Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wg55d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-15T16:37:44.483Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - The End of Special Interests Theory and the Beginning of a More Positive View of Democratic Politics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2010

Edward J. Balleisen
Affiliation:
Duke University, North Carolina
David A. Moss
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Get access

Summary

Public choice (sometimes known as rational choice) assumes that individuals act to promote their own interests. From this simple assumption, a large body of theoretical and empirical work has been spawned. Much of this research shows that bureaucrats, politicians, and pressure groups get their way at the expense of the voters and that regulation reflects the desires of these concentrated interests rather than the appropriate balancing of all the costs and benefits. But if one really believes in the economic model of behavior, then one should be skeptical of such results. After all, it was Adam Smith who showed that the self-interest of the baker and the candlestick maker leads them to provide what consumers desire. So by the same economic logic, one should expect that the invisible hand works for the democratic political system, as well. Now there are counter arguments to this last statement, but in this chapter I counter these counter arguments by using standard economic theory and methodology. Along the way, I show that many of the negative results arise because the authors (1) have incorrectly assumed that the political system is characterized by monopoly rather than by competition, and (2) have implicitly assumed that voters are irrational, which, of course, is contrary to the rational choice paradigm. The arguments that I use against the theory of special interests can also serve as the foundation for a theory that democratic markets are well served by the invisible hand.

Type
Chapter
Information
Government and Markets
Toward a New Theory of Regulation
, pp. 193 - 212
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alford, Robert R., and Friedland, Roger. 1985. Powers of Theory: Capitalism, the State and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arceneaux, Kevin. 2005. “Do Campaigns Help Voters Learn? A Cross-National Analysis.” British Journal of Political Science 36: 159–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1985. “Public Policies, Pressure Groups and Deadweight Costs.” Journal of Public Economics 28: 329–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breton, Albert. 1996. Competitive Governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Caplan, Bryan. 2007. The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Congleton, Roger. 1996. The Political Economy of Environmental Protection. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1982. Economic, Legal and Political Dimensions of Competition. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Duggan, John. 2006. “Candidate Objectives and Electoral Equilibrium.” in Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, eds. Weingast, Barry and Wittman, Donald (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Domhoff, William G. 2005. Who Rules America? Power, Politics and Social Change. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Hinich, Melvin. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Finkel, Steven E. 1993. “Re-examining the ‘Minimal Effects’ Model in Recent Presidential Campaigns.” Journal of Politics 55: 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freedman, Paul, Franz, Michael, and Goldstein, Kenneth. 2004. “Campaign Advertising and Democratic Citizenship.” American Journal of Political Science 48: 723–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Friedman, Rose. 1980. Free to Choose. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Gelman, Andrew, and King, Gary. 1993. “Why Are American Presidential Election Campaign Polls So Variable When Votes Are So Predictable?British Journal of Political Science 23: 409–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E.. 1996. “Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics.” Review of Economic Studies 63: 265–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hillman, Arye L. 1989. The Political Economy of Protection. Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Iyengar, Shanto, and Simon, Adam F.. 2000. “New Perspective and Evidence on Political Communication and Campaign Effects.” Annual Review of Pscyhology 51: 149–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keohane, Nathaniel O., Revesz, Richard L., and Stavins, Robert N.. 1998. “The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy.” Harvard Environmental Law Review 22: 313–354.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John. 1989. Congressmen's Voting Decision. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreuger, Anne O. 1974. “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society.” American Economic Review 64: 291–303.Google Scholar
Londregan, John. 2006. “Political Income Redistribution,” in Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, eds. Weingast, Barry and Wittman, Donald (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Lupia, Arthur. 1994. “Shortcuts versus Encyclopedias: Information and Voting Behavior in California Insurance Reform Elections.” American Political Science Review 88: 63–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mosca, Gaetano. 1939. The Ruling Class. Translated by Kahn, H.D.. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Oates, Wallace E. 2001. “The Political Economy of Environmental Policy.” Resources for the Future Discussion Paper01–55.Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam. 1984. “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 19: 211–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1974. “Theories of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics 5: 335–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1981. “Political Preferences for the Pork Barrel: A Generalization.” American Journal of Political Science 25: 96–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1994. “Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 19: 149–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stavins, Robert N. 2004. The Political Economy of Environmental Regulation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Sumner, Daniel. 2007. “Farm Subsidy Tradition and Modern Agricultural Realities.” Paper prepared for American Enterprise Institute project on Agricultural Policy for the 2007 Farm Bill and Beyond.
Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy 64: 416–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1967. “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft.” Western Economic Journal 5: 224–32.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1989. “Pressure Group Size and the Politics of Income Redistribution.” Social Choice and Welfare 6: 275–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, Donald A. 1995. The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why Democracies are Efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald. 2007. “Candidate Quality, Pressure Group Endorsements and the Nature of Political Advertising.” European Journal of Political Economy 23: 360–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, Donald. Forthcoming. “How Campaign Endorsements Activate Uninformed Voters.” Economic Journal.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×