Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T19:07:38.798Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 September 2017

Alessandro Roncaglia
Affiliation:
Sapienza University of Rome
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. 2006. Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. 1970. ‘The market for lemons’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488500.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. and Kranton, R. 2000. ‘Economics and identity’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 715–53.Google Scholar
Allais, M. 1953. ‘Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école américaine’, Econometrica 21: 503–46.Google Scholar
Andrews, P. W. S. 1993. The economics of competitive enterprise. Selected essays. ed. by Lee, F. S. and Earl, P. E., Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Anonymous [1581] 1893. A discourse of the common weal of this realm of England. New ed. by Lamond, E., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; repr. 1929.Google Scholar
Aristotle, 1977. Politics. With an English transl. by Rackham, H., The Loeb Classic Library, vol. 21, Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
(Pseudo)Aristotle, 1935. The Oeconomica. With an English transl. by Armstrong, G.C., London: Heinemann and Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1951. Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1962. ‘The economic implications of learning by doing’, Review of Economic Studies 26: 155–73.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. and Debreu, G. 1954. ‘Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy’, Econometrica 22: 265–90.Google Scholar
Arthur, B. 1994. Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Aspromourgos, T. 2009. The science of wealth. Adam Smith and the framing of political economy. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Babbage, C. 1832. On the economy of machinery and manufactures. London: Charles Knight; fourth edn. 1835; repr. New York: M. Kelley, 1963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacon, F. 1620. Novum Organum. London: Joannem Billium; repr. in The works of Francis Bacon, ed. by Spedding, J., Ellis, R. Lesline, Heath, D. Demon, vol. 4, London: Longman and Co. 1858.Google Scholar
Bacon, F. 1626. New Atlantis. London: J.H. for Lee, W.; repr. in Bacon, F., ‘The advancement of learning’ and ‘New Atlantis’. ed. by Case, T., Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1974.Google Scholar
Bailey, S. 1825. A critical dissertation on the nature, measure and causes of value. London: R. Hunter; repr. London: Frank Cass 1967.Google Scholar
Bain, J. S. 1956. Barriers to new competition. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baran, P. A. 1957. The political economy of growth. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Baran, P. A. and Sweezy, P. M. 1966. Monopoly capital. An essay on the American economic and social order. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Barone, E. 1908. ‘Il ministro della produzione nello stato collettivista’, Giornale degli economisti 2: 267–93 and 391414. (English transl., ‘The ministry of production in the collectivist state’, in Hayek (ed.) 1935).Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Grossman, H. I. 1971. ‘A general disequilibrium model of income and employment’, American Economic Review 61: 8293.Google Scholar
Barton, J. 1817. On the conditions of the labouring classes. London: John and Arthur Arch.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. 1959. Business behaviour, value and growth. New York: Harcourt & Co.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. 1977. ‘Say’s (at least) eight laws, or what Say and James Mill may really have meant’, Economica 44: 145–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W. J., Panzar, J. C. and Willig, R. D. 1982. Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. San Diego (Calif.): Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Beccaria, C. 1764. Dei delitti e delle pene. Livorno: Coltellini; repr. in Venturi, F. (ed.), Illuministi italiani. Tomo III. Riformatori lombardi piemontesi e toscani, Milano-Napoli: Ricciardi, 1958, pp. 27105.Google Scholar
Beccaria, C. 1804. Elementi di economia politica, in Custodi, P. (ed.), Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica, Milano: Destefanis, vol. 18, pp. 17356 and vol. 19, pp. 391543.Google Scholar
Benini, R. 1907. ‘Sull’uso delle formule empiriche nell’economia applicata’, Giornale degli economisti, second series, 35: 1053–63.Google Scholar
Bentham, J. [1776]. ‘Fragment on government’, in The works of Jeremy Bentham, 9 vols., ed. by Bowring, J., Edinburgh and London: William Tait-Simpkin and Marshall & Co., 1843–59, vol. 1, pp. 221–95; repr. in ‘A comment on the commentaries’ and ‘A fragment on government’, ed. by Burns, J.H. and Hart, H.L.A., London: Athlone Press 1977.Google Scholar
Bentham, J. [1787]. Defence of usury. Repr. in Jeremy Bentham’s economic writings, 3 vols., ed. by Stark, W., London: Allen and Unwin with the Royal Economic Society, 1952, vol. 1, pp. 121207.Google Scholar
Berg, M. 2005. Luxury and pleasure in eighteenth century Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Berle, A. A. and Means, G. 1932. The modern corporation and private property. New York: The Commerce Clearing House.Google Scholar
Bernstein, E. 1899. Die Voraussetzungen des Sozialismus und die Aufgaben der Sozialdemokratie. Stuttgart: Dietz. English transl., Evolutionary socialism, New York: Huebsch, 1909; repr. New York: Schocken, 1961.Google Scholar
Bible. The Jerusalem Bible. London: Darton, Longman and Todd, 1966.Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1889. Kapital und Kapitalzins. Zweite Abteilung: Positive Theorie des Kapitales. Innsbruck: Verlag der Wagner’schen Universitäts-Buchhandlung. English transl., The positive theory of capital, London: Macmillan, 1891.Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, E. 1896. ‘Zum Abschluss des Marxschen Systems’, in von Boenigk, O. (ed.), Staatswissenschaftliche Arbeiten. Festgaben für Karl Knies. Berlin: Haering. English transl., Karl Marx and the close of his system, London: Fisher Unwin, 1898.Google Scholar
Boisguilbert, Pierre le Pesant de 1695. Le détail de la France. Rouen: no publisher; repr. in Institut national d’études demographiques (INED), Pierre de Boisguilbert or la naissance de l’économie politique, 2 vols., Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1966.Google Scholar
Bortkiewicz, L. 1906–7. ‘Wertrechnung und Preisrechnung im Marxschen System’, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 23 (1906) n. 1 and 25 (1907) nn. 1–2. English transl., ‘Value and price in the Marxian system’, International Economic Papers 1952, 52: 560.Google Scholar
Bortkiewicz, L. 1907. ‘Zur Berichtigung der grundlegenden theoretischen Konstruktion von Marx im dritten Band des “Kapital”’, Conrads Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, series 3, 34: 319–35. English transl., ‘On the correction of Marx’s fundamental theoretical construction in the third volume of Capital’, in Sweezy, P. (ed), Karl Marx and the close of his system. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1949.Google Scholar
Box, G. E. P. and Jenkins, J. M. 1970. Time series analysis: forecasting and control. San Francisco: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Brundtland, G. H. (ed.) 1987. Our common future (Brundtland Report, World Commission on Environment and Development). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Caldwell, B. 2004. Hayek’s challenge. An intellectual biography of F.A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Campanella, T. [1602] 1964. La città del sole. Milano: Rizzoli.Google Scholar
Cantillon, R. 1755. Essai sur la nature du commerce en général. London: Fletcher Gyles. Repr. with English transl., Essay on the nature of trade in general, ed. by Higgs, H., London: Macmillan 1931; repr., New York: M. Kelley 1964.Google Scholar
Carlyle, T. 1888–89. Works. 37 vols., London: Chapman and Hall.Google Scholar
Chamberlin, E. 1933. The theory of monopolistic competition. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Child, J. 1688. Brief observations concerning trade and interest of money. London: E. Calvert and H. Mortlock; repr. as A discourse about trade, London: A. Sowle, 1690.Google Scholar
Clapham, J. A. 1922. ‘Of empty economic boxes’, Economic Journal 32: 305–14.Google Scholar
Clark, J. B. 1899. The distribution of wealth: a theory of wages, interests and profits. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Clower, R. W. 1965. ‘The Keynesian counter-revolution: a theoretical appraisal’, in Hahn, F. H. and Brechling, F. P. R. (eds.), The theory of interest rates. London: Macmillan, pp. 103–25.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1937. ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica 4; repr. in Coase, R. H., The firm, the market and the law. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press 1988, pp. 3355.Google Scholar
Colquhoun, P. 1814. Treatise on the wealth, power and resources of the British Empire. London: J. Mawman.Google Scholar
Comte, A. 1830–42. Cours de philosophie positive. 6 vols., Paris.Google Scholar
Croce, B. and Einaudi, L. 1957. Liberismo e liberalismo. ed. by Solari, P., Milano-Napoli: Riccardo Ricciardi editore.Google Scholar
