Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T05:55:15.294Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 January 2022

Joseph Jupille
Affiliation:
University of Colorado Boulder
James A. Caporaso
Affiliation:
University of Washington, Seattle
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2022

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbott, Andrew. 1992. An Old Institutionalist Reads the New Institutionalism. Contemporary Sociology 21: 754756.Google Scholar
Abrutyn, Seth. 2014. Revisiting Institutionalism in Sociology: Putting the “Institution” Back in Institutional Analysis. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron. 2006. A Simple Model of Inefficient Institutions. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 108 (4): 515546.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Cantoni, Davide, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2011. The Consequences of Radical Reform: The French Revolution. American Economic Review 101 (7): 32863307.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Johnson, Simon. 2005. Unbundling Institutions. Journal of Political Economy 113 (5): 949995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2001. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review 91 (5): 13691401.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2002. Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 12311294.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, Robinson, James A.. 2005. Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. In Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume IA, edited by Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven N., 386472. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty. New York: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2019. The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies and the Fate of Liberty. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Acharya, Avidit, and Lee, Alexander. 2019. Path Dependence in European Development: Medieval Politics, Conflict, and State Building. Comparative Political Studies 52 (13–14): 21712206.Google Scholar
Agar, Michael. 1985. Institutional Discourse. Text 5 (3): 147168.Google Scholar
Aggarwal, Vinod K. 1998. Reconciling Multiple Institutions: Bargaining, Linkages and Nesting. In Institutional Designs for a Complex World: Bargaining, Linkages and Nesting, edited by Aggarwal, Vinod K., 131. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1970. The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (3): 488500.Google Scholar
Alexander, Jeffrey C., ed. 1987. The Micro–Macro Link. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. 2011. The Institutional Revolution: Measurement and the Economic Emergence of the Modern World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Almandoz, Juan. 2012. Arriving at the Starting Line: The Impact of Community and Financial Logics on New Banking Ventures. The Academy of Management Journal 55 (6): 13811406.Google Scholar
Alter, Karen J, and Raustiala, Kai. 2018. The Rise of International Regime Complexity. Annual Review of Law and Social Science 14: 329349.Google Scholar
Althusser, Louis. 1971 [2001]. Lenin and Philosophy and Other Essays. Introduction by Jameson, Fredric. Translated from the French by Brewster, Ben. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Alvesson, Mats, and Spicer, André. 2019. Neo-institutional Theory and Organization Studies: A Mid-life Crisis? Organization Studies 40 (2): 199218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvesson, Mats, Hallett, Tim, and Spicer, André. 2019. Uninhibited Institutionalisms. Journal of Management Inquiry 28 (2): 119127.Google Scholar
Aminzade, Ronald. 1992. Historical Sociology and Time. Sociological Methods and Research 20 (4): 456480.Google Scholar
Ancona, Deborah G., and Chong, C.. 1996. Entrainment: Pace, Cycle, and Rhythm in Organizational Behavior. In Research in Organizational Behavior, Volume 18, edited by Staw, B. M. and Cummings, L. L., 251284. Greenwich: JAI.Google Scholar
Ancona, Deborah G., Goodman, Paul S., Lawrence, Barbara S., and Tushman, Michael L.. 2001. Time: A New Research Lens. Academy of Management Review 26 (4): 645663.Google Scholar
