Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-16T02:50:38.631Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

8 - Wicksell and Douglas on distribution and marginal productivity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Christian Bidard
Affiliation:
University of Paris
Heinz D. Kurz
Affiliation:
Karl-Franzens-Universität Graz, Austria
Get access

Summary

Production function and distribution

The hottest issue between the ‘neo-Ricardian’ and the ‘neoclassical’ schools has been the debate on capital theory, which mainly took place in the 1960s. As told from a neo-Ricardian standpoint, the dominant neoclassical school represents the technical capabilities of an economy by assuming the existence of a functional relationship (the production function F) between the amounts of ‘factors’ (capital K and labour L, land being ignored for the sake of simplicity) and their net product Q, i.e. Q = F(K, L). Function F is assumed to be well behaved (homogeneous and concave). A number of properties are derived from this conception, concerning distribution and its influence on the choice of technique k = K/L, output per worker q = Q/L, etc. However, it can shown analytically that several of these consequences are plainly wrong. To stick to the most famous argument, the neoclassical law of substitution between factors (‘the higher the remuneration of a factor, the lower its use’) is incompatible with the re-switching phenomenon, i.e. the possibility that the same technique is operated at both low and high rates of profit whereas it is dominated by another at an intermediate level: whatever the technique one classifies as more capitalistic, one of the two switchings contradicts the lesson of the law of substitution (see Sraffa, 1960). The reader may refer to Harcourt's classical book (1972) for a record of similar ‘paradoxes’ and the neo-Ricardian criticism of marginalist theory.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×