Custodi, P. 1803. ‘Notizie degli autori contenuti nel presente volume’, in Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica, parte antica, tomo 1, Milano: Destefanis.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. 1859. On the origin of species by means of natural selection. London: Murray; sixth edn., 1872.Google Scholar
Darwin, C. 1871. The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex. London: Murray; second edn., 1874.Google Scholar
David, P. 1985. ‘Clio and the economics of QWERTY’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 75: 332–7.Google Scholar
Davidson, P. 1994. Post Keynesian macroeconomic theory. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of value. An axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium. Cowles Foundation Monograph, n. 17, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
De Finetti, B. 1930. ‘Fondamenti logici del ragionamento probabilistico’, Bollettino dell’Unione matematica italiana 9: 258–61.Google Scholar
De Finetti, B. 1931. Probabilismo. Saggio critico sulla teoria delle probabilità e sul valore della scienza. Napoli: Perrella.Google Scholar
De Finetti, B. 1937. ‘La prévision, ses lois logiques, ses sources subjectives’, Annales de l’Institut Henri Poincaré 7: 168.Google Scholar
Defoe, D. 1719. The life and strange surprizing adventures of Robinson Crusoe, of York, mariner. 3 vols., London: W. Taylor.Google Scholar
De Quincey, T. 1821–22. ‘Confessions of an English opium eater’, London Magazine, Sept. 1821–Oct. 1822; repr. in volume form, 1822; second edn., 1856; repr. London: Grant Richards 1902.Google Scholar
De Quincey, T. 1824. ‘Dialogues of three templars on political economy’, London Magazine; repr. in De Quincey, T., Collected writings, ed. by Masson, D., , A. and Black, C., Edinburgh, vol. 9, repr. as Political economy and politics, New York: Augustus M. Kelley 1970, pp. 37112.Google Scholar
De Quincey, T. 1844. The logic of political economy. Edinburgh: William Blackwood and Sons; repr. in De Quincey, T., Collected writings, vol. 9, pp. 118294.Google Scholar
Descartes, R. 1637. Discours de la méthode. Leyda: I. Maire. English transl., Discourse on the method for conducting one’s reason well and for seeking truth in the sciences, Indianapolis: Hackett 1988.Google Scholar
D’Ippoliti, C. and Roncaglia, A. 2016. ‘Heterodox economics and the history of economic thought’, in Jo, T.-H. and Todorova, Z., eds, Advancing the frontiers of heterodox economics. Essays in honor of Frederick S. Lee. Abingdon and New York: Routledge, pp. 2138.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1928. Russian economic development since the revolution. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1946. Studies in the development of capitalism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1955. On economic theories and socialism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dobb, M. 1973. Theories of value and distribution since Adam Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. 1984. Technical change and industrial transformation. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. et al. 1988. Technical change and economic theory. London: Pinter.Google Scholar
Dunlop, J. T. 1938. ‘The movement of real and money wage rates’, Economic Journal 48: 413–34.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1881. Mathematical psychics. An essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences. London: C. Kegan Paul; repr. San Diego: James and Gordon 1995.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. 1925. Papers relating to political economy. 3 vols., London: Royal Economic Society; repr. New York: Burt Franklin 1970.Google Scholar
Edwards, W. 1961. ‘Behavioral decision theory’, Annual Review of Psychology 12: 473–98.Google Scholar
Eichner, A. S. 1976. The megacorp and oligopoly. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ellsberg, D. 1961. ‘Ambiguity, and the Savage axioms’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 75: 643–69.Google Scholar
Fama, E. 1970. ‘Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work’, Journal of Finance 25: 383417.Google Scholar
Ferguson, A. 1767. An essay on the history of civil society. Edinburgh: A. Kinkaid & J. Bell; repr. ed. by Forbes, D., Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press 1966.Google Scholar
Feyerabend, P. 1975. Against method. Outline of an anarchist theory of knowledge. London: New Left Books.Google Scholar
Fisher, I. 1892. Mathematical investigations in the theory of value and prices. New Haven: Transactions of the Connecticut Academy of Arts and Sciences; repr. New York: A.M. Kelley 1965.Google Scholar
Flux, A.W. 1894. ‘Review: K. Wicksell, Über Wert, Kapital und Rente; P.H. Wicksteed, An essay on the coordination of the laws of distribution’, Economic Journal 4: 305–13.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1953. Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1956. ‘The quantity theory of money. A restatement’, in Friedman, M. (ed.), Studies in the quantity theory of money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 321.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1968. ‘The role of monetary policy’, American Economic Review 58: 117.Google Scholar
Frisch, R. 1933. ‘Editorial’, Econometrica 1: 14.Google Scholar
Fuà, G. 1993. Crescita economica. Le insidie delle cifre. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Galbraith, J. K. 1955. The affluent society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, J. K. 1967. The new industrial state. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galiani, F. 1751. Della moneta. Napoli: Giuseppe Raimondi; second edn. Napoli: Stamperia simoniana 1780; repr. Milano: Feltrinelli 1963. (English transl., On money, ed. by Toscano, P. R., Ann Arbor: University Microfilm International 1977).Google Scholar
Galiani, F. 1770. Dialogues sur le commerce des blés. Londres: no publisher; repr. ed. by Nicolini, F., Milano-Napoli: Ricciardi 1959; Italian transl., Dialoghi sul commercio dei grani, Roma: Editori Riuniti 1978.Google Scholar
Galilei, G. 1623. Il Saggiatore. Roma: Giacomo Mascardi e Accademia dei Lincei; repr. in Opere, Milano-Napoli: Ricciardi 1953, pp. 89352.Google Scholar
Gårdlund, T. 1956. Knut Wicksell, rebell l det nya riket. Stockholm: Bonniers; English transl., The life of Knut Wicksell, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar 1996.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1960. Il capitale nelle teorie della distribuzione. Milano: Giuffrè.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1970. ‘Heterogeneous capital, the production function and the theory of distribution’, Review of Economic Studies 37: 407–36.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1981. Marx e gli economisti classici. Torino: Einaudi.Google Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1984. ‘Value and distribution in the classical economists and Marx’, Oxford Economic Papers 36: 291325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garegnani, P. 1990. ‘Sraffa: Classical versus Marginalist analysis’, in Bharadwaj, K. and Schefold, B. (eds.), Essays on Piero Sraffa, London: Routledge, pp. 112–41.Google Scholar
Genovesi, A. 1765–67. Delle lezioni di commercio o sia d’economia civile. 2 vols., Napoli: Fratelli Simone; repr. in Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica, ed. by Custodi, P., vols. 14–16, Milano: Destefanis, 1803.Google Scholar
Godfrey-Smith, P. 2009. Darwinian populations and natural selections. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Godley, W. and Lavoie, M. 2007. Monetary economics. An integrated approach to credit, money, income, production and wealth. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Godwin, W. 1793. Enquiry concerning political justice, and its influence on moral and happiness. London: G. G. and J. Robinson; repr. ed. by Kramnick, I., Harmondsworth: Penguin Books 1976.Google Scholar
Godwin, W. 1820. Of population. An enquiry concerning the power of increase in the numbers of mankind, being an answer to mr. Malthus’s essay on that subject. London: Longman, Hurst, Rees, Orme and Brown.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1967. ‘A growth cycle’, in Feinstein, C. H. (ed.), Socialism, capitalism and economic growth. Essays presented to Maurice Dobb, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 5458.Google Scholar
Goodwin, R. M. 1990. Chaotic economic dynamics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Gossen, H. H. 1854. Entwickelung der Gesetze des menschlichen Verkehrs, und der daraus fliessenden Regeln für menschliches Handeln. Brunswick: Vieweg; second edn. Berlin: Prager 1889. English transl., The laws of human relations and the rules of human action derived therefrom, ed. by Georgescu-Roegen, N., Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press 1983.Google Scholar
Gray, J. 1825. A lecture on human happiness. Philadelphia: D. & S. Neall.Google Scholar
Graziani, A. 2003. The monetary theory of production. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Haavelmo, T. 1944. ‘The probability approach in econometrics’, Econometrica 12 (Supplement): 1118.Google Scholar
Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (eds) 2001. Varieties of capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, A. 1938. Full recovery or stagnation?. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Harcourt, G. C. 2006. The structure of post-Keynesian economics. The core contributions of the pioneers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrod, R.F. 1930. ‘Notes on supply’, Economic Journal 40: 232–41.Google Scholar
