Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-ttngx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-01T08:13:50.051Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Chapter 1 - The State of Water Resources and the Need for a Comprehensive Perspective

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 April 2021

Ariel Dinar
Affiliation:
University of California, Riverside
Yacov Tsur
Affiliation:
Hebrew University of Jerusalem

Summary

The chapter presents temporal and spatial trends of main water indicators. Attention is given to the interaction between water resources and society over time in various parts of the world, the effects of climate change on the available water supplies, the technological means available to cope with water scarcity and deteriorated quality, the institutional and legal means developed in different countries, and the types of decisions needed to manage water resources. As such, the chapter motivates the book’s structure and contents.

Type
Chapter
Information
The Economics of Water Resources
A Comprehensive Approach
, pp. 8 - 44
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

The Purpose of This Chapter

The role of water across sectors and societies and the evolution of its services over time have been reflected in many aspects of human life. Water, as a resource, has been studied by many disciplines. They all agree that water is unevenly distributed over time and in space, giving rise to large gaps between water needs and water availability in certain times and certain locations and stressing the need for proper demand-and-supply management. It is the reduction of the spatial and temporal gaps between supply and demand that water economics plays a crucial role in. This chapter describes the interaction between water resources and society over time in various parts of the world, the effects of climate change on the available water supplies, the technological means available to cope with water scarcity and deteriorated quality, the institutional and legal means experienced by various countries, and the types of decisions needed to implement and manage such means.

1.1 Background

Water is a natural resource with flow and stock dimensions and with several origins.Footnote 1 Most water is natural, resulting from precipitation (rain and snow) that flows in rivers, and is stored in lakes and groundwater aquifers. Some aquifers are replenishable (from precipitation) and some are fossil, being stored a long time ago (thousands of years) in deep aquifers that are either nonrenewable or very slowly recharged. Some water can be produced by recycling treated wastewater or by desalinating seawater or brackish (saline) sources. More on the various types of water will be discussed in Chapter 2. Hereafter, unless otherwise noted, we will refer to natural water as renewable.

1.2 Spatial and Temporal Water Availability: How Much Water Is There and How Is It Used?

Existing data on renewable natural water availability worldwide have expanded over time with the introduction of satellite technologies and computational power. Several studies present estimates of the global renewable water supplies (Shiklomanov, Reference Shiklomanov and Gleick1993, Reference Shiklomanov1996, Reference Shiklomanov1999, Reference Shiklomanov2000; Clarke and King, Reference Clarke and King2004). These data suggest that annual flow of water available for sustainable extraction (without drawing down stocks or leading to contamination) is more or less constant, as can be seen in Table 1.1, which refers to global and continental available renewable natural water (ARNW) resources.

Table 1.1 Available renewable natural continental and world water resources

ContinentAvailable renewable natural water resources (km3/year)
MeanMin.Max
Europe2,9002,2543,410
North America7,9806,8958,917
Africa4,0503,0735,082
Asia13,51011,80015,008
South America12,03010,32014,350
Australia and Oceania2,4001,8912,880
World42,78039,78044,750

Note: Table elaborated by authors. Min. and Max columns represent possible changes in available renewable natural water resources as a consequence of wet and dry years. One cubic kilometer (km3) is equivalent to 1 billion cubic meters (m3) or 810,714 acre-feet.

Source: Based on data in Shiklomanov, Reference Shiklomanov2000

Against the more or less fixed quantity of ARNW, it is interesting to follow the changes in annual global withdrawals between 1900 and 1995, and forecasts (performed in 2000) for 2000, 2010, and 2025, as can be seen in Figure 1.1.

Figure 1.1 Estimates and forecasts of global water withdrawals between 1900 and 2015 (km3/year).

Source: Adapted from data in Shiklomanov (2000)

The ARNW resources are used by households for drinking, cooking, washing, and outdoor uses; for agricultural production (crop irrigation, livestock and aquaculture); for industrial production; and for environmental purposes. Water is also used in cooling, mining, and navigation, although to a lesser extent. Some uses (household, irrigation, industrial production, mining) are called consumptive because a part of the water consumed is no longer available in the same year for other uses, either because it disappears or moves away from its original consumption location, or because its quality is no longer adequate for use. Other uses are non-consumptive, although they may change the nature and timing of water availability (navigation, cooling, hydropower, and in-stream use for environmental purposes). A bulk estimate (UN-Water, 2015) suggests that 70, 20, and 10% of the available water flow are consumed in irrigation, industrial, and urban uses, respectively. It should be noted that with the introduction of improved wastewater treatment technologies, household and industrial sewage can be treated and be reused for irrigation, cooling, environmental purposes, and, in some cases, household purposes (e.g., in Orange County, California).

1.3 Population Trends and Available Renewable Natural Water Resources

Water is necessary for subsistence (drinking, cooking, hygiene), for agricultural and industrial production, and for environmental purposes.Footnote 2 It is therefore of interest knowing how much water is available in different locations intra- (within a year) and inter-temporal. Even if water is abundant, its quality may restrict its use, e.g., saline water is not suitable for drinking or irrigation of certain crops without proper treatment.

The availability of water for human consumption represents its level of scarcity. There are several measures for water scarcity (Brown and Matlock, Reference Brown and Matlock2011), but we will use one crude measure that addresses only the available quantity. Available water quantity per capita is calculated by dividing the total renewable natural water available in a sustainable fashion (which on average is fixed at the levels indicated in Table 1.1) by the population at a given year in the location of interest (world, continent, country, region, river basin). We calculate the scarcity index for all-natural water sources (rivers, lakes, aquifers) as well as for subsets of the water resources, such as groundwater. Figures 1.2 and 1.3 demonstrate the change in the water availability index during 1945–2015.

Source: World Data FAO AQUASTAT and Population Data from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015)

Figure 1.2 Freshwater resources per capita by continent (1) and by representative water-scarce regions (2) (1950–2015).

Note: Population values beyond 2015 are based on mid-level forecasts; the horizontal red lines in Figures 1.2 and 1.3 represent, from top to bottom, the Falkenmark water availability levels of 1,700, 1,000, and 500 m3/person/year, which, respectively, indicate Stress, Scarcity, and Absolute Scarcity.

Source: World Data FAO AQUASTAT and Population Data from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015)

Figure 1.3 Freshwater resources per capita for a sample of water-scarce (1) and water-abundant (2) countries (1950–2015).

To allow reference to scarcity levels, we use the “scarcity categories” suggested by Falkenmark (1989) and coined as the “Falkenmark indicator,” which is broadly used in the literature. The Falkenmark indicator proposes three levels of available renewable water per capita per year, measured in cubic meter per capita per year and denoted CMpy, as follows: CMpy above 1,700 indicates No Stress, CMpy between 1,000 and 1,700 indicates Stress, CMpy between 500 and 1,000 indicates Scarcity, and CMpy below 500 indicates Absolute Scarcity.

As can be seen from Figures 1.2 and 1.3, water availability per capita at year t, calculated as CMpyt=WPopt, with WW being the average (fixed) available renewable water resources and PoptPopt being the population at year t, takes, for most regions, a declining hyperbolic trend over time. The forecasted population growth trends for 2050 and beyond are negative for some countries. This is reflected in an inclining part of the available renewable water resources per capita per year graph.

In Figures 1.2 and 1.3 we draw the Falkenmark indices of 1,700, 1,000, and 500 m3/person/year. We expect that these lines will be intercepted by the water availability per capita lines earlier in time for countries with higher levels of water scarcity and later in time for more water-abundant countries.