Anderson, Perry. 2013 [1996]. Passages from Antiquity to Feudalism. London and New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Ansell, Chris. 2006. Network Institutionalism. In Rhodes, Binder, and Rockman 2006, 75–89.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, and Snyder, James M. Jr. 1999. Money and Institutional Power. Texas Law Review 77 (7): 16731704.Google Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko. 2001. Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko. 2007. Endogenizing Institutions and Institutional Changes. Journal of Institutional Economics 3 (1): 131.Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah. 1970. On Violence. New York: Harcourt.Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah. 1985 [1951]. The Origins of Totalitarianism, new edition with added prefaces. New York: Harcourt.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York: W. W. Norton and Co.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian. 1989. Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-in by Historical Events. Economic Journal 99 (394): 116131.Google Scholar
Auster, R. D. 1974. The GPITPC and Institutional Entropy. Public Choice 19 (Fall): 7783.Google Scholar
Auster, Richard. 1983. Institutional Entropy, again. Public Choice 40 (2): 211216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azari, Julia R., and Smith, Jennifer K.. 2012. Unwritten Rules: Informal Institutions in Established Democracies. Perspectives on Politics 10 (1): 3755.Google Scholar
Bacchi, Carol, and Rönnblom, Malin. 2014. Feminist Discursive Institutionalism: A Poststructural Alternative. NORA – Nordic Journal of Feminist and Gender Research 22 (3): 170186.Google Scholar
Bachrach, Peter, and Baratz, Morton S.. 1962. Two Faces of Power. American Political Science Review 56 (4): 947952.Google Scholar
Bachrach, Peter, and Baratz, Morton S.. 1963. Decisions and Nondecisions: An Analytical Framework. American Political Science Review 57 (3): 632642.Google Scholar
Baldwin, David A. 1985. Economic Statecraft. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Barkanov, Boris. 2013. Institutionalism. Britannica Academic, Encyclopædia Britannica, June 6, 2013. academic.eb.com/levels/collegiate/article/institutionalism/600953.Google Scholar
Barnes, Thomas G. 1961. Star Chamber Mythology. American Journal of Legal History 5: 111.Google Scholar
Barrett, Deborah, and Frank, David. 1997. Population Control for National Development: From World Discourse to National Policies. In Boli and Thomas 1999, 198–221.Google Scholar
Barrett, Michele. 1972. Introduction. In The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State, Engels, Friedrich, 730. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Bartlett, Randall. 1989. Economics and Power: An Inquiry into Human Relations and Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 2002. A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal Rights, and the Scope of the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H. 1988. Contra Contractarianism: Some Reflections on the New Institutionalism. Politics and Society 16: 387401.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H. 1997. Area Studies and the Discipline: A Useful Controversy? PS: Political Science and Politics 30 (2): 166169.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H. 2014. The New Institutionalism. In Institutions, Property Rights, and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North, edited by Galiani, Sebastian and Sened, Itai, 5065. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Battilana, Julie, and D’Aunno, Thomas. 2009. Institutional Work and the Paradox of Embedded Agency. In Lawrence et al. 2009a, 31–58.Google Scholar
Baum, Joel, and Oliver, Christine. 1991. Institutional Linkages and Organizational Mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly 36 (2): 187218.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Breunig, Christian, Green-Pedersen, Christoffer, Jones, Bryan D, Mortensen, Peter B, Nuytemans, Michiel, and Walgrave, Stefaan. 2009. Punctuated Equilibrium in Comparative Perspective. American Journal of Political Science 53 (3): 603620.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Breunig, Christian, and Grossman, Emiliano, eds. 2019. Comparative Policy Agendas: Theory, Tools, Data. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., and Jones, Bryan D.. 1993. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Jones, Bryan D., and MacLeod, Michael C.. 2000. The Evolution of Legislative Jurisdictions. Journal of Politics 62 (2): 321349.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Tom, Buckley, Walter, and Burns, Tom R.. 1975. Meta-power and Relational Control in Social Life. Social Science Information 14 (6): 4978.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Tom, and Burns, Tom R.. 1975. The Structuring of International Economic Relations. International Studies Quarterly 19 (2): 126159.Google Scholar
Beck, Colin J., Drori, Gili S., and Meyer, John W.. 2012. World Influences on Human Rights Language in Constitutions: A Cross-national Study. International Sociology 27 (4): 483501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Howard S. 1963. Outsiders: Studies in the Sociology of Deviance. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Bell, Roderick, Edwards, David V., and Wagner, R. Harrison, eds. 1969. Political Power: A Reader in Theory and Research. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, and Mookherjee, Dilip. 1987. Institutional Structure and the Logic of Ongoing Collective Action. American Political Science Review 81 (1): 129154.Google Scholar