Harrod, R.F. 1939. ‘An essay in dynamic theory’, Economic Journal 49: 1433.Google Scholar
Harrod, R.F. 1951. The life of John Maynard Keynes. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Harrod, R.F. 1961. ‘Review of P. Sraffa, Production of commodities by means of commodities’, Economic Journal 71: 78387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harvey, W. 1628. Exercitatio anatomica de motu cordis et sanguinis. Francoforti: G. Fitzeri. English transl., The anatomical exercises, ed. by Keynes, G., New York: Dover Publications 1995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawtrey, R. G. 1919. Currency and credit. London: Longmans.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. 1931. Prices and production. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. 1932. ‘Money and capital: a reply’, Economic Journal 42: 237–49.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (ed.). 1935. Collectivist economic planning. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. 1944. The road to serfdom. Chicago: Chicago University Press; repr. (with an introduction by Friedman, M.) 1994.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. 1994. Hayek on Hayek, ed. by Kresge, S. and Wenar, L., Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. et al. (eds.), 2004. Foundations of human sociality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Heukelom, F. 2014. Behavioral economics: a history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. 1937. ‘Mr. Keynes and the classics: a suggested interpretation’, Econometrica 5: 147–59.Google Scholar
Hilferding, R. 1910. Das Finanzkapital. Wien: Wiener Volksbuchhandlung Ignaz Brand. English transl., Finance capital: a study of the latest phase of capitalist development, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul 1981.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. 1977. The passions and the interests. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. 1982. ‘Rival interpretations of market society: civilizing, destructive, or feeble?’, Journal of Economic Literature 20: 1463–84.Google Scholar
Hobbes, T. 1651. Leviathan. London: Andrew Crooke; repr. ed. by Macpherson, C. B., Harmondsworth: Penguin Books 1968, repr. 1987.Google Scholar
Hobson, J. 1902. Imperialism: a study. London: Nisbet.Google Scholar
Hodgskin, T. 1825. Labour defended against the claims of capital or the unproductiveness of capital proved. London: Knight and Lacey; repr. London: Hammersmith Bookshop 1964.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G.M. 1988. Economics and institutions. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G.M. 1998. ‘The approach of institutional economics’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36: 166–92.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 1739–40. A treatise of human nature. 3 vols., London: John Noon; repr. Oxford: Clarendon Press 1978; repr. Bristol: Thoemmes 1990.Google Scholar
Hume, D. [1740] 1938. An abstract of a treatise on human nature. With an introduction and ed. by Keynes, J. M. and Sraffa, P., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 1752. Political discourses. Edinburgh: A. Kincaid and A. Donaldson; repr. in Essays: moral, political, and literary, ed. by Miller, E. F., Indianapolis: Liberty Press 1987.Google Scholar
Huntington, S.P. 1996. The clash of civilization and the remaking of the world order. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hutcheson, F. 1755. A system of moral philosophy. 3 vols., London: A. Millar.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1865. The coal question. London: Macmillan; repr. New York: Augustus M. Kelley 1965.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1871. The theory of political economy. London: Macmillan; second edn. 1879; repr. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books 1970.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1874. The principles of science: a treatise on logic and scientific method. London: Macmillan; second edn. 1877.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1881. ‘Richard Cantillon and the nationality of political economy’, Contemporary Review, January; repr. in Cantillon, R., Essai sur la nature du commerce en général, ed. by Higgs, H., London: Macmillan, 1931 (repr. New York: Kelley, 1964), pp. 333–60.Google Scholar
Kahn, R.F. [1929] 1983. L’economia del breve periodo. ed. by Dardi, M., Torino: Boringhieri; English edn., The economics of the short period. New York: St. Martin’s Press 1989.Google Scholar
Kahn, R.F. 1931. ‘The relation of home investment to unemployment’, Economic Journal 41: 173–98; repr. in Kahn, , 1972, pp. 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahn, R.F. 1972. Selected essays on employment and growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. 1979. ‘Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk’, Econometrica 47: 313–27.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1942. ‘Professor Hayek and the concertina effect’, Economica. 9: 359–82.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1956. ‘Alternative theories of distribution’, Review of Economic Studies 23: 94100.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1957. ‘A model of economic growth’, Economic Journal 67: 591624.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1961. ‘Capital accumulation and economic growth’, in Lutz, F. A. (ed.), The theory of capital, London: Macmillan, pp. 177220.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1966. ‘Marginal productivity and the macro-economic theories of distribution’, Review of Economic Studies 33: 309–19.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. 1943. Studies in economic dynamics. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. 1971. Selected essays on the dynamics of the capitalist economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M. 1972. Selected essays on the economic growth of the socialist and the mixed economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kautilya, [fourth century BC] 1967. Arthaśāstra. ed. by Shamasastri, R., Mysore: Mysore Printing and Publishing House.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1913. Indian currency and finance. London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 1, London: Macmillan 1971.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1919. The economic consequences of the peace. London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 2, London: Macmillan 1971.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1921. A treatise on probability. London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 8, London: Macmillan 1973.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1923. A tract on monetary reform. London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 4, London: Macmillan 1971. (Italian transl., ed. by Sraffa, P., La riforma monetaria, Milano: Fratelli Treves 1925).Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1925. The economic consequences of Mr. Churchill. London: Hogarth Press; repr. in Keynes, 1931, pp. 207–30 and in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 9, pp. 272–94.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1930. A treatise on money. 2 vols., London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vols. 5 and 6, London: Macmillan 1971.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1931. Essays in persuasion. London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J.M., Collected writings, vol. 9, London: Macmillan 1972.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1933. Essays in biography. London: Macmillan; repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 10, London: Macmillan 1972.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan. (Repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 7, London: Macmillan 1973).Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1937. ‘The general theory of employment’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 51: 200–23, repr. in Keynes, 1973, vol. 14, pp. 109–23.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1940. How to pay for the war. London: Macmillan. (Repr. in Keynes, J. M., Collected writings, vol. 9, London: Macmillan 1972, pp. 367439).Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1973. The General Theory and after. In Collected writings, vols. 13 (Part I: preparation) and 14 (Part II: defence and development), ed. by Moggridge, D., London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. N. 1891. The scope and method of political economy. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. 1978. Manias, panics and crashes. A history of financial crisis. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. 1921. Risk, uncertainty and profit. Boston: Hart, Schaffner & Marx; repr. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Kregel, J. A. 1976. ‘Economic methodology in the face of uncertainty. The modelling methods of Keynes and the post-Keynesians’, Economic Journal 86: 209–25.Google Scholar
Krugman, P.R. 1990. Rethinking international trade. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kuhn, T. S. 1962. The structure of scientific revolutions. Princeton: Princeton University Press; second edn. 1970.Google Scholar