Another way to measure scarcity is by referring to the parameters of the water availability per capita graphs (in Figure 1.3, for example). We can compare the MCpytMCpyt curves to declining linear trend, Y − ϑtYϑt with intercept Y and slope ϑϑ. As can be depicted from the sample graphs, some regions (continents, countries, or even subregions within a country – not presented) can be identified by these two parameters: the intercept and slope of the water availability per capita trend. The intercept represents the fixed water endowments per capita of that region and the slope represents the population growth rate in the region (if we can measure the water quality degradation, this slope can also represent the water scarcity due to deteriorating quality). The lower the intercept the more severe the scarcity, and the higher the slope the faster water becomes scarce in that region.

Another important observation is that while continental water-scarcity trends (Figure 1.2) suggest “No Scarcity” in most continents, and “Stress” toward the year 2050 in most continents, the situation still varies dramatically across countries in these continents (see Figure 1.3 for selected countries with extreme water-scarcity conditions).

So far, we have discussed water-scarcity trends associated with population growth, given that on average the available natural renewable water resources are fixed. Climate change will most likely affect the average supply of natural water unfavorably in many regions, particularly in arid and semiarid regions, thereby exacerbating water scarcity in these regions.

1.3.1 Additional Trends Affecting Water Scarcity

In addition to the population trends described above, there are several additional trends that affect spatial water scarcity. We will discuss here one trend – the increase in urban population – that affects local water scarcity, the economics of investment in water infrastructure, and also the opportunity to create new sources of water (manufactured/produced water).

Urban population growth is affected by many factors, including international migration and rural-to-urban migration, both of which are affected by water scarcity; poor environmental conditions; social unrest (civil wars) at the migration source region; and high natural population growth rates. The urban population in 2014 accounted for nearly 55% of the total global population, up from one-third in 1960. Such increase in urban population added about 2.5 billion people to cities over the past 55 years. This trend is still ongoing: the annual growth rate of urban population is predicted to be 1.84%, 1.63%, and 1.44% during the periods 2015–2020, 2020–2025, and 2025–2030, respectively (UN-DESA-PD, 2015). Figures 1.4 and 1.5 present the situation of urban population in 1975 and 2015.

Figure 1.4 Major world cities with populations exceeding 5 million inhabitants in 1975.

Source: Authors’ elaboration using data from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, 2006

Figure 1.5 Major world cities with populations exceeding 5 million inhabitants in 2015.

Source: Authors’ elaboration, using data from Demographia World Urban Areas, 11th Annual Edition, 2016

The urban expansion between 1975 and 2015 is significant as can be seen from the two previous figures. In 1975, there were 11 urban centers with 10–15 million inhabitants, 1 urban center with 15–19 million inhabitants, and 2 urban centers with 20–24 million inhabitants. In 2015, the corresponding numbers were 23, 5, and 10, with 2 urban centers containing above 30 million inhabitants. The economic implications are enormous. First, such changes mean that the increased urban demand for water needs to be addressed by new reservoirs and conveyance systems, which translates into major long-term investments in infrastructure. Second, as indicated by UN-DESA-PD (2015) and as can be seen in Figures 1.4 and 1.5, most of the urban growth is and will be in developing countries (mainly Asia), suggesting a significant burden on the budgets of these economies for investing in water supply and sanitation infrastructure (support for such investments as well as for prevention of waterborne-disease outbreaks are often sought from the donor community). Third, and on the positive side, this situation, if handled well and supported by appropriate funding institutions and regulations, could create an opportunity for new water sources in the form of treated wastewater that can be recycled and reused in irrigated agriculture, thus releasing freshwater for urban use (Hernandez-Sancho et al., Reference Hernandez-Sancho, Lamizana-Diallo, Mateo-Sagasta and Qadeer2015; Tsur, Reference Tsur2015). We will discuss this opportunity in Section 1.9.

1.4 Climate Change Shock Effects on the Water System

Climate change has been affecting our natural systems and the economy for quite some time. Impact of climate change on the water system will be felt in several ways. First, a change in average precipitation: Some locations face a reduction while others face an increase (Figure 1.8). The second impact has been felt through increase in variability of the precipitation events, ranging from increased number of drought and flood events and increased duration and severity of these events. Another effect climate change has had on the water sector is increased evaporation due to higher temperatures, leading to less effective irrigation in most parts of the world (Figure 1.8). A comprehensive discussion of the information in Figure 1.8 appears below. But before this, we would like to focus on drought and flood event distribution over time.

The Center for Natural Disaster suggests a sharp increase in drought and flooding events around the world in the past 100 years, with increased longevity and severity (Gupta-Sapir et al., Reference Gupta-Sapir, Hargitt and Hoyois2003). Figures 1.6 and 1.7 present a sharp increase in the number of drought and flood events, respectively, since the 1960s.Footnote 3 These extreme events have significant economic impact that, if incorporated into the policy realm of the various drought- and flood-prone countries, would change economic considerations within the water sector.

Figure 1.6 Global drought events between 1900 and 2015.

Source: D. Guha-Sapir, R. Below, Ph. Hoyois – EM-DAT: The CRED/OFDA International Disaster Database – www.emdat.be – Université Catholique de Louvain – Brussels – Belgium. [Permission granted on EM-DAT website]

Figure 1.7 Global flood events between 1900 and 2015.

Source: D. Guha-Sapir, R. Below, Ph. Hoyois – EM-DAT: The CRED/OFDA International Disaster Database – www.emdat.be – Université Catholique de Louvain – Brussels – Belgium. [Permission granted on EM-DAT website]

A comparison of the aggregated number of drought and flood events over the past century (Table 1.2) suggests a remarkable increase in the number of these events over the past 40 years compared to the period during the first eight decades of the twentieth century.

Table 1.2 Number of drought and flood events between 1900 and 2015 divided into three periods

Decadal periodTotal drought eventsTotal flood events
1900–19382030
1939–197690383
1977–20155784,152
Source: Data in Figures 1.6 and 1.7

With such increases in extreme flood and drought events during 1900–2015, what would the future be with climate change’s expected impacts? The Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Stocker et al., 2013) suggests a range of future values of hydrological variables that demonstrates expected effects of climate change on the hydrological cycle. Figure 1.8 presents predicted annual mean values of six hydrological variables during the period 2081–2100, including precipitation, evaporation, relative humidity, evapotranspiration, runoff in rivers, and soil moisture.

Figure 1.8 Future changes in six main hydrological parameters predicted for 2081–2100.

Source: Adapted from the IPCC WGI AR5 (figure TFE.1, fig. 3), Stocker et al., 2013 [Permission obtained]

The six variables listed in Figure 1.8 demonstrate a distributional range of both increase and decrease in precipitation (−0.8 to +0.8) millimeters per day, evaporation (−1 to +0.8) millimeters per day, relative humidity (−9 to +6%), evapotranspiration (−0.8 to +0.8) millimeters per day, runoff (−40 to +40%), and soil moisture (−10 to +10%), suggesting a wide range of variability across different parts of the world.

Watching the changes in precipitation in two of the focus points in our book – California and the Jordan River BasinFootnote 4 (Figures 1.9 and 1.10, respectively) – it is clear that these two semiarid regions face a major decline in precipitation as well as increase in their variability. These trends are consistent across many regions and may differ only in magnitude.

Figure 1.9 Annual precipitation in California, 1983 and 2015.

Source: Modified by authors from data provided by Center for Hydrometeorology and Remote Sensing at the University of California, Irvine, http://chrs.web.uci.edu/

Figure 1.10 Annual precipitation in the Jordan Basin States, 1983 and 2015.

Source: Modified by authors from data provided by Center for Hydrometeorology and Remote Sensing at the University of California, Irvine, http://chrs.web.uci.edu/

What do we learn so far from the past trends of hydrological parameters and predicted future changes? The data available so far suggest that water becomes scarcer (both in terms of quantity, quality, and variability) and that the level of scarcity varies by region. Why is that important for the analysis in our book? Because this means that economic and policy decisions are required in order to deal with scarcity. It also means that economic policies vary among locations, based on severity of scarcity.