Berger, Peter L., and Luckmann, Thomas. 1966. The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City: Doubleday and Company.Google Scholar
Berkovitch, Nitza. 1999. The Emergence and Transformation of the International Women’s Movement. In Boli and Thomas 1999, 100–126.Google Scholar
Berman, Elizabeth Popp. 2012. Explaining the Move toward the Market in US Academic Science: How Institutional Logics Can Change without Institutional Entrepreneurs. Theory and Society 41 (3): 261299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, Marianne, and Mullainathan, Sendhil. 2003. Are Emily and Greg More Employable than Lakisha and Jamal? A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination. American Economic Review 94 (4): 9911013.Google Scholar
Beyer, Jürgen. 2010. The Same or Not the Same: On the Variety of Mechanisms of Path Dependence. International Journal of Social Sciences 5 (1): 111.Google Scholar
Binns, Christopher A. 1979. The Changing Face of Power: Revolution and Accommodation in the Development of the Soviet Ceremonial System: Part I. Man (new series) 14 (4): 585606.Google Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa, and Chaney, Eric. 2013. The Feudal Revolution and Europe’s Rise: Political Divergence of the Christian West and the Muslim World before 1500 CE. American Political Science Review 107 (1): 1634.Google Scholar
Blondel, Jean. 2006. About Institutions, Mainly, but Not Exclusively, Political. In Rhodes, Binder, and Rockman 2006, 716–730.Google Scholar
Boas, Taylor. 2007. Conceptualizing Continuity and Change: The Composite-Standard Model of Path Dependence. Journal of Theoretical Politics 19 (1): 3354.Google Scholar
Boli, John. 1987. World Polity Sources of Expanding State Authority and Organization, 1870–1970. In Thomas et al. 1987, 71–91.Google Scholar
Boli, John. 1999. Conclusion: World Authority Structures and Legitimations. In Boli and Thomas 1999, 267–300.Google Scholar
Boli, John, and Thomas, George M., eds. 1999. Constructing World Culture: International Nongovernmental Organizations since 1875. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Bonilla-Silva, Eduardo. 2017. Racism without Racists: Color-Blind Racism and the Persistence of Racial Inequality in America, 5th edition. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1989. Three Faces of Power. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Bouma, Gary. 1998. Distinguishing Institutions and Organisations in Social Change. Journal of Sociology 34 (3): 232245.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1990. The Logic of Practice. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1991. Language and Symbolic Power. Edited and introduced by Thompson, John B., translated by Raymond, Gino and Adamson, Matthew. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre. 2014. On the State: Lectures at the Collège de France, 1989–1992, edited by Champagne, Patrick, Lenoir, Remi, Poupeau, Franck and Rivière, Marie-Christine. Translated by Fernbach, David. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Boxenbaum, Eva, and Jonsson, Stefan. 2017. Isomorphism, Diffusion and Decoupling: Concept Evolution and Theoretical Challenges. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 77–101.Google Scholar
Boxenbaum, Eva, and Pedersen, Jesper Strandgaard. 2009. Scandinavian Institutionalism: A Case of Institutional Work. In Lawrence et al. 2009a, 178–204.Google Scholar
Bradley, Karen, and Ramirez, Francisco O.. 1996. World Polity Promotion of Gender Parity: Women’s Share of Higher Education, 1965–85. Research in Sociology of Education and Socialization 11: 6391.Google Scholar
Braudel, Fernand. 1980. On History. Translated by Matthews, Sarah. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Braudel, Fernand. 1992 [1979]. Civilization and Capitalism, 15th–18th Century, Volume 2, The Wheels of Commerce, translated from the French, revised by Reynolds, Siân. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Braybrooke, David, and Lindblom, Charles E.. 1963. A Strategy of Decision. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Brekhus, Wayne. 1998. A Sociology of the Unmarked: Redirecting Our Focus. Sociological Theory 16 (1): 3451.Google Scholar
Brinton, Mary C., and Nee, Victor, eds. 1998. The New Institutionalism in Sociology. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Broom, Leonard, and Selznick, Phillip. 1955. Sociology: A Text with Adapted Readings. New York: Row, Peterson.Google Scholar
