced panel data for 102 countries between 1996 and 2014 (excluding 1997, 1999, 2001).Footnote 4 There are three input variables in the dataset: labor (L), capital (K), and energy (E). The labor input is the labor force variable that is obtained from the World Bank website; the capital input is the capital stock in billions of constant 2011 international dollars, which is obtained from the IMF website. Both energy consumption per capita and population variables are obtained from the World Bank website.Footnote 5 We then conduct the country's energy input in kilotonnes of oil equivalent (Ktoe) by multiplying energy consumption per capita and population. Following Kutlu (Reference Kutlu2020), we calculate the capital stock by summing the government, private, and public–private capital stocks; and we assume that the output is the real GDP in billions of constant 2011 international dollars.Footnote 6
We obtain the geographical distances between two countries from CEPII dataset (Mayer and Zignago, Reference Mayer and Zignago2011).Footnote 7 The geographic distance is calculated based on bilateral distances of most important cities of two countries using the great circle formula. For most countries in our dataset, the most important city of a country is taken as its capital.Footnote 8 Several previous firm-level productivity spillover studies assume that the spillover effect is a function of distance. For example, Halpern and Muraközy (Reference Halpern and Muraközy2007) identify the effect of distance on horizontal and vertical productivity spillovers via labor channel by using Hungarian manufacturing firms' data. Distance limits labor mobility and further retards the effectiveness of knowledge transfer. The study suggests that knowledge transfers more effectively through face-to-face communication. Similarly, using US firm-level data, Lychagin et al. (Reference Lychagin, Pinkse, Slade and Reenen2016) explain that geographic location is important for both intra- and inter-country productivity spillover. High-skilled workers are more likely to change jobs in the same geographic region, which causes knowledge flows within regional labor networks. Geographic distance weights specify that productivity spillovers decay gradually as distance becomes farther. Thus, distance is an appropriate candidate to measure productivity spillovers. In Table 1, we present the descriptive statistics for our dataset.
3.2. Productivity and efficiency spillover model for countries
We assume that the output and technical efficiency of a country are affected by spillovers from other countries. Following Glass et al. (Reference Glass, Kenjegalieva and Sickles2016), we assume that the production process of a country is determined by the following SAR production function:Footnote 9
where y it is the logarithm of real GDP (output) of country i at time t; ρ ∈ [0, 1) represents the SAR parameter, which is capturing the spatial spillovers; w ij ≥ 0 is the spatial weight for the effect of jth country's real GDP on the real GDP of ith country and w ii = 0, which rules out self-spillover; x it is the vector of frontier variables, which are exogenous; u it ≥ 0 is a term that captures technical inefficiency; and r it is a vector of variables that affect efficiency. For example, in the ‘Empirical model and results’ section, we assume that r it includes a variable representing the control of corruption control. Hence, the distribution of inefficiency is a function of control of corruption. We assume that $v_{it}\sim N( 0, \;\,\sigma _v^2 )$ and $u_{it}^\ast{\sim} N + ( {0, \;\,1} )$ are independently distributed random variables. Hence, $u_{it}\sim N^ + ( {0, \;\,\sigma_{u, it}^2 } )$ where $\sigma _{u, it}^2 = \exp ( {r_{it}^{\rm^{\prime}} \gamma } ) \ge 0$. Similar to the variance of u it, we reparameterize the variance of v it as follows $\sigma _v^2 = \exp ( {c_v} )$ where c v is a parameter. We assume that the weighting matrix is row-normalized, i.e. $\sum\nolimits_j {w_{ij} = 1}$. This weighting matrix assures that the efficiency estimates lie in the unit interval (Kutlu, Reference Kutlu2018b). We assume that the ijth component of weighting matrix is:
where d ij is the distance between country i and j. When ρ = 0, we would not have productivity and efficiency spillovers. However, when ρ ≠ 0, we would have productivity and efficiency spillovers. The estimations are done via maximum likelihood estimation method.
3.3. The effect of spillovers on technical efficiencies of countries
The conventional stochastic frontier models calculate the efficiency by exp ( − u it). However, since this formula ignores spatial spillovers, we need to rearrange our model to obtain spillover-corrected efficiency scores. In matrix notation, we have:
where y t(y 1t, y 2t,, y Nt), x t(x 1t, x 2t,, x Nt), u t(u 1t, u 2t,, u Nt), v t(v 1t, v 2t,, v Nt), S(ρ;q t) = (I N − ρW(q t))−1, w is the weighting matrix, $\tilde{x}_t = S( {p; \;q_t} ) x_t$, $\tilde{u}_t = S( {p; \;q_t} ) u_t$, and $\tilde{v}_t = S( {p; \;q_t} ) v_t$. Then, the spatial-spillover-corrected efficiency is given by Kutlu (Reference Kutlu2018b, Reference Kutlu2022):
4. Empirical model and results
We provide the estimation results of three models in Table 2. The first set of parameters represent the stochastic frontier parameters. In line with the conventional stochastic frontier models, we model the production frontier via the translog functional form where the technological changes are captured by the time trend, T, and its interaction with other variables. Then, the table presents the parameter estimates for $\sigma _v^2$ and $\sigma _{u, it}^2$. The inefficiency estimates are positively related to the parameter estimates in $\sigma _{u, it}^2$. Hence, a negative coefficient for corruption control would indicate a positive relationship between efficiency and corruption control. The table also announces the spatial spillover parameter, ρ, along with mean and median efficiency estimates.Footnote 10
Note: Standard errors are given in parenthesis. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.