Kula, W. 1958. Rozwazania o historii. Warszawa: Państwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe. Italian transl., Riflessioni sulla storia, Venezia: Marsilio 1990. (English transl., The problems and methods of economic history, Aldershot: Ashgate 2001).Google Scholar
Kula, W. 1970. Miary i ludzie. Warszawa: Państwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe. English transl. Measures and men, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lafargue, P. 1880. ‘Le droit à la paresse’, L’égalité; repr. Paris: Maspero 1969. English transl., The right to be lazy, Chicago: C.H. Kerr 1989.Google Scholar
Lakatos, I. 1978. The methodology of scientific research programmes. Philosophical papers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lange, O. 1936–37. ‘On the economic theory of socialism’, Review of Economic Studies 4: 5371 and 123–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. 1968. On Keynesian economics and the economics of Keynes. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lenin, 1916. English transl., Imperialism, the highest stage of capitalism, London: Junius 1996.Google Scholar
Leontief, W. 1941. The structure of the American economy, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press; second edn. 1951.Google Scholar
Levhari, D. 1965. ‘A nonsubstitution theorem and switching of techniques’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 79: 98105.Google Scholar
Levhari, D. and Samuelson, P. 1966. ‘The nonswitching theorem is false’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 518–19.Google Scholar
List, F. 1841. Das nationale System der politischen Oekonomie. Stuttgard: J.G. Cotta. English transl., The national system of political economy, ed. by Lloyd, S. S., London: Longmans, Greene and Co. 1909.Google Scholar
Lloyd, W. F. 1837. Lectures on population, value, poor laws and rent. London; repr. New York: A.M. Kelley 1968.Google Scholar
Locke, J. 1690. Two treatises of government. London: Awnsham and John Churchill; critical edn., ed. by Laslett, P., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1960; edn. quoted, London: J.M. Dent (Everyman’s Library) 1975.Google Scholar
Locke, J. 1692. Some considerations on the consequences of the lowering of interest, and raising the value of money. London: A. and J. Churchill; repr. in Locke on money, 2 vols., ed. by Kelly, P.H., Oxford: Clarendon Press 1991.Google Scholar
Longfield, M. 1834. Lectures on political economy. Dublin: R. Milliken & Son.Google Scholar
Longfield, M. 1835. Three lectures on commerce, and one on absenteeism. Dublin: William Curry, Junior & Co.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. 1972. ‘Expectations and the neutrality of money’, Journal of Economic Theory 4: 103–24.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. 1976. ‘Econometric policy evaluation: a critique’, in Brenner, K. and Meltzer, A. M. (ed.), The Phillips curve and labor markets, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 1946.Google Scholar
Luxemburg, R. 1913. Die Akkumulation des Kapitals. Ein Beitrag zur ökonomischen Erklärung des Imperialismus. Berlin: Paul Singer. Italian transl., L’accumulazione del capitale, Torino: Einaudi 1960; repr. 1968. English transl., The accumulation of capital, London: Routledge 2003.Google Scholar
Machiavelli, N. [1513] 1960. Il principe. Milano: Feltrinelli. English transl., The prince, ed. by Adams, R. M., New York: Norton 1992.Google Scholar
Maifreda, G. 2012. From oikonomia to political economy. Farnham: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Malinvaud, E. 1977. The theory of unemployment reconsidered. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Malthus, T. R. 1798. An essay on the principle of population as it affects the future improvement of society. London; second edn., 1803; critical edn., ed. by James, P., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1989.Google Scholar
Malthus, T. R. 1800. An investigation of the cause of the present high price of provisions. London: J. Johnson.Google Scholar
Malthus, T. R. 1820. Principles of political economy. London: John Murray; second edn., London: William Pickering 1836; repr. New York: Augustus M. Kelley 1964.Google Scholar
Mandeville, B. 1714. The fable of the bees, or private vices, public benefits. London: J. Roberts; critical edn., ed. by Haye, F. B., Oxford: Clarendon Press 1924; repr. Indianapolis: Liberty Press 1988.Google Scholar
Mann, T. 1901. Buddenbrooks. Verfall einer Familie. München: Fisher.Google Scholar
Marcuse, H. 1956. One-dimensional man. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Marcuzzo, M. C. 2012. Fighting market failure. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Marris, R. 1964. The economic theory of ‘managerial’ capitalism. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1872. ‘Mr. Jevons’s Theory of political economy’, Academy, 1 April; repr. in Marshall 1925, pp. 93100.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1879a. The economics of industry. London: Macmillan. (Italian transl., Economia della produzione, Milano: Isedi 1975).Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1879b. The pure theory of foreign trade. The pure theory of domestic values. Cambridge: Privately printed.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1890. Principles of economics. London: Macmillan; eighth edn., 1920; critical edn., ed. by Guillebaud, C. W., 2 vols., London: Macmillan 1961.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1892. Elements of economics of industry. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1919. Industry and trade. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1923. Money, credit, and commerce. London: Macmillan; repr., Fairfield: Augustus M. Kelley 1991.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1925. Memoirs. ed. by Pigou, A.C., London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1926. Official papers. ed. by Keynes, J.M., London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1996a. The correspondence of Alfred Marshall economist. ed. by Whitaker, J. K., 3 vols., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. and , M. P. 1996b. Official papers of Alfred Marshall. A supplement. ed. by Groenewegen, P., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marx, K. [1844] 1932. Ökonomisch-philosophische Manuskripte aus dem Jahre 1844. In Karl Marx – Friedrich Engels Historisc-kritische Gesamtausgabe, ed. by Adoratskij, V., Berlin: Marx-Engels Gesamtausgabe (MEGA). English transl., ‘Economic and philosophical manuscripts’, in Marx, K., Early writings, ed. by Bottomore, T. B., London: C.A. Watts & Co. 1963, pp. 61219.Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1847. Misère de la philosophie. Réponse à la philosophie de la misère de M. Proudhon. Paris: A. Frank, and Bruxelles: C. G. Vogler. English transl., The poverty of philosophy, Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House 1962.Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1859. Zur Kritik der Politischen Ökonomie. Berlin: Dietz. English transl., Contributions to the critique of political economy, London: Lawrence & Wishart 1970; passages quoted from Marx and Engels 1959, pp. 83–7.Google Scholar
Marx, K. [1865] 1898, Value, price and profit, ed. by Aveling, E. Marx. Chicago: Charles Kerr & Company co-operative.Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1867–94. Das Kapital. 3 vols., Hamburg: O. Meissner. English transl., Capital, London: Dent 1946 (for vols. 1 and 2) and Harmondsworth: Penguin Books 1976, repr. 1986 (for vol. 3).Google Scholar
Marx, K. 1905–10. Theorien über den Mehrwert. ed. by Kautsky, K., Stuttgart: Dietz. English transl., Theories of surplus-value, Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House and London: Lawrence and Wishart, Part 1, 1963; Part 2, 1969; Part 3, 1972.Google Scholar
Marx, K. and Engels, F. [1845] 1888. ‘Feuerbach’, appendix to Engels, F., Ludwig Feuerbach, Stuttgard: Dietz. English transl., ‘Theses on Feuerbach’, in Marx, and Engels, 1959, pp. 283–6.Google Scholar
Marx, K. and Engels, F. [1845–46] 1932. Die Deutsche Ideologie. Berlin: Marx-Engels Gesamtausgabe (MEGA). English transl., The German ideology, London: Lawrence and Wishart 1939; passages quoted from Marx and Engels 1959, pp. 287302.Google Scholar
Marx, K. and Engels, F. 1848. Manifest der Kommunistischen Partei. London: J.E. Burghard, Bildungs-Gesellschaft für Arbeiter. (Italian transl., Manifesto del partito comunista, Torino: Einaudi, fourth edn. 1966.) English transl., ‘Manifesto of the Communist Party’, in Marx and Engels 1959, pp. 4382.Google Scholar
Marx, K. and Engels, F. 1878. ‘Kritik des Gothaer Programms’, Die Neue Zeit, n. 18. English transl., ‘Critique of the Gotha programme’, in Marx, and Engels, 1959, pp. 153–73.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D. and Green, J. R. 1995. Microeconomic theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. 1985. The rhetoric of economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
McClure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G., Cohen, J. D. 2004. ‘Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards’, Science 306: 503–7.Google Scholar
McCormick, T. 2009. William Petty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
McCulloch, J.R. 1825. The principles of political economy. Edinburgh: William and Charles Tait, and London: Longmans and Co..Google Scholar