1.5 Other Human-Made Shocks to the Water System

While climate change effects on the water cycle are also the results of human-attributed impacts that increase global greenhouse gas (GHG) emission, this is not the only shock caused to the water system by anthropogenic activities. Climate change–induced impacts are global in nature, meaning that GHG emission in any location contributes to GHG concentration in the atmosphere, which then affects different regions with different extents.

Other human-made shocks are more local in nature. We will refer only to a couple of impacts, translating into lower groundwater (GW) level in aquifers that makes water pumping more expensive, and to deteriorated water quality that makes the water unsuitable for consumption for various purposes. Over-pumping of groundwater leads also to land subsidence, which, depending on the geology/morphology of the aquifer, can be associated with significant economic damage. We do not address the economics of land subsidence in this book.

Renewable groundwater resources comprise nearly 31% of the renewable freshwater resources on earth (Shiklomanov, Reference Shiklomanov2000). As such, the sustainable yield of groundwater (that does not draw stocks below certain thresholds) is an important and valuable resource that in some semiarid regions, e.g., the Middle East and western United States, is the major source of water for irrigation and urban use.

Moreover, groundwater stocks serve as a buffer to smooth water supply during dry years, when surface water becomes less available. In addition, due to poor regulation and malfunctioning institutions for groundwater pumping in many countries, this resource has always been used beyond its safe recharge, mainly due to expansion of irrigation areas. This trend has resulted in lowering of the water table level, land subsidence, and deterioration of water quality due to intrusion of saltwater and deep percolation of pollutants from irrigated fields. For example, according to Shah (Reference Shah2009: figure 2.1), between the years 1940 and 2009, India, China, and Mexico increased groundwater extraction from 10 to 260, from 10 to 90, and from 20 to 60 km3/year, respectively. These countries, and many others, face both depleted and contaminated aquifers and the meager consequences to the people that rely on this resource in the form of congestion cost, saline water intrusion from adjacent aquifers, and seawater intrusion (Shah, Reference Shah2009; CONAGWA, 2010; Shen, Reference Shen2015). Figure 1.11 presents recent results from a study that documented trends in the depletion over time of several major aquifers around the world and its extent.

Figure 1.11 Trends in groundwater levels in major aquifers.

Source: Richey et al. (Reference Richey, Thomas, Lo, Reager, Famiglietti, Voss, Swenson and Rodell2015), Quantifying Renewable Groundwater Stress with GRACE, Water Resources Research, doi: 10.1002/2015WR017349 [Permission obtained]

Data in Figure 1.11 suggest that of the 37 major aquifers studied, 23 face 10–20% depletion. While not all world aquifers were included in the study, the results are the mirror image of the situation in most of the groundwater aquifers around the world. Such depletion has remarkable impacts on the ability of GW stocks to play their role as buffers in periods of severe scarcity. Another aspect of such depletion is the effect of water-level drawback on the water quality in the aquifers due to the intrusion of seawater, where applicable. And finally, depletion of water level in aquifers leads to an increase in the pumping cost, which makes irrigated agriculture to be less profitable.

Richey et al. (Reference Richey, Thomas, Lo, Reager, Famiglietti, Voss, Swenson and Rodell2015) developed a groundwater depletion index, called RGS (Renewable Groundwater Stress), based on water withdrawal above natural recharge. Using GRACE observations for the period 2003–2013, the authors calculated RGS values for the world’s 37 largest aquifers and classified the groundwater stress conditions of each aquifer as low, moderate, high, or extreme. Aquifers with high or extreme stress conditions undergo depletion at alarming rates, which means that their exploitation has been, or soon will be, limited due to vanishing water stocks or quality deterioration triggered by the declining water head. Of the 37 major aquifers, Richey et al. (Reference Richey, Thomas, Lo, Reager, Famiglietti, Voss, Swenson and Rodell2015: table 3) identified 12 to be under high or extreme stress, including the Great Plains and Ogallala aquifers in North America, the Indus Basin and Tarim Basin aquifers in India and China, 6 aquifers in Africa, and the Great Artesian Basin aquifer in Australia. Konikow (Reference Konikow2013) uses data on groundwater withdrawal and natural recharge during the period 1900–2008 to estimate groundwater depletion for all major US aquifers. Aggregate groundwater depletion (extraction above recharge) in 2008 was 25 Km3Km3, which amounts to 70% of total US domestic water consumption during that year.

Water quality deterioration around the world is another major constraint on use of water and is directly and indirectly associated with the high economic cost of waterborne diseases and their prevention. Water pollution, resulting from economic activities, indicates a failure of institutions and regulatory interventions to curb such pollution. The major water pollution sources are human activities: residential, industrial, and agricultural. The data are staggering (UN-Water, 2013): about 80% of the residential sewage in developing countries is discharged untreated to natural water bodies, and the industrial sector globally release between 300–400 million tons of raw sewage to water bodies. Agriculture pollutes groundwater and soil with nitrates (from fertilizers) and minerals (salinity). Such pollution reduces the suitability, hence availability, of groundwater for irrigation and drinking purposes. In addition, salinization of soils reduces the productivity of agricultural land and, in addition, increases the volume of water needed to flash the pollutants from the soil profile (Assoulin et al., Reference Assouline, Russo, Silver and Or2015).

1.6 The Gap between the Supply and Demand

With increased population-driven demand for water, on the one hand, and the climate change–driven shocks to the water system, on the other hand, the gap between water needs and natural water supply has been widening over time. A recent study (The 2030 Water Resource Group, 2009) estimates that conventional approaches will not be sufficient to close this gap in the near future. Indeed, the cited study considers mainly structural approaches, namely, infrastructure and special linking of water sources (including intra- and inter-basin water transfers), which are extremely costly. Based on the analysis in The 2030 Water Resources Group (2009: 45–48), under a number of simplifying assumptions, the global water consumption (for all purposes) is currently 7,000 Km3. About 20% of this quantity could be provided by increase in quantity supplied under business-as-usual investments and improvements. An additional 20% of this quantity will be provided by improvements in water productivity in agriculture and industrial production. The remaining 60% is a gap that will need to be addressed by means beyond those considered under business-as-usual (or conventional) approaches. In Section 1.7, we discuss the various measures, both structural and non-structural that could be considered to close the gap between water needs and available water supply.

1.7 Technological Means to Close the Gap (Supply Management)

The gap between demand and supply, as defined earlier, can be reduced by increasing the supply of water. Supply of water can be increased by regulating floods, snowmelt, and river flow; by recycling water; and by producing new water via desalination. Each of these ways to close the gap between supply and demand has an opportunity cost associated with the benefits of increased supply.

1.7.1 Reservoirs

Building new reservoirs increases the storage capacity for water as can be seen in Figure 1.12. It is striking that most of the reservoirs around the world are located where water is abundant (such as South America and Southeast Asia) or in countries with financial means (such as the United States and Western Europe) suggesting that such an approach to closing the gap is not effective in semiarid and arid regions where the gap is significant.

Figure 1.12 Water reservoirs around the world (2011).

1.7.2 Wastewater Treatment and Reuse

Treating and reusing municipal wastewater is an untapped source of water that has a tremendous potential, especially with the major increase in urban population (Hernandez-Sancho et al., Reference Hernandez-Sancho, Lamizana-Diallo, Mateo-Sagasta and Qadeer2015; Tsur, Reference Tsur2015). Reuse of residential wastewater for irrigation purposes, if done properly, achieves two objectives. First, it releases freshwater that can be used for residential consumption, and second, it prevents the pollution of the environment. Figure 1.13 presents the ratio of treated wastewater to produced sewage in counties around the world. As can be seen, most countries in 2012 and especially the developing countries have ratios in the range of 0–40%.

Figure 1.13 Ratio of treated wastewater to produced sewage in selected countries (in 2012).