The first model ignores heterogeneity; the second model ignores spatial spillovers; and the third model controls for both heterogeneity and spatial spillovers. In these models, the country-specific heterogeneity is controlled via country-fixed effects and spatial spillovers are controlled by the SAR stochastic frontier model that we described earlier. Among others, Greene (Reference Greene2005), Kutlu and McCarthy (Reference Kutlu and McCarthy2016), and Kutlu et al. (Reference Kutlu, Tran and Tsionas2019, Reference Kutlu, Tran and Tsionas2020) point out the importance of controlling heterogeneity in a stochastic frontier model.Footnote 11 When heterogeneity is present and ignored, inefficiency would be confused with heterogeneity, which may bias the parameter estimates. Heterogeneity includes technological and other differences between countries. Hence, a developed country may end up being less efficient if it is not utilizing the existing resources and technology entirely, even if its output is more than a developing country. Similarly, if there are spatial spillovers and these spillovers are not controlled, the parameter and efficiency estimates would be biased. We test for homogeneity (i.e. equality of coefficients of country-specific dummy variables) and then reject the homogeneity at any conventional statistical significance level. The SAR coefficient is statistically significant at any conventional statistical significance level. Moreover, the estimated model satisfies the input monotonicity assumption at the mean. In particular, the mean (median) elasticity of output with respect to labor, capital, and energy inputs are 0.46 (0.46), 0.39 (0.38), and 0.31 (0.31), respectively. Hence, we will use the third model that controls for heterogeneity and spatial spillovers as our benchmark model.Footnote 12
In what follows, unless otherwise is stated the estimation results would be based on our benchmark model. The estimates show that the average and median efficiencies are 71.16% and 74.72%, respectively.Footnote 13 The coefficient of corruption control variable is negative and statistically significant at any conventional levels. Hence, we predict that the higher controlling for corruption would improve efficiency in a country. Some studies explain part of our results from different perspectives. For example, Dal Bó and Rossi (Reference Dal Bó and Rossi2007) and Gamberoni et al. (Reference Gamberoni, Gartner, Giordano and Lopez-Garcia2016) use firm-level data to probe corruption that can lead input misallocation and distort firm's productivity. Dal Bó and Rossi (Reference Dal Bó and Rossi2007) elaborate that firms in more corrupt countries are more likely to misallocate their resources by using electricity firms' efficiency data in 13 Latin American countries. Corruption leads firms to move their managerial effort away from the supervision and coordination of the production process. Thus, firms will hire more workers to produce a given level of output. Moreover, Gamberoni et al. (Reference Gamberoni, Gartner, Giordano and Lopez-Garcia2016) argue that corruption negatively influences the input allocation as well as total factor productivity (TFP) growth in Central and Eastern European (CEE) firms.Footnote 14 They then highlight that controlling of corruption, especially improving the effectiveness of the regulatory environment, would be beneficial to weak institutions in improving the production process and aggravating TFP growth.Footnote 15
In Table 3, we present country-specific technical efficiency and related estimates by considering the spillover effect of corruption control. The first column presents the averages of efficiency estimates; the second column presents the averages of efficiency losses due to spillovers (there is efficiency loss because other countries are not fully efficient); the third column presents the average change in efficiency when the corruption control variable increases by one standard deviation for all countries; and the fourth column presents the average change in efficiency when the corruption control variable increases only for the relevant country. According to the estimates in the first two columns, we find many countries in Southeast Asia are most technically efficient in the production process while they minimize efficiency loss. Reversely, many highly corrupt African countries performed the worst with the lowest efficiency and highest efficiency loss. From 1996 to 2014, Southeast Asian countries such as Indonesia, Malaysia, and Cambodia are the most efficient countries with efficiencies 96.58%, 96.44%, and 96.1%, respectively. This result is similar to Kao (Reference Kao2013)'s national productivity study by measuring TFP. He highlights that Indonesia and Malaysia have the highest combination of labor and capital productivity among 10 Southeast Asian countries in the study.Footnote 16 This finding also indicates that both countries performed well in allocating their production resources. At this point, we want to state that although the technical efficiency of Cambodia is high, the country does not perform very well in terms of overall production due to its intrinsic technological disadvantages. That is, while the management is relatively good, the production technology/environment dampens the overall production levels for given inputs. In particular, Cambodia is ranked 100th out of 102 countries in terms of the dummy variable that captures heterogeneity. In contrast to Cambodia, Indonesia performed better than the median country in terms of its available production technology.Footnote 17
Note: Total CC effect: the total marginal effect of corruption control variable when increased by one standard deviation. Direct CC effect: the direct marginal effect of corruption control variable when increased by one standard deviation.