McCulloch, J.R. 1845. The literature of political economy. London: Longman, Brown, Green and Longmans; repr., Fairfield: Augustus M. Kelley 1991.Google Scholar
Meadows, D. H., Meadows, D. L., Randers, D. L. and Beherens, W. W. III 1972. The limits to growth. New York: New American Library.Google Scholar
Menger, C. 1871. Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre. Wien: Braumuller; second edn., ed. by Menger, K., 1923. English transl., Principles of economics, New York: New York University Press 1981.Google Scholar
Menger, C. 1883. Untersuchungen über die Methode der Sozialwissenschaften und der politischen Oekonomie insbesondere. Berlin: Dunker & Humblot. English transl., Problems of economics and sociology, Urbana: University of Illinois Press 1963; repr. as Investigations into the method of the social sciences with special reference to economics, New York: New York University Press 1985.Google Scholar
Menger, C. 1884. Die Irrthümer des Historismus in den deutschen Nationalökonomie. Wien: Hölder; Italian transl., Gli errori dello storicismo, Milano: Rusconi 1991.Google Scholar
Mill, J. 1821. Elements of political economy. London: Baldwin, Cradock and Joy; repr. in Mill, J., Selected economic writings, pp. 203366.Google Scholar
Mill, J. 1843. A system of logic. 2 vols., London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1844. Essays on some unsettled questions of political economy. London: John W. Parker; second edn., 1874; repr. Clifton: Augustus M. Kelley, 1974.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1848. Principles of political economy. London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1859. On liberty. London: J.W. Parker. Repr. Northbrook (Ill.): AHM Publishing Co. 1947.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1861. ‘Utilitarianism’, Fraser’s Magazine 64: 383–4; repr. in Mill, J. S. and Bentham, J., Utilitarianism and other essays, Ryan, A. ed., London: Penguin Books 1987, pp. 272338.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1982. Can ‘it’ happen again? Essays on instability and finance, Armonk (N.Y.): Sharpe.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. 1993. ‘Schumpeter and finance’, in Biasco, S., Roncaglia, A. and Salvati, M. (eds.), Market and institutions in economic development. Houndmills: Macmillan, pp. 103–15.Google Scholar
Mirabeau (Victor Riqueti, marquis de) 1756. L’ami des hommes. Avignon: no publisher.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. 2002. Machine dreams. Economics becomes a cyborg science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. 2012. Science-Mart. Privatizing American science. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Mises, L. 1920. ‘Die Wirtschaftsrechnung im Sozialistischen Gemeinwesen’, Arkiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 47: 86121. (English transl. in Hayek, (ed.) 1935).Google Scholar
Mishan, E. J. 1967. The costs of economic growth. London: Staples Press.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. 1944. ‘Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money’, Econometrica 12: 4588.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. 1963. ‘The monetary mechanism and its interaction with real phenomena’, Review of Economics and Statistics 45 (Supplement): 79107.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. 1958. ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment’, American Economic Review 48: 161–97.Google Scholar
Moggridge, D. E. 1992. Maynard Keynes. An economist’s biography. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Montchrétien, A. 1615. Traité de l’oeconomie politique. Paris; critical edn., ed. by Billacois, F., Genève: Droz 1999.Google Scholar
More, T. 1516. Utopia. Louvain: T. Martens. English transl., Utopia, in The complete works of St. Thomas More, vol. 4, ed. by Surtz, E. and Hexter, J. H., New Haven: Yale University Press 1965; repr. 1979.Google Scholar
Murphy, A. E. 1986. Richard Cantillon: entrepreneur and economist. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Muth, J. F. 1961. ‘Rational expectations and the theory of price movements’, Econometrica 29: 315–35.Google Scholar
Nash, J. F. 1950. ‘Equilibrium points in N-person games’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences (USA) 36: 48–9.Google Scholar
Neisser, H. 1932. ‘Lohnhohe und beschäftigungsgrad in Marktgleichgewicht’, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 36: 415–55.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. 1995. ‘Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change’, Journal of Economic Literature 33: 4890.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Neumann, J. 1937. ‘Über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes’, in Menger, K. (ed.), Ergebrisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums, 1935–36, vol. 8, pp. 7383, Wien: Deuticke. English transl., ‘A model of general economic equilibrium’, Review of Economic Studies 13 (1945): 19.Google Scholar
Neumann, J. and Morgenstern, O. 1944. Theory of games and economic behaviour. Princeton: Princeton University Press; second edn. 1947; third edn. 1953.Google Scholar
Ortes, G. 1790. Riflessioni sulla popolazione delle nazioni in rapporto all’economia nazionale. Firenze: no publisher, repr. in Custodi, P. (ed.), Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica, Parte moderna, vol. 24, Milano: Destefanis 1804, pp. 5111.Google Scholar
Owen, R. 1813. A new view of society. London: Cadell and Davies; repr. in Owen, R., Report to the county of Lanark. A new view of society. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books 1970, pp. 85198.Google Scholar
Owen, R. 1820. Report to the county of Lanark. Lanark, 1 May; repr. in Owen 1857–58, vol. 2, pp. 261310; repr. in Owen, R., Report to the county of Lanark. A new view of society, pp. 199270.Google Scholar
Owen, R. 1857–58. The life of Robert Owen, written by himself. 2 vols., London: Effingham Wilson; repr. Fairfield: Augustus M. Kelley 1977.Google Scholar
Pantaleoni, M. 1889. Principii di economia pura. Firenze: G. Barbera; second edn. 1894. English transl., Pure economics, London: Macmillan 1898.Google Scholar
Pantaleoni, M. 1898. ‘Dei criteri che devono informare la storia delle dottrine economiche’, Giornale degli economisti, 4 novembre, repr. in Pantaleoni 1925, pp. 211–45.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1896. ‘La courbe de la répartition de la richesse’, in Recueil publié par la Faculté de Droit de l’Université de Lausanne à l’occasion de l’Exposition nationale de 1896, pp. 373–87. Italian transl., La curva di ripartizione della ricchezza, in Corsi, M. (ed.), Le diseguaglianze economiche, Torino: Giappichelli 1995, pp. 5170.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1896–97. Cours d’économie politique. 2 vols., Lausanne: F. Rouge.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1901–2. Les systèmes socialistes. 2 vols., Paris: Giard et Briére; second edn. 1926.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1906. Manuale di economia politica. Milano: Società editrice libraria; repr. Roma: Bizzarri 1965.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1916. Trattato di sociologia generale. 2 vols., Firenze: Barbera; repr. Roma: Bizzarri 1964.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1960. ‘A mathematical formulation of the Ricardian system’, Review of Economic Studies 27: 7898 (repr. in Pasinetti 1974).Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1962. ‘Rate of profit and income distribution in relation to the rate of economic growth’, Review of Economic Studies 29: 267–79 (repr. in Pasinetti 1974).Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1965. ‘A new theoretical approach to the problems of economic growth’, Academiae Pontificiae Scientiarum Scripta Varia, n. 28: 571696.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1966. ‘Changes in the rate of profits and switches of techniques’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 503–17.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1969. ‘Switches of technique and the “rate of return” in capital theory’, Economic Journal 79: 508–31.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1973. ‘The notion of vertical integration in economic analysis’, Metroeconomica 25: 129.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1975. Lezioni di teoria della produzione. Bologna: Il Mulino. English transl., Lectures in the theory of production, London: Macmillan, 1977.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1981. Structural change and economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Perrotta, C. 2004. Consumption as an investment: I. On the fear of goods from Hesiod to Adam Smith. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1662. A treatise of taxes and contributions. London: N. Brooke; repr. in Petty 1899, pp. 197.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1690. Political arithmetick. London: Robert Clavel and Henry Mortlock; repr. in Petty 1899, pp. 233313.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1691a. The political anatomy of Ireland. London: D. Brown and W. Rogers; repr. in Petty 1899, pp. 121231.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1691b. Verbum sapienti. In appendix to Petty, W. 1691a; repr. in Petty 1899, pp. 99120.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1899. Economic writings. ed. by Hull, C., 2 vols., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; repr. New York: Augustus M. Kelley 1963.Google Scholar
