Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pftt2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T18:52:55.806Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

10 - Liberalizing tariff-rate quotas: quantifying the effects of enhancing market access

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 February 2010

Aziz Elbehri
Affiliation:
US Department of Agriculture
Merlinda D. Ingco
Affiliation:
Senior Economist, World Bank
Thomas W. Hertel
Affiliation:
Purdue University
Kenneth Pearson
Affiliation:
Monash University
Merlinda D. Ingco
Affiliation:
The World Bank
L. Alan Winters
Affiliation:
University of Sussex
Get access

Summary

Introduction

The tariff-rate quota (TRQ) system has become an important instrument of international trade sanctioned by the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture (URAA). The TRQ regime was codified in the URAA as a new policy mechanism to ensure both tariffication and market access. Tariffication required conversion of non-tariff barriers (NTBs) into tariff-equivalents to be lowered over a period of time, while market access ensured that quantities imported before the agreement could continue to be imported. Quotification provided for import opportunities despite the high out-of-quota tariffs. There are nearly 1,400 tariff lines notified under TRQs, about 200 are country-specific rather than global (OECD, 1997). Moreover, many agricultural products covered by TRQ regimes are also subject to domestic protection in OECD countries.

Fourteen developing countries submit market access commitments to the WTO but only two – South Korea and Philippines – seem to have implemented significant TRQ regimes (Abbott and Morse, 1999, see chapter 4 in this volume). (Some developing countries that have recently entered the WTO, such as those in Eastern Europe, or that have sought to enter, such as China, have adopted TRQs to limit liberalization of their agricultural markets.)

Developing countries have adopted TRQs quite differently. The percentage of their TRQs that is actually filled is often low, indicating a lack of quota rents and few significant restrictions on trade (Abbott and Morse, 1999). Moreover, bilateral quotas are uncommon in developing countries – more significant are the TRQs that developed countries impose on the former's exports.

Type
Chapter
Information
Agriculture and the New Trade Agenda
Creating a Global Trading Environment for Development
, pp. 194 - 220
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbott, P. and B. A. Morse, 1999. “How Developing Countries are Implementing Tariff-Rate Quotas,” see chapter 4 in this volume
Abbott, P. and Paarlberg, P., 1998. “Tariff Rate Quotas: Structural and Stability Impacts in Growing Markets,” Agricultural Economics, 19, 257–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boughner, D. S. and H. de Gorter, 1999. “The Economics of 2-Tier Tariff Rate Import Quotas and the Agreement on Agriculture in the World Trade Organization,” Department of Agricultural, Resource, and Managerial Economics, Cornell University
de Melo, J. and D. Tarr, 1992. A General Equilibrium Analysis of US Foreign Trade Policy, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press
Elbehri, A. and K. R. Pearson, 2000. “Implementing Bilateral Tariff Rate Quotas in Global Trade Analysis Project using GEMPACK,” Global Trade Analysis Project Technical Paper, 18, Global Trade Analysis Project, Purdue University
Haley, S., 1999. “Stocks-to-Use Ratios and Sugar Pricing Relationship: Implications for US Sugar Policy,” in “Sugar and Sweetener,” Washington, DC: United States Department of Agriculture/ERS, September
Harrison, W. J. and Pearson, K. R., 1996. “Computing Solutions for Large General Equilibrium Models Using GEMPACK,” Computational Economics, 9, 83–127CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertel, T. W. (ed.), 1997. Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press
Huff, K. and T. W. Hertel, 1996. “Decomposing Welfare Changes in Global Trade Analysis Project,” Global Trade Analysis Project Technical Paper, 5, Global Trade Analysis Project, Purdue University
International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium (International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium), 2000. “Issues in Reforming Tariff-Rate Quotas in the Agreement on Agriculture in the World Trade Organization,” International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium Commissioned Paper, 13, Washington, DC
Martin, W. and A. Winters (eds.), 1995. “The Uruguay Round and the Developing Economies,” World Bank Discussion Paper, 307, Washington, DC
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) Secretariat, 1997. Internal document, Paris
Sheales, T., S. Gordon, A. Hafi, and C. Toyne, 2000. “Sugar: International Policies Affecting Market Expansion,” Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics Research Report, 99–14, Canberra
Skully, D. W., 1999. “The Economics of Tariff-Rate Quota Administration,” Working Paper, 99–6, International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium, Washington, DC
Suarez, N., 1997. “Origin of the US Sugar Import Tariff-Rate Quota Shares,” in “Sugar and Sweetener Situation and Outlook Report. (SSS–221),” US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Washington, DC September
Swinbank, A., 1999. “European Union Agriculture, Agenda 2000 and the World Trade Organization Commitments,” The World Economy, 22(1), 41–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinbank, A., 1997. “Europe's Green Money,” in C. Ritson and D. R. Harvey (eds.), The Common Agricultural Policy, CAB International, Wallingford, 115–37
Tsigas, M. and M. D. Ingco, 1999. “Market Access Liberalization in the Next Round of World Trade Organization Negotiations: A General Equilibrium Assessment of Tariff-Rate Quotas,” selected paper, American Agricultural Economic Association Annual Meeting, August 8–11, Nashville
Vasavada, U. and Chambers, R. G., 1986. “Investment in US Agriculture,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 68(4), 950–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×