Regarding the results shown in Table 3, note that technical efficiency refers to how well the country maximizes the outputs giving the available inputs conditional on the technology available to the country. Hence, it is a concept that is related to how well the resources of a country are managed relative to its potential. Thus, a country with advanced production technology may still show technical inefficiency if it does not use its technological advantage effectively. The way that we capture country heterogeneity allows us to compare the technical efficiencies of countries based on their own potentials. Our results suggest that while some countries (e.g. Algeria, Morocco, etc.) have some technological disadvantages, they manage their production process relatively well.
Despite the financial crisis in 1997, countries in this region recovered very soon with high economic growth. For most Southeast Asian countries, the average real GDP has steadily grown approximately 5% or more every year, which is higher than the world GDP growth rate.Footnote 18 During this time period, ‘Factory Asia’ has placed in Southeast Asian countries. This region becomes one of the most important producers in manufacturing global value chains.Footnote 19 In addition, we find that lower corruption-controlled African countries' efficiencies are generally lower than other regions. Zimbabwe (30.3%), Tanzania (32.14%), and Zambia (34.17%) are the most inefficient countries in managing the production process (in the sense of technical efficiency). Meanwhile, most of the countries in Southeast Asia minimize their efficiency loss (e.g. Indonesia (3.03pp), Malaysia, (3.39pp) and Philippines (3.51pp) have best performance in efficiency).Footnote 20 However, Africa, Namibia (25.73pp), Kenya (25.68pp), and Mauritius (22.12pp) have largest efficiency losses due to spillovers (i.e. the efficiency loss due to other countries not being fully efficient) in their production. The high-efficiency losses in these countries are partially caused by deficiency of corruption control efforts by their neighboring countries. We then displayed the estimated countries corruption control effort in the last two columns. The average and median change in the efficiency when the corruption control variable increases by one standard deviation (0.9828) for all countries are 6.75pp and 5.82pp, respectively.Footnote 21 Similarly, the average and median change in the efficiency when the corruption variable increases by one standard deviation for the country of interest (i.e. direct efficiency change) are 4.22pp and 3.64pp, respectively.
In order to visualize the spillover effect, we facilitate the average spatial efficiency (column 1) in Figure 1. We observe that Southeast Asian and European countries have the highest technical efficiency. The most efficient Southeast Asian countries, Indonesia, Malaysia, and Cambodia, intensified their clampdown on corruption more than others, while bringing positive efficiency spillovers to their neighbors, Thailand, Vietnam, and Myanmar. Consequently, the high anti-corruption efforts enhance their neighbors' technical efficiency that Thailand, Vietnam, and Myanmar estimated average technical efficiency is 93.08%, 92.64%, and 91.50%, respectively. Similarly, Western European countries with relatively high-level corruption control (Belgium, Netherlands, Luxembourg, and Portugal) have high technical efficiency that spillovers to their neighboring countries (United Kingdom, Germany, and Spain).
Overall, we observe efficiency spillovers across countries (regions) that high-corruption-control and high-efficiency countries are more likely to have relatively high corruption-control and high-efficiency neighbors. That is, high-corruption-control and high-efficiency counties would boost their neighbors' efforts in combating corruption, as well as technical efficiency through spillovers. Hence, corruption control is not only important in the origin country but also other countries surrounding it. On the other hand, a country surrounded by countries that are having difficulty in handling corruption would also be negatively affected through efficiency spillovers. This suggests that countries have incentives to handle their own corruption problems, meanwhile, they may benefit if the surrounding countries do not have corruption-related problems. Of course, in practice, there may exist political reasons that dominate efficiency-related benefits. However, this study only concentrates on economic benefits that are related to efficiency gains.
To uncover how country-level technical efficiency has changed over time, we divide countries into subgroups according to their changes in efficiency between time periods. We use the ending year efficiency minus the beginning year efficiency to calculate the efficiency difference and present them in Figure 2. In Figure 2, according to the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) business cycle peak year data,Footnote 22 we divide our 19-year sample into three periods, where period 1 is between 1996 and 2002, period 2 is between 2002 and 2008, and period 3 is between 2008 and 2014.
