Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-x24gv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-16T19:56:01.728Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Chapter 2 - Trust and Behavioral Economics

Exploration of Trust Based on Game Theory

from Part I - Fundamental Level of Trust

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 December 2021

Frank Krueger
Affiliation:
George Mason University, Virginia
Get access

Summary

This chapter explores the role of trust in facilitating economic transactions. We cover seminal and more recent research suggesting how the game-theoretic approach in economics relies on trust to explain market transactions between two parties – individuals and firms. We also study how the experimental results of the trust game (and assorted variations) introduced by economists helps better our understanding of how trust affects the underlying dynamic in dyadic transactions. Relationships between trust levels in society and macroeconomic growth are also explored.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2000). The moonlighting game: An experimental study on reciprocity and retribution. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 42(2), 265277. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167–2681(00)00089-5Google Scholar
Alesina, A., & La Ferrara, E. (2002). Who trusts others? Journal of Public Economics, 85(2), 207234. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047–2727(01)00084-6Google Scholar
Alós-Ferrer, C., & Farolfi, F. (2019). Trust games and beyond. Frontiers in Neuroscience, 13, 114. https://doi.org/10.3389/fnins.2019.00887Google Scholar
Anderhub, V., Engelmann, D., & Güth, W. (2002). An experimental study of the repeated trust game with incomplete information. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 48(2), 197216. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167–2681(01)00216-5Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1972). Gifts and exchanges. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 1(4), 343362.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1974). The limits of organization. W. W. Norton & Company. https://doi.org/10.1177/000271627541700157Google Scholar
Banerjee, R. (2018). On the interpretation of World Values Survey trust question: Global expectations vs. local beliefs. European Journal of Political Economy, 55, 491510. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.04.008Google Scholar
Becker, G. M., DeGroot, M. H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring utility by a single‐response sequential method. Behavioral Sciences, 9(3), 226232. https://doi.org/10.1002/bs.3830090304Google Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 122142. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1995.1027Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C., Xiao, E., & Muldoon, R. (2011). Trustworthiness is a social norm, but trusting is not. Politics, Philosophy & Economics, 10(2), 170187. https://doi.org/10.1177/1470594X10387260Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, C. (2008). Social trust and fractionalization: A possible reinterpretation. European Sociological Review, 24(3), 271283. https://doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcn004Google Scholar
Bohnet, I., Greig, F., Herrmann, B., & Zeckhauser, R. (2008). Betrayal aversion: Evidence from Brazil, China, Oman, Switzerland, Turkey, and the United States. American Economic Review, 98(1), 294310. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.1.294Google Scholar
Bohnet, I., & Meier, S. (2012). Trust, distrust, and bargaining. In Croson, R. & Bolton, G. E. (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of economic conflict resolution (pp. 183198). Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199730858.013.0017Google Scholar
Burt, R. S., & Knez, M. (1996). Trust and third-party gossip. In Kramer, R. M. & Tyler, T. R. (Eds.), Trust in organizations: Frontiers of theory and research (pp. 6889). Sage Publications, Inc. https://doi.org/10.2307/3857331Google Scholar
Camerer, C., & Vepsalainen, A. (1988). The economic efficiency of corporate culture. Strategic Management Journal, 9(S1), 115126. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250090712Google Scholar
Camerer, C., & Weigelt, K. (1988). Experimental tests of a sequential equilibrium reputation model. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 56(1), 136. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911840Google Scholar
Chang, L. J., & Smith, A. (2015). Social emotions and psychological games. Current Opinion in Behavioral Sciences, 5, 133140. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cobeha.2015.09.010Google Scholar
Cohn, A., Maréchal, M. A., Tannenbaum, D., & Zünd, C. L. (2019). Civic honesty around the globe. Science, 365(6448), 7073. https://doi.org/10.1016/10.1126/science.aau8712CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S95S120. https://doi.org/10.1086/228943Google Scholar
Cook, K. S., & State, B. (2015). Trust and economic organization. In Scott, R. & Kosslyn, S. (Eds.), Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences (pp. 111). Wiley.Google Scholar
Dirks, K. T., & Ferrin, D. L. (2001). The role of trust in organizational settings. Organizational Science, 12(4), 450467. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.12.4.450.10640Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268298. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003Google Scholar
Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2), 293315. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159181. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.3.159Google Scholar
Geanakoplos, J., Pearce, D., & Stacchetti, E. (1989). Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 1(1), 6079. https://doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(89)90005-5Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1973). Getting a job: A study of contacts and careers. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in financial development. American Economic Review, 94(3), 526556. https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828041464498Google Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Trusting the stock market. The Journal of Finance, 63(6), 25572600. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01408.xGoogle Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2009). Cultural biases in economic exchange? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 10951131. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2009.124.3.1095CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagan, J., & McCarthy, B. (1998). Mean streets: Youth crime and homelessness. Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511625497Google Scholar
Ho, B. (2012). Apologies as signals: With evidence from a trust game. Management Science, 58(1), 141158. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1410CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, N. D., & Mislin, A. A. (2011). Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 32(5), 865889. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2011.05.007Google Scholar
King-Casas, B., Sharp, C., Lomax-Bream, L., Lohrenz, T., Fonagy, P., & Montague, P. R. (2008). The rupture and repair of cooperation in borderline personality disorder. Science, 321(5890), 806810. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1156902Google Scholar
Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 12511288. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355300555475CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M. (1990). Corporate culture and economic theory. In Alt, J. & Shepsle, K. (Eds.), Perspectives on positive political economy (pp. 90143). Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511571657.006Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M., Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., & Wilson, R. (1982). Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 245252. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(82)90029-1Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American community. Simon & Schuster. https://doi.org/10.1145/358916.361990Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D., Leonardi, R., & Nanetti, R. Y. (1994). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.2307/2075319Google Scholar
Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 12811302.Google Scholar
Rose, D. R., & Clear, T. R. (1998). Incarceration, social capital, and crime: Implications for social disorganization theory. Criminology, 36(3), 441480. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-9125.1998.tb01255.xGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, D. M., Sitkin, S. B., Burt, R. S., & Camerer, C. (1998). Not so different after all: A cross-discipline view of trust. Academy of Management Review, 23(3), 393404. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1998.926617Google Scholar
Sally, D. (1995). Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: A meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992. Rationality and Society, 7(1), 5892. https://doi.org/10.1177/1043463195007001004Google Scholar
Small, M. L. (2004). Villa Victoria: The transformation of social capital in a Boston barrio. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sobel, J. (2002). Can we trust social capital? Journal of Economic Literature, 40(1), 139154. https://doi.org/10.1257/0022051027001Google Scholar
Solow, R. M. (1995). But verify. New Republic, 213(11), 3639. [Review of Fukuyama, Trust: The social virtues and the creation of prosperity, The Free Press.]Google Scholar
Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2011). Trust in public institutions over the business cycle. American Economic Review, 101(3), 281287. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.3.281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thielmann, I., & Hilbig, B. E. (2015). Trust: An integrative review from a person–situation perspective. Review of General Psychology, 19(3), 249277. https://doi.org/10.1037/gpr0000046Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×