Petty, W. 1927. Papers. 2 vols., ed. by Lansdowne, H., London: Constable.Google Scholar
Phelps, E. S. 1967. ‘Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time’, Economica 34: 254–81.Google Scholar
Phillips, A. W. 1958. ‘The relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957’, Economica 25: 283–99.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. 1912. Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan; new ed., The Economics of Welfare, London: Macmillan 1920.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. 1922. ‘Empty economic boxes: a reply’, Economic Journal 32: 458–65.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. 1927. Industrial fluctuations. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. 1933. The theory of unemployment. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. 1950. Keynes’s General Theory: a retrospective view. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Piore, M. and Sabel, C. 1984. The second industrial divide. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Plato, 1930. The republic. Books 1–5 (vol. 1), with an English transl. by Shorey, P., The Loeb Classic Library, London: Heinemann and Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Poitras, G. 2000. The early history of financial economics, 1478–1776. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Popper, K.R. 1934. Logik der Forschnung. Wien: Springer. enlarged English edn., The logic of scientific discovery, London: Hutchison 1959.Google Scholar
Popper, K.R. 1945. The open society and its enemies. 2 vols., London: Routledge and Kegan Paul; fifth edn., 1966.Google Scholar
Popper, K.R. 1969. Conjectures and refutations. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Postlethwayt, M. 1751–55. Universal dictionary of trade and commerce. London: W. Strahan.Google Scholar
Pownall, T. 1776. A letter from Governor Pownall to Adam Smith, L.L.D. F.R.S., being an examination of several points of doctrine, laid down in his ‘Inquiry in to the nature and causes of the wealth of nations’. London; repr. New York: Augustus M. Kelley 1967; repr. in Smith 1977, pp. 337–76.Google Scholar
Proudhon, P.-J. 1840. Qu’est-ce que la propriété?. Paris: Brocard. English transl., What is property? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1994.Google Scholar
Quesnay, F. 1758–59. Tableau économique. Paris (first edn., 1758; second edn., 1759; third edn., 1759). Repr. with an English transl. in Kuczynski, M. and Meek, R. L., Quesnay’s tableau économique, London: Macmillan and New York: Kelley 1972.Google Scholar
, 1959. Committee on the working of the monetary system, Report, London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Ramsey, F. P. 1931. The foundations of mathematics. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Raphael, D. D. 2007. The impartial spectator. Adam Smith’s moral philosophy. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Ravix, J. and Romani, P.-M. eds. 1997. Turgot. Formation et distribution des richesses. Paris: Flammarion.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1971. A theory of justice. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Reinert, S. A. 2011. Translating empire. Emulation and the origins of political economy. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Remak, R. 1929. ‘Kann die Volkswirtschaftslehre eine exakte Wissenschaft werden?’, Jahrbucher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 131: 703–36.Google Scholar
Ricardo, D. 1951–55. Works and correspondence. 10 vols., ed. by Sraffa, P., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (vol. 11, Indexes, 1973).Google Scholar
Rickett, W. A. 1985–98. Guanzi. 2 vols., Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1928. ‘The representative firm’, Economic Journal 38: 387404.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. 1932. An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1915. A study of industrial fluctuations. London: P.S. King & Son; repr., London School of Economics and Political Science 1948.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1924. ‘Those empty boxes’, Economic Journal 34: 1630.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1926. Banking policy and the price level. An essay in the theory of trade cycle. London: King and Son.Google Scholar
Robertson, D. 1930. ‘The trees of the forest’, Economic Journal 40: 8089.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1933. The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan; second edn. 1969.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1953. ‘The production function and the theory of capital’, Review of Economic Studies 21: 81106.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1956. The accumulation of capital. London: Macmillan; third edn. 1969.Google Scholar
Romer, P. 1986. ‘Increasing returns and long-run growth’, Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–37.Google Scholar
Romer, P. 1990b. ‘Is the notion of long-period positions compatible with classical political economy?’, Political Economy 6: 103–11.Google Scholar
Romer, P. 2009a, ‘Keynes and probability: an assessment’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 16: 485510.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1975. Sraffa e la teoria dei prezzi. Roma-Bari: Laterza; second edn., 1981. English transl. Sraffa and the theory of prices, Chichester: Wiley 1977.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1977. Petty: la nascita dell’economia politica. Milano: Etas Libri. English transl. Petty. The origins of political economy, Armonk: Sharpe 1985.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1990a. ‘Le scuole sraffiane’, in Becattini, (ed.), Il pensiero economico: temi, problemi e scuole. Torino: Utet, pp. 233–74. English transl., ‘The Sraffian schools’, Review of Political Economy 1991, 3: 187–219.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 1990b. ‘Is the notion of long-period positions compatible with classical political economy?’, Political Economy 6: 103–11.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2005a. The wealth of ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2005b. Il mito della mano invisibile. Roma-Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2009a, ‘Keynes and probability: an assessment’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 16: 485510.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2009b, Piero Sraffa. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. 2015. ‘Institutions, resources and the common weal’, in Baranzini, M., Rotondi, C. and Scazzieri, R. eds. Resources, production and structural dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 259–78.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, A. and Tonveronachi, M. 2015. ‘Post-Keynesian, post-Sraffian economics: an outline’, in Papadimitriou, D. (ed.), Contributions to economic theory, policy, development and finance. Essays in honor of Jan A. Kregel. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 4064.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, N. and Birdzell, L.E. 1986. How the West grew rich. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Rossi, E. 1946. Abolire la miseria. La fiaccola; repr. ed. by Sylos Labini, P., Roma-Bari: Laterza 1977.Google Scholar
Rostow, W. W. 1960. The stages of economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Russell, B. and Whitehead, A. N. 1910–13. Principia mathematica. 3 vols., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. 1947. Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. 1948. Economics. New York: Mc Graw Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. 1962. ‘Parable and realism in capital theory: the surrogate production function’, Review of Economic Studies 29: 193206.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. 1966. ‘A summing up’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 568–83.Google Scholar
Savage, L. J. 1954. The foundation of statistics. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Savary, J. 1675. Le parfait negociant. Paris: Louis Billaine; repr., Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen 1993.Google Scholar
Say, J. B. 1803. Traité d’économie politique. Paris: Deterville. English transl., A treatise on political economy, New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers 2000.Google Scholar