Source: Sato et al. (2013) [Permission obtained]

In addition to Figure 1.13, which shows relative values of treatment to production of wastewater, Table 1.3 provides the number of wastewater facilities and the global total wastewater treatment capacity during the periods 1990–1997 and 1998–2013. Values in Table 1.3 suggest that the rise is significant: a 398% increase in the number of wastewater treatment facilities worldwide and a 20% increase in the global capacity. Both indicators are impressive. They mean also that during the period 1999–2013, the additional treatment facilities added to the stock were mainly local and small.

Table 1.3 Global number of wastewater facilities and capacity (billion cubic meters per year)

PeriodGlobal number of facilitiesGlobal capacity (109 m3/year)
1990–199818,062255,524.1
1999–201372,007306,873.4
Source: FAO AQUASTAT

Awareness of the need to treat residential sewage doesn’t mean that treated wastewater will be applied only for irrigation. So far, treated wastewater is used for various purposes, including irrigation of agricultural crops, but also irrigation of golf courses, irrigation of public areas in urban centers, support for ecosystem services (e.g., Albufera wetland in southeastern Spain – see Andreu et al., Reference Andreu, Ferrer-Polo, Angel Perez, Solera, Paredes-Arquiola, Schwabe, Albiac-Murillo, Connor, Hassan and Meza González2013), and for recharge of groundwater aquifers, which can contribute to irrigation and residential water supply following additional treatment (4 Southern California, 2016; Orange County Sanitation District, 2016). Table 1.4 presents trends of treated wastewater reuse in California between 2001 and 2015. The use of recycled water for irrigation in Israel has more than doubled during the past 20 years and Israeli irrigators now use more recycled water than fresh (natural) water (see discussion in Chapter 2).

Table 1.4 Treated wastewater reuse for various purposes in California, 2001, 2009, 2015

Year200120092015
Beneficial reuseAcre-feet/year (rounded values)Percent totalAcre-feet/year (rounded values)Percent totalAcre-feet/year (rounded values)Percent total
Golf course irrigation115,0002244,000756,0008
Landscape irrigation112,00017126,00018
Agriculture irrigation239,00045245,00037219,00031
Commercial22,00046,00015,0001
Industrial50,000767,0009
Geothermal energy production1,000≪115,000218,0003
Seawater intrusion barrier22,000449,000754,0008
Groundwater recharge49,000980,00012115,00016
Recreational impoundment35,000726,000428,0004
Natural systems: restoration, wetlands, wildlife habitat22,000430,000424,0003
Other (sewer flushing, misc. wash-down etc.)20,000412,00022,000≪1
Grand total525,000669,000714,000
Source: Dinar et al., 2018 (Adapted from California State Water Resources Control Board [n.d.])

1.7.3 Irrigation Expansion and Improvements

The increased demand for food due to higher world population levels and changes to their diet and income means that more water will be needed for food production in many parts of the world. A look at historical data on area equipped for irrigation can provide some insights (FAO, 2016). Globally, the area equipped for irrigation increased from 164 to 324 million hectares (ha) over the past 50 years. Some countries facing severe water scarcity led such increases. For example, significant percentage increases occurred in Saudi Arabia (from 0.3 to 1.6 million ha), Libya (from 0.1 to 0.5 million ha), Yemen (from 0.2 to 0.7 million ha), China (from 45 to 68 million ha), and India (from 26 to 67 million ha).

1.7.4 Desalination

The last resort is the investment in desalination. While expensive, desalination guarantees a stable supply of water, mainly for urban and industrial uses, but in some countries (mostly in the Middle East) also for irrigation. Figures 1.14 and 1.15 provide information on the expansion of the number of medium- and large-scale desalination plants and their capacity by country between 1990 and 2014.

Source: Authors’ elaboration, based on data from Hansaki et al. (2016)

Figure 1.14 Number and location of desalination plants in 1990 (top) and 2014 (bottom).

Source: Authors’ elaboration, based on data from Hansaki et al. (2016)

Figure 1.15 Global capacity of desalination plants in 1990 (top) and 2014 (bottom).

1.8 Demand Management

In Section 1.7, we reviewed several technological means to close the gap between supply and demand. They include storing water during wet years to be used during dry years, treating residential sewage and reusing it in irrigation and for environmental purposes (e.g., river and estuary restoration), and producing drinkable water via desalination of seawater. These measures are often expensive. Demand management means achieving more with a given quantity of water. Examples include providing the incentives to use water saving irrigation technologies, reducing leakage and water loss from conveyance and distribution facilities, more socially desirable allocation of water, and encouraging water conservation. Chapters 3, 4, 5, and 7 focus on aspects of demand management. Here we review the global trends in several of the components of demand management over time.

In the following, we review the time trends in institutions (e.g., water markets), incentives (e.g., water pricing), and regulations (e.g., domestic water laws, standards, restrictions/quotas, and international treaties on shared rivers and aquifers).

1.8.1 Domestic Water Laws

We start with domestic water laws that have been enacted globally (Figure 1.16). Water laws introduce certain regulations in the water sector, which are likely to lead to better management of the resource. We expect that states will turn to legal and institutional reforms when they face a high level of water scarcity and deteriorated quality. Scrutiny of Figure 1.16 suggests that there has been a spike in the number of domestic laws enacted since 1990. This could be the result of either the realization of the scarcity level globally or the increased awareness following the 1992 Rio Declaration.Footnote 5 What we do not know is that different types of water laws affect the capacity to deal with water scarcity. This question is an important topic for future research.

Figure 1.16 Global number of domestic water laws enacted by year, 1815–2015.

Note: The decline in 2015 reflects truncation in documented data that will be filled in future years.

Source: FAOLEX (n.d.)

1.8.2 International Water Treaties

Many of the river basins are international in nature. There are nearly 260 basins that are shared by 2 or more countries. Such basins often involve conflicts over water ownership and management. Treaties over international water have been signed between riparian states since the mid-1880s (Figure 1.17) in an attempt to address the conflicts over water and the future likelihood that such conflicts would worsen as a result of climate change (Dinar and Dinar, Reference Dinar and Dinar2016). The literature analyzing the performance of international treaties has been expanded over the past two decades, recognizing the importance of these institutions. We dedicate Chapter 9 to addressing the economics of international water. Following a similar motivation, treaties to settle claims over groundwater that are shared by two or more countries have also been attempted, although with less success due to the more complicated nature of groundwater hydrology. Figure 1.18 presents the cumulative number of groundwater treaties signed over the period between 1915 and 2015.

Figure 1.17 Total cumulative number of transboundary river basin water laws and agreements, 1855–2015.

Note: The decline in 2015 reflects truncation in documented data that will be filled in future years.

Source: International Water Law Project (n.d.)

Figure 1.18 Total cumulative number of transboundary groundwater laws and agreements, 1915–2015.

Source: International Water Law Project (n.d.)

1.8.3 Water Markets

Several additional nonstructural measures that have been implemented globally include water trade and water pricing. Water markets can ease the relative scarcity in a specific region by moving water from a relatively water-abundant region to the water-scarce region or from a relatively low-value use to a relatively high-value use. In order for water markets to perform, property rights for water must be well defined so that individuals know how much water they “own” and can sell in the market.Footnote 6

We start with a recently published dataset on status of water rights allocation in various countries (The Nature Conservancy, 2016). Water rights allocation is a necessary condition for the efficient operation of a water market. As can be seen from Table 1.5, of the nearly 20% of the countries facing water scarcity, there are water rights allocations in only 22 (11%), but evidence of trading exists in only 11 (5.5%).