Figure 2(a) shows changes in spatial technical efficiency in the first period. In this period, the majority of Southeast Asian countries suffered a loss in efficiency, potentially reducing the effort on corruption control. That is, the financial crisis reduced government spending on clamping down on corruption. The East and Southeast Asian financial crisis in 1997 devalued Asian countries' currencies and defaulted on their domestic debt. Therefore, it consequently caused inflation and other financial losses as well as reduced the effort of corruption control. As the center of the financial crisis, Thailand lost the most efficiency (26.46pp) and corruption control (31.6%) during the first period. Their neighbors, China and Indonesia suffered efficiency losses while their enforcement of corruption control decreased in varying degrees. China and Indonesia suffered an efficiency loss of 15.64pp and 1.66pp. At the same time, their control of corruption decreased by 10.3% and 86.9%, respectively.
In the second period (see Figure 2(b)), many Asian countries achieved rapid efficiency growth and jointly enhanced efforts to combat corruption. For example, China's efficiency increased by 55.74pp and its corruption control effort raised by 51.5%. China's neighboring countries' technical efficiency and the effort of corruption control increased. Thailand's efficiency improved the most by 26.48pp and its corruption control increased by 7.3% during the second period. At the same time, Malaysia and Indonesia's efficiency and corruption control improved marginally as well. Malaysia and Indonesia's efficiency increased by 0.59pp and 2.01pp, and corruption control was enhanced by 2.9% and 26.3%, respectively.
According to Figure 2(c), we observe that both efficiency and the enforcement of corruption control weakened, that most European, African, and Southeast Asian countries suffered losses in technical efficiency and the reduction in corruption control efforts in the third period. This period began with the global financial crisis from 2007 to 2009 due to an unsustainable asset bubble in the US and ended with the great oil crisis in 2014. The worldwide financial crises weakened corruption control efforts, raised fraud, and deteriorated technical efficiencies through spillovers. Accordingly, China, El Salvador, and Congo, the countries most affected in this period, experienced efficiency losses of 32.7pp, 34.29pp, and 35.54pp, respectively, and their neighboring countries' efficiency was reduced at the same time due to the spillover effect. In particular, China's efficiency decreased by 32.7pp in 2014, and its corruption control effort was reduced by 54.2%. Another potential reason was the promotion of new anticorruption policies by the Chinese government that had to break the old pattern. The promotion process might cause a temporary disruption in technical efficiency. While these new anticorruption policies brought a temporary distortion of efficiency, they may enhance efficiency better than old policies in the long run.
5. Concluding remarks
Our study applies a SAR stochastic frontier model to estimate the effect of corruption control on efficiency from 1996 to 2014 for 102 countries. The study fills the gap in the economic literature on corruption control, technical efficiency, and spatial spillovers. It is notably novel in several respects. First, the SAR model controls heterogeneity to eliminate biases in parameter estimates. The model also considers the spillover effect of technical efficiency and the control of corruption. The estimates show that the lack of corruption controls reduces efficiency more with spillovers. Control of corruption in a country not only significantly reduces the country's inefficiency but also its negative spillovers influence their neighboring countries. Similarly, if the neighboring countries enhance their control of corruption, then the country is likely to be relatively efficient compared to a country with more corrupt neighbors.
We then present the averages of efficiency estimates, the averages of efficiency losses due to spillovers from corrupt neighbors, and the efficiency changes are partially affected by the change of corruption control. The results indicate that Southeast Asian and European countries were the most efficient countries on average from 1996 to 2014. We observe that technical efficiencies are significantly distorted during the oil crisis in 2014. To study the dynamic change of country-level technical efficiency, we divide countries into three subgroups according to the changes in efficiency between time periods: 1996 and 2002, 2002 and 2008, and 2008 and 2014. We obtain efficiency changes by calculating the difference between ending year efficiency and the beginning year efficiency. The results show that 85 out of 102 countries' technical efficiencies continually increased in the second period compared to the first period. However, in the third period, 67 (out of 102) of countries' efficiencies dramatically declined, particularly in China. We suspect the deterioration of efficiencies in China was caused in part by financial crises as well as the temporary disruption by implementing new anticorruption policies. It is worth investigating whether the episode of financial crises is an important mechanism in the causal relationship between corruption control and technical efficiency in a future study.
In order to improve technical efficiency spillovers, we suggest that countries should jointly take actions to enhance the control of corruption. While collaborating with other countries, governments need to investigate corruption from different perspectives, and then formulate corresponding anticorruption regulations and policies based on their actual situations. In addition, we suggest that governments encourage market competition by enhancing property rights, creating tax incentives, and propagating procurement transparency. To maximize technical efficiency and stimulate economic growth, promoting anticorruption policies and enforcing market competitiveness associated with local and regional conditions at an appropriate time will be a valuable research topic in the future.