Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-dfsvx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T15:46:41.963Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Sexism in the Code: A Comparative Study of Income Taxation of Working Wives and Mothers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2010

Bridget J. Crawford
Affiliation:
Pace University School of Law
Anthony C. Infanti
Affiliation:
School of Law, University of Pittsburgh
Get access

Summary

Close scrutiny of the Code reveals a strong pattern of work disincentive for married women and inequitable treatment of the two-earner family. The observation that American working wives are predominantly secondary family earners is not intended to express a social ideal. It merely reflects a contemporary social reality. Women workers generally earn substantially less than their male counterparts. Working wives earn less than their employed husbands. The American wife's working career is likely to be broken by child bearing and -rearing. Unless prompted by economic necessity, her return to work is generally considered discretionary. Even when she is earning a substantial salary, her husband is unlikely to view his employment as discretionary. Thus, the American working wife should properly be understood as a secondary family earner for the purpose of determining the work disincentive effect of various Code provisions.

UNITED STATES TAXATION OF WORKING WIVES AND MOTHERS

Prior to 1948, taxation was individual. Joint returns were authorized but seldom used because the aggregate family income was taxed as though it were the income of a single taxpayer. Since each individual taxpayer was taxed at progressive rates, a tax benefit would result from shifting earned and unearned income among family members. (Earned income is the fruit of personal effort and labor, e.g., salary; unearned income arises from the ownership of property, e.g., rent and dividends.) Thus, a husband with taxable earned income of $8,000 would secure a tax advantage by shifting $4,000 to his wife. Because of the progressive nature of income tax rates, each would pay less than one-half of the tax that the husband would have paid on the entire amount.

Type
Chapter
Information
Critical Tax Theory
An Introduction
, pp. 3 - 10
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×