Table 1.5 Status of water rights, allocation and trade in water-scarce countries

Countries with water scarcityNo significant water scarcity
Status of water rights, allocation and tradeNo water rightsNo water rights, water allocation is allowedWater rights, no evidence of tradingWater rights, reallocation is allowed, no evidence of tradingWater rights, reallocation is allowed, evidence of tradingWater rights, evidence of trading
Italy, Greece, Mauritania, Niger, Libya, Chad, Eritrea, Iraq, Syria, Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan, Tajikistan, Pakistan, Myanmar, ThailandEast Timor, Malaysia, Indonesia, Kirgizstan, Saudi Arabia, MaliTurkey, Bulgaria, Egypt, Sudan, Ethiopia, Botswana, Argentina,Algeria, Iran, Afghanistan, ZimbabweWestern US states, Mexico, Brazil, Peru, Chile, Morocco, Portugal, Yemen, South Africa, AustraliaChinaRest of the world
No. of countries (% of total)15 (7.5%)6 (3%)7 (3.5%)4 (2%)10 (5%)1 (0.5%)157 (78.5%)
Source: Adapted from The Nature Conservancy, 2016 (fig. 15)

We selected three countries, Australia, the United States (California), and Chile (Figures 1.19, 1.20, and 1.21), where a water-rights system is in place and there is evidence of water trading over time. Figures 1.191.21 demonstrate the extent of water trading in each country/state, subject to the institutional and legal system in place in each, as well as the infrastructure to allow water trade. We do not analyze the differences in performance but rather provide the data. Explaining the differences in market performance is certainly a subject for additional research.

Figure 1.19 Water transfers between water districts in California, 1982–2014.

Note: Volumes include short-term contracts, long-term contracts, permanent transfers, and water committed but not transferred.

1 Acre-foot = 1,235 cubic meters.

Source: Adapted by authors from Public Policy Institute of California, www.ppic.org/main/publication_show.asp?i=1177

Figure 1.20 Volume of water allocation and entitlement trade in the South Murray–Darling Basin, 1983–2013.

Note: ML=Mega Liter. 1 Mega liter = 1,000 cubic meters. Data for 2012 was not available in the sources used. Water year in Australia starts in July. Therefore, the year marks on the horizontal axis should be read: 1983–1984 for 1983, etc.

South Murray–Darling Basin (SMDB) is presented because the lion share of the transactions in Australia take place in the SMDB. For example, in 2011–2012, 74% of water entitlement trade and 94% of water allocation trade in the Australian water market (1,437,000,000 cubic meters and 429,700,000 cubic meters, respectively) took place in Murray–Darling Basin.

Source: Authors’ elaboration based on data in Wheeler et al., Reference Wheeler, Loch, Zuo and Bjornlund2014 (for 1983–2011) and in Wheeler (2016, personal communication)

Figure 1.21 Number of registered transactions in water rights in Chile between 1999 and 2012.

Note: Data on non-consumptive trade exists only for 2005–2012.

Source: Elaborated by authors based on data in Consultorias LIDD (2013)

Water rights in Chile are defined in terms of flow (liters per second) in specific stretches of rivers. For example, in 1999/2000 the total value of flow in registered transactions was 160,836.30 liters per second (5,075,495,000 m3) (Consultorias LIDD, 2013).

Some similarities can be observed across all three markets. First, it is obvious that the period after 2000 is characterized by an increase in the volume traded as well as the number of transactions (in Chile). Second, short-term leases (California) and allocation trade (Australia) are more prevalent than long-term/permanent/entitlement trades. And finally, it is also clear that the market has started to accommodate environment demands only in recent years.

It is difficult to compare the performance of the water markets in Australia, California, and Chile because each country/state has its water-market operation based on different institutional frameworks, water conveyance systems, and rules on how transactions are to be developed and performed. For example, Regnacq et al. (2016) report that trading volumes by the late 2000s were only roughly 3 to 5% of total water use in the urban and agricultural sector in California (Hanak, 2015). And water trading in Australia’s Murray–Darling Basin has accounted for one-third or more of total water availability in that basin (AITHER, 2014, 2015; Howitt, Reference Howitt, Easter and Huang2014). In the case of Chile, in 1999/2000, registered transactions (Figure 1.21) accounted for 14.3% of total available water (nearly 35.43 km3).

1.8.4 Water PricingFootnote 7

Water pricing is considered among the most popular and, at the same time, the most controversial policy intervention used to address water scarcity via demand management. Pricing of water has two key roles, (1) a financial role as a mechanism for recovering the investment and operation and maintenance (O&M) cost of the water system and (2) an economic role, signaling the scarcity value and opportunity cost of water, in order to guide allocation decisions both within and across water sub-sectors. Under certain conditions, pricing of water could also promote equity objectives. There are big differences among sectors such as irrigation, urban, hydropower, and environment. These differences arise from three causes: (1) The nature of the use of water by the sector; for example, irrigation and urban use are consumptive, i.e., they remove the water from the system (rivers, lakes, or aquifers) and often deteriorate its quality by adding pollutants. Water used for hydropower generation is non-consumptive, though it affects water flows and quality. Environmental water use is partly non-consumptive and, in many cases, improves water quality. (2) Ability to identify individual users; for example, while the use by hydropower is transparent, it is hard to identify individual users and monitor their water intake when appropriate infrastructure (e.g., water meters) doesn’t exist in irrigation or urban uses. For example, if farmers pump from a shared reservoir, or when households use a central water outlet serving an apartment building, there is no way to assign water use without measuring devices. (3) The unit value of water may differ a lot across sectors, e.g., between urban and irrigation, with urban typically higher than irrigation. Environment and hydropower are typically within this range (Young and Loomis, Reference Young and Loomis2014). In addition to sectoral differences, we must also recognize, especially in the irrigation sector, the impacts that physical locations (e.g., drainage and quality externalities between upstream and downstream users) have on these three aspects.

More in-depth discussion and analysis on water pricing methods can be found in Tsur and Dinar (Reference Tsur and Dinar1997), Dinar and Saleth (Reference Dinar, Maria Saleth, Folmer and Tietenberg2005), and the literature they cite. We will provide in Tables 1.6 and Table 1.7 explanations of water-pricing methods used in the irrigation and residential sectors. More analytical aspects can be found in Chapter 5.

Table 1.6 Main methods for pricing irrigation water consumption

MethodApplication principles
Volumetric (single rate)Irrigators pay per volume of water they consume. This method necessitates a water-measuring device. Variation of the volumetric approach include (1) indirect calculation based on measurement of flow time (as from a reservoir) or time of uncertain flow (proportions of a flow of a river) and (2) a charge for a given minimal volume to be paid for even if not consumed.
Volumetric (tiered)Irrigators pay per volume based on the volume consumed. This method necessitates a water-measuring devise. This is a multi-rate volumetric method, in which water rates vary as the amount of water consumed exceeds certain threshold values. Usually rates are higher for larger volumes. Number of tiers could be greater than two.
OutputIrrigators pay a water fee per each unit of the output they produce. No water-measuring device is needed.
InputIrrigators pay a water fee per each unit of a certain input used, usually associated with regulation of pollution from use of chemicals. No water-measuring device is needed.
Per unit areaIrrigators are charged per unit of irrigated area, depending on the kind and extent of the crop irrigated, irrigation method, the season of the year, etc. Pumped water is usually charged at a higher rate than gravity water. Farmers are required to pay, in some cases, the per area charges that are also in effect for non-irrigated land.
Two-part tariffThis method involves charging irrigators a constant marginal price per unit of water purchased (volumetric marginal cost pricing) and a fixed annual (or admission) charge for the right to purchase the water. A water-measuring device is needed. The admission charge is the same for all farmers. This pricing method has been advocated, and practiced, where a public utility produces with marginal cost below average cost and must cover total costs (variable and fixed).
Betterment levyWater fees are charged per unit area, based on the increase in land value accruing from the provision of irrigation water.
Source: Based on Tsur and Dinar (Reference Tsur and Dinar1997) and Dinar and Saleth (Reference Dinar, Maria Saleth, Folmer and Tietenberg2005)

Table 1.7 Main methods for pricing residential water consumption

MethodApplication principles
Household fixed FeeA fixed sum is charged to the household periodically (monthly or bi-monthly) no matter how much water the household consumed.
Flat fee (volumetric)The household is charged a fixed fee per unit of water consumed no matter how much water was consumed.
Inclining block rate (volumetric)The household is charged, usually, the marginal cost, in blocks, reflecting segments of consumption, with higher ranges of consumption facing higher rates per unit of water consumed. Number of blocks can reach five.
Declining block rate (volumetric)The household is charged in blocks, reflecting segments of consumption, with higher ranges of consumption facing lower rates per unit of water consumed. The idea behind declining block rate structure is that the utility provides incentives to consumers to consume more water and so to cover better fixed costs.
Water budget rate structure (volumetric)Similar to Inclining Block Rate except that the first block is flexible and subject to adjustment (volume), based on special circumstances such as family size, livestock on premise, etc. The first block is usually relatively very low in rate per unit of water. Remaining blocks are very high (Dinar and Ash 2015).