Schabas, M. 1990. A world ruled by numbers. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1908. Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen Nationalökonomie. München-Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. Italian transl., L’essenza e i principi dell’economia teorica, Roma-Bari: Laterza 1982.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1912. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. München-Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot; second edn. 1926; third edn. 1931; fourth edn. 1935. English edn. The theory of economic development. Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press 1934; repr. New York: Oxford University Press 1961.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1914. ‘Epochen der Dogmen- und Methodengeschichte’, in Grundriss der Sozialökonomie, Tübingen: Mohr, first part, pp. 19124. English transl., Economic doctrine and method: an historical sketch. London: Allen & Unwin and New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1928. ‘The instability of capitalism’, Economic Journal 38: 361–86.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1939. Business cycles. A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. 2 vols., New York and London: McGraw Hill; repr., Philadelphia: Porcupine Press 1982. (Partial repr. ed. by Fels, R., New York and London: McGraw Hill 1964.)Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harpers & Bro.; second edn. 1947; third edn. 1950; fourth edn. 1954; fifth edn. 1976; repr. London: Routledge 1994.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1946. ‘L’avenir de l’entreprise privée devant les tendences socialistes modernes’, in Comment sauvegarder l’entreprise privée, Editions Association Professionelle des Industriels, Canada, pp. 103–08.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1954. History of economic analysis. ed. by Schumpeter, E. Boody, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. 1970. Das Wesen Des Geldes, ed. by Mann, F.K.. Göttingen: Vanderlök & Ruprecht; English transl., Treatise on money. Aalten: Wordbridge, 2014.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1984. Resources, values and development. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 1991. Money and value: on the etics and economics of finance. Roma: Edizioni dell’Elefante.Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2009. The idea of justice. London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Senior, W. N. 1827. An introductory lecture on political economy. London: J. Mawman.Google Scholar
Senior, W. N. 1836. An outline of the science of political economy. London: W. Cloves and Sons.Google Scholar
Senior, W. N. 1837. Letters on the Factory Act. London: B. Fellowes.Google Scholar
Serra, A. 1613. Breve trattato delle cause che possono far abbondare li regni d’oro, e argento, dove non sono miniere. Con applicatione al Regno di Napoli. Napoli: L. Scorriggio; repr., Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen GmbH 1994. English transl., ed. by Reinert, S.. A short treatise on the wealth and poverty of nations. London: Anthem Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Shove, G. F. 1928. ‘Varying costs and marginal net products’, Economic Journal 38: 258–66.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1957. Models of man. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. 1979. Models of thought. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. 1980. ‘Macroeconomics and reality’, Econometrica 48: 148.Google Scholar
Sims, C. A. 1982. ‘Policy analysis with econometric models’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, n. 1: 107–64.Google Scholar
Sismondi, S. 1819. Nouveaux principes d’économie politique, ou De la richesse dans ses rapports avec la population. Paris: Delaunay; second edn., Paris: Treuttel et Würst 1827. English transl., New principles of political economy. New Brunswick (N.J.): Transaction Publishers 1991.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 1983. John Maynard Keynes. Hopes betrayed. 1883–1920. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 1992. John Maynard Keynes. The economist as saviour, 1920–1937. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 2000. John Maynard Keynes. Fighting for Britain, 1937–1946. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 2010. Keynes. A very short introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1759. The theory of moral sentiments. London: A. Millar; critical edn., ed. by Raphael, D.D. and Macfie, A.L., Oxford: Oxford University Press 1976.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell; critical edn., ed. by Campbell, R.H. and Skinner, A.S., Oxford: Oxford University Press 1976.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1795. Essays on philosophical subjects. London: T. Cadell and W. Davies; critical edn., ed. by Wightman, W.P.D. and Bryce, J.C., Oxford: Oxford University Press 1980.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1977. Correspondence. ed. by Mossner, E. C. and Ross, I. S., Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1978. Lectures on jurisprudence. ed. by Meek, R. L., Raphael, D. D. and Stein, P. G., Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1983. Lectures on rhetoric and belles lettres. Ed. by Bryce, J. C., Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. 1956. ‘A contribution to the theory of economic growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 79: 6594.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. 1957. ‘Technical change and the aggregate production function’, Review of Economics and Statistics 39: 312–20.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. 1963. Capital theory and the rate of return. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Solow, R.M. 1967. ‘The interest rate and transition between techniques’, in Feinstein, C.H. (ed.), Socialism, capitalism and economic growth. Essays presented to Maurice Dobb, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 30–9.Google Scholar
Spaventa, L. 1968. ‘Realism without parables in capital theory’, in Récherches récentes sur la fonction de production, Centre d’études et de récherches universitaire de Namur, p. 1545.Google Scholar
Spence, W. 1807. Britain independent of commerce. London: T. Cadell and W. Davies.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1920. L’inflazione monetaria in Italia durante e dopo la guerra. Milano: Scuola tipografica salesiana. English transl., ‘Monetary inflation in Italy during and after the war’, Cambridge Journal of Economics 1993, 17: 7–26.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1922a. ‘The bank crisis in Italy’, Economic Journal 32: 178–97.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1922b. ‘Italian banking today’, Manchester Guardian Commercial. The reconstrucion of Europe, 7 December, n. 11: 675–76.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1925. ‘Sulle relazioni fra costo e quantità prodotta’, Annali di economia 2: 277328. English transl., ‘On the relations between cost and quantity produced’, Italian Economic Papers, 1998, 3: 323–63.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1926. ‘The laws of returns under competitive conditions’, Economic Journal 36: 535–50.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1930. ‘A criticism’ and ‘A Rejoinder’, in ‘Symposium on increasing returns and the representative firm’, Economic Journal 40: 8993.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1932. ‘Dr. Hayek on money and capital’ and ‘A rejoinder’, Economic Journal 42: 4253, 249–51.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1951. ‘Introduction’, in Ricardo, D., 1951–55, vol. I, pp. xiiilxii.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of commodities by means of commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1962. ‘Production of commodities: a comment’, Economic Journal 72: 477–79.Google Scholar
Stackelberg, H. 1933. ‘Zwei kritische Bemerkungen zur Preistheorie Gustav Cassel’, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4.Google Scholar
Steindl, J. 1945. Small and big business. Economic problems of the size of firms. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; new Italian edn., Piccola e grande impresa. Problemi economici della dimensione dell’impresa, Milano: Franco Angeli 1991.Google Scholar
Steindl, J. 1952. Maturity and stagnation in American capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; repr. New York: Monthly Review Press 1976.Google Scholar
Steindl, J. 1990. Economic papers, 1941–88. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Steuart, J. 1767. An inquiry into the principles of political oeconomy. 2 vols., London: A. Millar and T. Cadell; critical edn., ed. by Skinner, A. S., Edinburgh and London: Oliver and Boyd 1966.Google Scholar
Stewart, D. 1794. ‘Account of the life and writings of Adam Smith LL. D.’, Transactions of the Royal Society of Edinburgh 3: 55137; repr. in Smith 1795 (1980), pp. 269332.Google Scholar
Sweezy, P. 1942. The theory of capitalist development. NewYork: Monthly Review Press; repr. 1968.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1954. ‘Il problema dello sviluppo economico in Marx ed in Schumpeter’, in Papi, G.U. (ed.), Teoria dello sviluppo economico, Milano: Giuffrè. English transl., ‘The problem of economic growth in Marx and Schumpeter’, in Sylos Labini, 1984, pp. 3778.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1956. Oligopolio e progresso tecnico. Milano: Giuffrè; fourth edn. Torino: Einaudi 1967. English transl., Oligopoly and technical progress, Cambridge (Mass.): Harvard University Press 1962; second edn., 1969.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1972. Sindacati, inflazione e produttività. Roma-Bari: Laterza. English transl., Trade unions, inflation and productivity, Westmead: Saxon House 1974.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1974. Saggio sulle classi sociali. Roma-Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1976. ‘Competition: the product markets’, in Wilson, and Skinner, (eds.), pp. 200–32.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 1984. The forces of economic growth and decline. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press.Google Scholar
Sylos Labini, P. 2000. Sottosviluppo. Una strategia di riforme. Roma-Bari: Laterza. English transl., Underdevelopment. A strategy for reform, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 2001.Google Scholar