Note: In most methods, there are also additional fixed costs such as “connection fees” paid by the household upon establishing the contract with the utility.

Source: Expanded from Dinar and Saleth (Reference Dinar, Maria Saleth, Folmer and Tietenberg2005)

There is scant empirical evidence on the effectiveness of water pricing. In other words, there are very few if any empirical works that compare the impact of the introduction of water pricing or a change in the water pricing method. One such study (Baerenklau et al., Reference Baerenklau, Schwabe and Dinar2014) compared the observed reduction in quantities consumed in an urban water district in southern California after a Water Budget Rate Structure replaced a Flat Rate pricing system. They observed a decrease in the total households’ water consumption that progressed from 0% in the first year following the reform up to 17% in the third year following the reform. The trend in reduction was linear. In other studies, Tsur (Reference Tsur2015, Reference Tsur2020) uses national-level data from Israel, suggesting that total residential water consumption has decreased by 14% between 2007 and 2011 (from 767.3 to 664.8 million m3 per year). This decrease is explained by several factors, including a sharp increase in domestic water prices in 2007 to reflect the full cost of water supply (including scarcity cost).

1.9 Role for Economics in Managing Water Resources under Scarcity

This chapter reviewed the interactions between different aspects of social, physical, institutional, technological, and regulatory impacts on water resources use by different sectors globally and in different countries and continents.

Under scarcity of water and other related resources, decisions regarding investments, allocation, use, and sharing the costs and the benefits from investment in water resources and their use become the center of an intersectoral discourse. Economic considerations are relevant for assisting in such decisions.

Economic considerations will be further investigated both theoretically and empirically in the remaining chapters of the book. The various chapters of the book provide the basis for our belief that managing water resources requires a comprehensive approach that, although predominantly economic, relies also on ethical, technical, ecological, sociological, and political considerations.

The various economic tools that we reviewed in this chapter and that will be further developed in the remaining chapters of the book, include pricing of water resources, investment in water infrastructure, regulations of water resources, and the various institutions and management practices that are appropriate to deal with various external shocks, such as climate change, which affect the availability and distribution of water resources.

As such, the remaining chapters address economic principles and methods with a focus on theoretical, empirical, and policy aspects in their application to water management. Therefore, they should be of interest to a wide range of academic readers and, in addition, to water managers and policymakers.

Concepts for Review

  • Falkenmark Scarcity Index

  • Water stress

  • Water scarcity

  • Absolute scarcity

  • Non-consumptive water use

  • Consumptive water use

  • Non-structural policy measures

  • Structural policy measures

  • Domestic water law

  • International water treaties

  • Water markets

  • Water leases

  • Water entitlements

  • Water pricing (volumetric [single rate], volumetric [tiered], output, input, per unit area, two-part tariff, betterment levy, household fixed fee, flat fee, inclining block rate, declining block rate, water budget rate structure)

Practice Questions

  1. 1. Based on the reading in this chapter, suggest and demonstrate three measures of water scarcity. Use the country-level data in the book datasets provided for this chapter to calculate the scarcity indices you suggest for three countries considered to face a priori different levels of scarcity. Do the various indices provide similar ranks of scarcity among the three countries? Why?

  2. 2. Economists have suggested water markets as one efficient way to address water scarcity. As we realize from Table 1.5, water markets have not been practiced widely around the world. Using the information provided for Australia, California, and Chile, and exploring more information in the literature cited in this chapter and elsewhere, compare the institutional, physical, and economic conditions in each of these states to discuss performance of the water markets across these three states.

  3. 3. One of the pricing methods used in irrigated agriculture is per area (per hectare) charges. Based on the literature cited in this chapter, introduce at least two variations of this pricing method. After explaining the principles for their operations, describe whether or not and to what extent they are able to affect the behavior of irrigators when water scarcity calls for conservation.

Footnotes

1 We would like to acknowledge the research assistance of Vincent Ta, allowing us to present the various trends, both inter-temporal and cross-sectional, of the various variables presented in this chapter. We benefited from access to data and maps that were produced upon our request by Dr. Amir AghaKouchak and Dr. Phu Dinh Nguyen, Center for Hydrometeorology & Remote Sensing, University of California, Irvine; Dr. Manzoor Qadir, Institute for Water, Environment and Health, United Nations University, Ontario, Canada; Dr. Naota Hanasaki, National Institute for Environmental Studies, Japan; and Dr. Sarah Wheeler, University of South Wales, Adelaide, Australia.

2 From hereafter we will use the term “water” instead of “water resources.”

3 It is also possible that the upward trend reflects increase in reporting and recording capacity over time.

4 Including Jordan, Israel, the Palestinian Authority, and parts of southern Lebanon and southwest Syria.

5 Rio Declaration on Environment and Development, The United Nations Conference on Environment and Development, Rio de Janeiro, June 1992.

6 This holds in any market transaction, as stressed by the “Coase Theorem,” suggesting a simple way to achieve social efficiency (under “certain conditions”) in the case of a common pool resource with externality (such as water) that otherwise is hard to regulate. The Theorem states that once property rights to holders of the resource are identified, quantified, and allocated via any mechanism, and once incentives are provided to allow exchange for payments of units of the resource, social efficiency can be achieved via the market mechanism. The conditions are: (1) it is feasible to assign the property rights (they are identifiable); (2) there are positive net benefits from the reallocation; (3) the transaction cost of coordinating the transfers is low (enforcement and monitoring); (4) no free-rider problem (no one can benefit without paying); and (5) allocation agreements are respected (no cheating).

7 See also Chapters 5 and 8.

References

AITHER. 2014. The AITHER Water Markets Report 2013–14 Review and 2014–15 Outlook. Melbourne, Australia. Available at www.aither.com.au/ wp-content/uploads/2014/11/Aither-WaterMarketsReport-Oct2014.pdf.Google Scholar
AITHER. 2015. The AITHER Water Markets Report 2014–15 Review and 2015–16 Outlook. Melbourne, Australia. Available at www.aither.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2015/08/Aither_WaterMarketsReport2015-FINAL-07Aug.pdf.Google Scholar
AITHER. 2016. The AITHER Water Markets Report 2015–16 review and 2016–17 outlook. Melbourne, Australia. Available at www.aither.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2016/08/Aither_WaterMarketsReport2015-FINAL 25Aug2016.pdf.Google Scholar
Andreu, J., Ferrer-Polo, J., Angel Perez, M., Solera, A., and Paredes-Arquiola, J.. 2013. Drought Planning and Management in the Jucar Basin, Spain. In: Schwabe, K. J., Albiac-Murillo, J. D., Connor, R., Hassan, R., and Meza González, L. (eds.), Drought in Arid and Semi-Arid Regions: A Multi-disciplinary and Cross-Country Perspective. Berlin: Springer, pp. 237249.Google Scholar
Assouline, S., Russo, D., Silver, A., and Or, D.. 2015. Balancing Water Scarcity and Quality for Sustainable Irrigated Agriculture. Water Resources Research, 51:34193436. DOI:10.1002/2015WR017071.Google Scholar
Baerenklau, K., Schwabe, K., and Dinar, A.. 2014. The Residential Water Demand Effect of Increasing Block Rate Water Budgets. Land Economics, 90(4):683699.Google Scholar
Brown, A., Matlock, M. D.. 2011. A Review of Water Scarcity Indices and Methodologies. University of Arkansas, The Sustainability Consortium, White Paper 106, April.Google Scholar
Clarke, R., and King, J.. 2004. The Atlas of Water. London: Earthscan.Google Scholar
CONAGUA. 2010. Estadísticas del agua 2010. Comisión Nacional del Agua. Mexico.Google Scholar
Consultorias LIDD. 2013. Analysis Estimacion del Precio Privado de Los Derechos de Aprochamiento de Aguas. Informe Final submitted to Comicion Nacional de Riego, Santiagi, April.Google Scholar
Demographia World Urban Areas 12th Annual Edition. 2016. Available at www.demographia.com/db-worldua.pdf. Accessed August 1, 2016.Google Scholar
Dinar, A., and Maria Saleth, R.. 2005. Issues in Water Pricing Reforms: From Getting Correct Prices to Setting Appropriate Institutions. In: Folmer, Henk and Tietenberg, Tom (eds.), The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2005/2006. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 151.Google Scholar
Dinar, A., and Ash, T.. 2015. Water Budget Rate Structure: Experiences from Several Urban Utilities in Southern California. In: Lago, M., Mysiak, J., Mario Gómez, C., Delacámara, G., and Maziotis, A (eds.), Use of Economic Instruments in Water Policy: Insights from International Experience. Berlin: Springer, pp. 147170.Google Scholar
Dinar, S., and Dinar, A.. 2016. International Water Scarcity and Variability: Managing Resource Use across Political Boundaries. San Francisco: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Dinar, A., Parker, D., Huynh, H., and Tieu, A.. 2018. The Evolving Nature of California’s Water Economy. In: Martin, P. L., Goodhue, R. E., and Wright, B. D. (eds.), California Agriculture: Dimensions and Issues. Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics. Available at https://giannini.ucop.edu/publications/cal-ag-book/.Google Scholar
FAO. 2016. FAOStat. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). Available at http://faostat3.fao.org/home/E. Accessed May 28, 2016.Google Scholar
4 Southern California. 2016. Orange County’s Wastewater Purification System, World’s Largest, Expands. Available at www.nbclosangeles.com/news/local/Orange-Countys-Wastewater-Purification-System-Worlds-Largest-Expands-211900901.html. Accessed June 11, 2016.Google Scholar
Gupta-Sapir, D., Hargitt, D., and Hoyois, P.. 2003. Thirty Years of Natural Disasters 1974–2003: The Numbers. Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium: UCL Presses Universitaires De Louvain.Google Scholar
Gupta-Sapir, D., Below, R., and Hoyois, P.. 2015. EM-DAT: The CRED/OFDA International Disaster Database – Université Catholique de Louvain – Brussels – Belgium. Available at www.emdat.be. Accessed April 12, 2016.Google Scholar
Hanasaki, N., Yoshikawa, S., Kakinuma, K., and Kanae, S.. 2016. A Seawater Desalination Scheme for Global Hydrological Models. Hydrology and Earth Systems Science Discussions. DOI:10.5194/hess-2016-119.Google Scholar
Hernandez-Sancho, F., Lamizana-Diallo, B., Mateo-Sagasta, J., and Qadeer, M.. 2015. Economic Valuation of Wastewater – The Cost of Action and the Cost of No Action. Nairobi: United Nations Environment Programme.Google Scholar
Howitt, R. E. 2014. Are Lease Water Markets Still Emerging in California? In: Easter, K. W. and Huang, Q. (eds.), Water Markets for the 21st Century: What Have We Learned? Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 83102.Google Scholar
International Water Law Project. (n.d.). Available at www.internationalwaterlaw.org/. Accessed June 6, 2020.Google Scholar
Konikow, L. F. 2013. Groundwater Depletion in the United States (1900−2008): U.S. Geological Survey Scientific Investigations Report 2013−5079. Available at http://pubs.usgs.gov/sir/2013/5079.Google Scholar
Lago, M., Mysiak, J., Mario Gómez, C., Delacámara, G., and Maziotis, A. (eds.). 2014. Use of Economic Instruments in Water Policy: Insights from International Experience. Heidelberg: Springer.Google Scholar
Orange County Sanitation District. 2016. Resource Recovery: More Than a Sewage Treatment Plant. Available at www.ocsd.com/. Accessed June 11, 2016.Google Scholar
Richey, A. S., Thomas, B. F., Lo, M.-H., Reager, J. T., Famiglietti, J. S., Voss, K., Swenson, S., and Rodell, M.. 2015. Quantifying Renewable Groundwater Stress with GRACE. Water Resources Research, 51:52175238.Google Scholar
Richter, Brian. 2016. Share Water: Using Water Markets and Impact Investment to Drive Sustainability. Washington, DC: The Nature Conservancy.Google Scholar
Shah, T. 2009. Taming the Anarchy: Groundwater Governance in South Asia. Washington, DC: RFF Press.Google Scholar
Shiklomanov, I. A. 1993. World Fresh Water Resource. In: Gleick, Peter H. (ed.), Water in Crisis: A Guide to the World’s Fresh Water Resources. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shiklomanov, I. A. 1996. Assessment of Water Resources and Water Availability in the World. St. Petersburg: State Hydrological Institute.Google Scholar
Shiklomanov, I. A. 1999. World Water Resources: An Appraisal for the 21st Century. IHP Report. Paris: UNESCO.Google Scholar
Shiklomanov, I. A. 2000. Appraisal and Assessment of World Water Resources. Water International, 25(1):1132.Google Scholar
Shen, D. 2015. Groundwater Management in China. Water Policy, 17:6182.Google Scholar
Sato, T., Qadir, M., Yamamotoe, S., Endoe, T., and Zahoor, A.. 2013. Global, Regional, and Country Level Need for Data on Wastewater Generation, Treatment, and Use. Agricultural Water Management, 130:113.Google Scholar
Stocker, T. F., Qin, D., Plattner, G.-K., Alexander, L. V., Allen, S. K., Bindoff, N. L., Bréon, F.-M., Church, J. A., Cubasch, U., Emori, S., Forster, P., Friedlingstein, P., Gillett, N., Gregory, J. M., Hartmann, D. L., Jansen, E., Kirtman, B., Knutti, R., Krishna Kumar, K., Lemke, P., Marotzke, J., Masson-Delmotte, V., Meehl, G. A., Mokhov, I. I., Piao, S., Ramaswamy, V., Randall, D., Rhein, M., Rojas, M., Sabine, C., Shindell, D., Talley, L. D., Vaughan, D. G., and Xie, S.-P.. 2013. Technical Summary. In: Stocker, T. F., Qin, D., Plattner, G.-K., Tignor, M., Allen, S. K., Boschung, J., Nauels, A., Xia, Y., Bex, V., and Midgley, P. M. (eds.), Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 33115. doi:10.1017/ CBO9781107415324.005.Google Scholar
The 2030 Water Resource Group. 2009. Charting Our Water Future: Economic Frameworks to Inform Decision-Making. Available at www.mckinsey.com/business-functions/sustainability-and-resource-productivity/our-insights/charting-our-water-future. Accessed September 11, 2016.Google Scholar
Tsur, Y. 2015. Closing the (Widening) Gap between Natural Water Resources and Water Needs in the Jordan River Basin: A Long-Term Perspective, Water Policy, 17(3):538557.Google Scholar
Tsur, Y. 2020. Optimal Water Pricing: Accounting for Environmental Externalities. Ecological Economics, 170. doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.106429.Google Scholar
Tsur, Y., and Dinar, A.. 1997. On the Relative Efficiency of Alternative Methods for Pricing Irrigation Water and Their Implementation. World Bank Economic Review, 11(2):243262.Google Scholar
UN, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, 2006. World Urbanization Prospects. The 2005 Revision. Available at www.un.org/esa/population/publications/WUP2005/2005WUPHighlights_Final_Report.pdf.Google Scholar
UN, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (UN-DESA-PD). 2015. World Urbanization Prospects: The 2014 Revision, (ST/ESA/SER.A/366), New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
UN-Water. 2015. Annual Report. UN-Water Technical Advisory Unit 7, Avenue de la Paix Case postale 2300. Available at unwater@un.org l www.unwater.org, CH-1211 Genève 2 – Switzerland, August 14.Google Scholar
UN-Water, World Water Day, 2013. Water Quality. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
UN World Urbanization Prospects. 2006. The 2005 Revision. Available at www.un.org/esa/population/publications/WUP2005/2005WUPHighlights_Final_Report.pdf.Google Scholar
Wheeler, S., Loch, A., Zuo, A., and Bjornlund, H.. 2014. Reviewing the Adoption and Impact of Water Markets in the Murray-Darling Basin, Australia. Journal of Hydrology, 518, Part A(10):2841.Google Scholar
Young, R. A., and Loomis, J., 2014. Determining the Economic Value of Water: Concepts and Methods. New York: Resources for the Future Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1.1 Available renewable natural continental and world water resources