Tagliacozzo, G. (ed.) 1937. Economisti napoletani dei sec. XVII e XVIII. Bologna: Cappelli.Google Scholar
Tarshis, L. 1939. ‘Changes in real and money wages’, Economic Journal 49: 150–4.Google Scholar
Aquinas, Thomas 1265–73. Summa theologiae. repr. in 5 vols., Roma 1962.Google Scholar
Thompson, W. 1824. An inquiry into the principles of the distribution of wealth most conducive to human happiness. London: Longman, Hurst, Rees, Orme, Brown and Green-Wheatley and Adlard.Google Scholar
Thornton, H. 1802. Enquiry into the nature and effects of the paper credit of Great Britain. London: Hatchard; repr. ed. by Hayek, F., London School of Economics, 1939.Google Scholar
Thünen, J. H. 1826–50. Der isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und Nationalökonomie. Part one, Hamburg: Perthes 1826; Part two, Rostock: Leopold 1850; Part three, Rostock: Leopold 1850 and 1863. English transl. of Part one, Isolated state, ed. by Hall, P., Oxford: Pergamon Press 1966.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. 1988. The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press.Google Scholar
Tonveronachi, M. 1983. J. M. Keynes. Dall’instabilità ciclica all’equilibrio di sottoccupazione. Roma: NIS.Google Scholar
Tooke, T. 1838–57. History of prices, 1793–1856. 6 vols., London: Longman, Orme, Brown, Green & Longmans.Google Scholar
Tooke, T. 1844. An inquiry into the currency principle. London: Longman, Brown, Green & Longmans; repr., Series of reprints of scarce works in political economy, n. 15, London School of Economics and Political Sciences 1959.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1808. The economists refuted. Dublin: LaGrange and London: S.A. Oddy.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1815. An essay on the external corn trade. London: J. Hatchard.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1817. ‘A paper on the means of reducing the poors rates and of affording effectual and permanent relief to the labouring classes’, The Pamphleteer n. 20: 509–28.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1818. ‘Strictures on Mr. Ricardo’s doctrine respecting exchangeable value’, Edinburgh Magazine, Oct., pp. 335–38.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1821. An essays on the production of wealth. London: Longman, Rees, Orme, Brown, & Longmans.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1835. Colonization of South Australia. London: Longman, Rees, Orme, Brown & Green.Google Scholar
Tugan-Baranovsky, M. J. 1905. Theoretische Grundlagen des Marxismus. Leipzig: Dunker & Humblot.Google Scholar
Turgot, A.-R.-J. [1759]. ‘Éloge de Vincent de Gournai’, Mercure de France; repr. in Ravix and Romani 1997, pp. 123–53.Google Scholar
Turgot, A.-R.-J. [1766]. Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses. Publ. in 1769–70 in Ephémérides du citoyen with changes introduced by DuPont de Nemours; original text in Schelle, 1913–23, vol. 2, pp. 533601; repr. in Ravix and Romani 1997, pp. 157226.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1899. The theory of the leisure class. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1904. The theory of business enterprise. New York: Charles Scribener’s Sons.Google Scholar
Verdoorn, P. 1949. ‘Fattori che regolano lo sviluppo della produttività del lavoro’, L’industria 1: 310.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1931. ‘Cost curves and supply curves’, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 3: 2346.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1937. Studies in the theory of international trade. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1991. Essays on the intellectual history of economics. ed. by Irwin, D.A., Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Vromen, J. J. 2007. ‘Neuroeconomics as a natural extension of bioeconomics: the shifting scope of standard economic theory’, Journal of Bioeconomics 9: 145–67.Google Scholar
Wakefield, E. G. 1829. A letter from Sydney, the principal town of Australasia. London: Joseph Cross.Google Scholar
Wakefield, E. G. 1833. England and America. 2 vols., London: R. Bentley.Google Scholar
Wald, A. 1936. ‘Über einige Gleichungssysteme der Mathematischen Ökonomie’, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 7: 637–70. English transl., ‘On some systems of equations of mathematical economics’, Econometrica 19 (1951): 368–403.Google Scholar
Walras, L. 1867. ‘La Bourse et le crédit’, in Paris guide, par les principaux écrivains et artistes de la France, deuxième partie, Paris: Librairie Internationale, pp. 1731–51; repr. in Auguste et Leon Walras, Oeuvres économiques complètes, vol. 7, Mélanges d’économie politique et sociale, Paris: Economica 1987, pp. 180200.Google Scholar
Walras, L. 1874. Eléments d’économie politique pure. Lausanne: Corbaz; second part, 1877; second edn. 1889, third edn. 1896, fourth edn. 1900, ‘definitive’ edn. 1926. English transl. of the 1926 edn., ed. by Jaffé, W., Elements of pure economics, London: Irwin Inc. 1954; repr. London: Allen & Unwin 1965.Google Scholar
Walras, L. 1880. ‘La Bourse, la spéculation et l’agiotage’, Bibliothèque Universelle et Revue Suisse n. 5 (March): 452–76 and n. 6 (April): 66–94.Google Scholar
Walras, L. 1896. Études d’économie sociale. Théorie de la répartition de la richesse sociale. Lausanne: Corbaz; repr. Paris: Economica 1990.Google Scholar
Walras, L. 1898. Études d’économie politique appliquée. Théorie de la production de la richesse sociale. ed. definitive ed. by Leduc, G., Lausanne: P. Rouge and Paris: F. Pichon 1936; repr. Paris: Economica 1992.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1904–5. ‘Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus’, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 20–21; second edn. in Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie, Tübingen: Mohr 1922. English transl., The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism, London: Allen & Unwin 1930.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1922. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. 2 vols., Tübingen: Mohr. English transl., Economy and society, New York: Bedminster Press 1968.Google Scholar
Whately, R. 1831. Introductory lectures on political economy. London: B. Fellowes; second edn. 1832.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1893. Über Wert, Kapital, und Rente. Jena: G. Fischer. English transl., Value, capital and rent, London: Allen & Unwin 1954.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1898. Geldzins und Güterpreise bestimmenden Ursachen. Jena: G. Fischer. English transl., Interest and prices, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1900. ‘Om gränsproduktivitaten såsom grundval för den nationalekonomiska fördelningen’, Ekonomisk Tidskrift 2: 305–37. English transl., ‘Marginal productivity as the basis for distribution in economics’, in Wicksell, K., Selected papers on economic theory, London: Allen & Unwin 1958, pp. 93121.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. 1901–6. Forelasningar i nationalekonomi. 2 vols., Stockholm-Lund: Fritzes-Berlingska. English transl., Lectures on political economy, 2 vols., London: Routledge and Kegan Paul 1934–35.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, P. H. 1894. An essay on the co-ordination of the laws of distribution. London: Macmillan; repr. ed. by Steedman, I., Aldershot: Edward Elgar 1992.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, P. H. 1910. The common sense of political economy. London: Macmillan; repr. ed. by Robbins, L., 2 vols., London: Routledge 1933.Google Scholar
Wilson, T. 1572. A discourse uppon usurye. Londini: Rychardi Tottelli; repr. ed. by Tawney, R. H., London: Bell 1926; repr. London: Frank Cass 1963.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, L. 1921. ‘Logisch-philosophische Abhandlung’, Annalen der Naturphilosophie, 14: 185262. English edn. with revisions and the German text, Tractatus logico-philosophicus. London: Kegan Paul 1922.Google Scholar
Wittgenstein, L. 1953. Philosophische Untersuchungen. (with English transl., Philosophical investigations). ed. by Anscombe, G. E. M. and Rhees, R., Oxford: Blackwell; repr. 1972.Google Scholar
Wood, A. 1975. A theory of profits. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Xenophon, 1923. Memorabilia and Oeconomicus. ed. Capps, E., Page, T.E. and Rouse, W.H.D., Loeb Classic Library, London: Heinemann and New York: Putnam’s Sons.Google Scholar
Young, A. 1928. ‘Increasing returns and economic progress’, Economic Journal 38: 527–42.Google Scholar
Zeuthen, F. 1933. ‘Das Prinzip der Knappheit, technische Kombination und ökonomische Qualität’, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 4: 124.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Alessandro Roncaglia
  • Book: A Brief History of Economic Thought
  • Online publication: 12 September 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316798416.020
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Alessandro Roncaglia
  • Book: A Brief History of Economic Thought
  • Online publication: 12 September 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316798416.020
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Alessandro Roncaglia
  • Book: A Brief History of Economic Thought
  • Online publication: 12 September 2017
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316798416.020
Available formats
×