Source: Based on data in Shiklomanov, 2000
Figure 1

Figure 1.1 Estimates and forecasts of global water withdrawals between 1900 and 2015 (km3/year).

Source: Adapted from data in Shiklomanov (2000)
Figure 2

Figure 1.2

Figure 3

Figure 1.2

Source: World Data FAO AQUASTAT and Population Data from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015)
Figure 4

Figure 1.3

Figure 5

Figure 1.3

Source: World Data FAO AQUASTAT and Population Data from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division (2015)
Figure 6

Figure 1.4 Major world cities with populations exceeding 5 million inhabitants in 1975.

Source: Authors’ elaboration using data from United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, 2006
Figure 7

Figure 1.5 Major world cities with populations exceeding 5 million inhabitants in 2015.

Source: Authors’ elaboration, using data from Demographia World Urban Areas, 11th Annual Edition, 2016
Figure 8

Figure 1.6 Global drought events between 1900 and 2015.

Source: D. Guha-Sapir, R. Below, Ph. Hoyois – EM-DAT: The CRED/OFDA International Disaster Database – www.emdat.be – Université Catholique de Louvain – Brussels – Belgium. [Permission granted on EM-DAT website]
Figure 9

Figure 1.7 Global flood events between 1900 and 2015.

Source: D. Guha-Sapir, R. Below, Ph. Hoyois – EM-DAT: The CRED/OFDA International Disaster Database – www.emdat.be – Université Catholique de Louvain – Brussels – Belgium. [Permission granted on EM-DAT website]
Figure 10

Table 1.2 Number of drought and flood events between 1900 and 2015 divided into three periods

Source: Data in Figures 1.6 and 1.7
Figure 11

Figure 1.8 Future changes in six main hydrological parameters predicted for 2081–2100.

Source: Adapted from the IPCC WGI AR5 (figure TFE.1, fig. 3), Stocker et al., 2013 [Permission obtained]
Figure 12

Figure 1.9 Annual precipitation in California, 1983 and 2015.

Source: Modified by authors from data provided by Center for Hydrometeorology and Remote Sensing at the University of California, Irvine, http://chrs.web.uci.edu/
Figure 13

Figure 1.10 Annual precipitation in the Jordan Basin States, 1983 and 2015.

Source: Modified by authors from data provided by Center for Hydrometeorology and Remote Sensing at the University of California, Irvine, http://chrs.web.uci.edu/
Figure 14

Figure 1.11 Trends in groundwater levels in major aquifers.

Source: Richey et al. (2015), Quantifying Renewable Groundwater Stress with GRACE, Water Resources Research, doi: 10.1002/2015WR017349 [Permission obtained]
Figure 15

Figure 1.12 Water reservoirs around the world (2011).

Source: www.sciencedaily.com/releases/2011/06/110602102447.htm
Figure 16

Figure 1.13 Ratio of treated wastewater to produced sewage in selected countries (in 2012).

Source: Sato et al. (2013) [Permission obtained]
Figure 17

Table 1.3 Global number of wastewater facilities and capacity (billion cubic meters per year)

Source: FAO AQUASTAT
Figure 18

Table 1.4 Treated wastewater reuse for various purposes in California, 2001, 2009, 2015

Source: Dinar et al., 2018 (Adapted from California State Water Resources Control Board [n.d.])
Figure 19

Figure 1.14

Figure 20

Figure 1.14

Source: Authors’ elaboration, based on data from Hansaki et al. (2016)
Figure 21

Figure 1.15

Figure 22

Figure 1.15

Source: Authors’ elaboration, based on data from Hansaki et al. (2016)
Figure 23

Figure 1.16 Global number of domestic water laws enacted by year, 1815–2015.Note: The decline in 2015 reflects truncation in documented data that will be filled in future years.

Source: FAOLEX (n.d.)
Figure 24

Figure 1.17 Total cumulative number of transboundary river basin water laws and agreements, 1855–2015.Note: The decline in 2015 reflects truncation in documented data that will be filled in future years.

Source: International Water Law Project (n.d.)
Figure 25

Figure 1.18 Total cumulative number of transboundary groundwater laws and agreements, 1915–2015.

Source: International Water Law Project (n.d.)
Figure 26

Table 1.5 Status of water rights, allocation and trade in water-scarce countries

Source: Adapted from The Nature Conservancy, 2016 (fig. 15)
Figure 27

Figure 1.19 Water transfers between water districts in California, 1982–2014.Note: Volumes include short-term contracts, long-term contracts, permanent transfers, and water committed but not transferred.1 Acre-foot = 1,235 cubic meters.

Source: Adapted by authors from Public Policy Institute of California, www.ppic.org/main/publication_show.asp?i=1177
Figure 28

Figure 1.20 Volume of water allocation and entitlement trade in the South Murray–Darling Basin, 1983–2013.Note: ML=Mega Liter. 1 Mega liter = 1,000 cubic meters. Data for 2012 was not available in the sources used. Water year in Australia starts in July. Therefore, the year marks on the horizontal axis should be read: 1983–1984 for 1983, etc.South Murray–Darling Basin (SMDB) is presented because the lion share of the transactions in Australia take place in the SMDB. For example, in 2011–2012, 74% of water entitlement trade and 94% of water allocation trade in the Australian water market (1,437,000,000 cubic meters and 429,700,000 cubic meters, respectively) took place in Murray–Darling Basin.

Source: Authors’ elaboration based on data in Wheeler et al., 2014 (for 1983–2011) and in Wheeler (2016, personal communication)
Figure 29

Figure 1.21 Number of registered transactions in water rights in Chile between 1999 and 2012.Note: Data on non-consumptive trade exists only for 2005–2012.

Source: Elaborated by authors based on data in Consultorias LIDD (2013)
Figure 30

Table 1.6 Main methods for pricing irrigation water consumption

Source: Based on Tsur and Dinar (1997) and Dinar and Saleth (2005)
Figure 31

Table 1.7 Main methods for pricing residential water consumption

Source: Expanded from Dinar and Saleth (2005)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×