Brousseau, Éric, and Glachant, Jean-Michel, eds. 2008. New Institutional Economics: A Guidebook. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brown, Roger, and Gilman, Albert. 1960. The Pronouns of Power and Solidarity. In Style in Language, edited by Sebeok, Thomas A., 253276. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Brunsson, Nils. 1989. The Organization of Hypocrisy: Talk, Decisions, and Actions in Organizations. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 2001. Game Theory, Mathematics, and Economics. Journal of Economic Methodology 8 (1): 2732.Google Scholar
Buchanan, Sean. 2020. Corralling Organizational Institutionalism. Journal of Management Inquiry 29 (3): 251253.Google Scholar
Buttel, Frederick H. 2000. World Society, the Nation-State, and Environmental Protection. American Sociological Review 65: 117121.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1995a. Rational Actors, Equilibrium, and Social Institutions. In Knight and Sened 1995, 57–93.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1995b. The Rational Choice Theory of Social Institutions: Cooperation, Coordination, and Communication. In Modern Political Economy: Old Topics, New Directions, edited by Banks, Jeffrey S. and Hanushek, Eric A., 216267. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cammack, Paul. 1992. The New Institutionalism: Predatory Rule, Institutional Persistence, and Macro-social Change. Economy and Society 21 (4): 397429.Google Scholar
Campbell, Donald T. 1969. Ethnocentrism of Disciplines and the Fish-Scale Model of Omniscience. In Interdisciplinary Relationships in the Social Sciences, edited by Sherif, Muzafer and Sherif, Carolyn W., 328348. Chicago: Aldine Publishing.Google Scholar
Campbell, John L. 1998. Institutional Analysis and the Role of Ideas in Political Economy. Theory and Society 27 (3): 377409.Google Scholar
Campbell, John L. 2004. Institutional Change and Globalization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, John L. 2010. Institutional Reproduction and Change. In Morgan et al. 2010a, 87–115.Google Scholar
Capoccia, Giovanni, and Daniel Kelemen, R.. 2007. The Study of Critical Junctures: Theory, Narrative, and Counterfactuals in Historical Institutionalism. World Politics 59 (3): 341369.Google Scholar
Capoccia, Giovanni. 2016a. Critical Junctures. In Fioretos, Falleti, and Sheingate 2016a, 89–106.Google Scholar
Capoccia, Giovanni. 2016b. When Do Institutions “Bite”? Historical Institutionalism and the Politics of Institutional Change. Comparative Political Studies 49, 8 (July): 10951127.Google Scholar
Carey, John M. 2000. Parchment, Equilibria, and Institutions. Comparative Political Studies 33, 6/7 (August/September): 735761.Google Scholar
Chacar, Ana, Celo, Sokol, and Hesterly, William. 2018. Change dynamics in institutional discontinuities: Do formal or informal institutions change first? Lessons from rule changes in professional American baseball. Business History 60 (5): 728753.Google Scholar
Christensen, Tom, and Lægreid, Per. 2013. SCANCOR and Norwegian Public Administration Research Development. Nordiske Organisasjonsstudier 15 (4): 91110.Google Scholar
Ciavatta, David. 2014. The event of absolute freedom: Hegel on the French Revolution and its calendar. Philosophy and Social Criticism 40 (6): 577605.Google Scholar
Clark, Gregory. 1996. The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth: England, 1540–1800. Journal of Interdisciplinary History 26, 4 (Spring): 563588.Google Scholar
Clegg, John J. 2015. Capitalism and Slavery. Critical Historical Studies 2, 2 (Fall): 281304.Google Scholar
Clegg, Stewart R. 1989. Frameworks of Power. London and Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clemens, Elisabeth S., and Cook, James M.. 1999. Politics and Institutionalism: Explaining Durability and Change. Annual Review of Sociology 25: 441466.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4 (November): 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3 (1): 144.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1988a. The Nature of the Firm: Origin. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 4 (1): 317.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1988b. The Nature of the Firm: Influence. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 4 (1): 3347.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1988c. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cobb, Roger W. and Ross, Marc Howard. 1997. Cultural Strategies of Agenda Denial. Lawrence: University of Kansas Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, G.A. 1986. Forces and Relations of Production. In Analytical Marxism, edited by Roemer, John, 1122. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Michael D., March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1972. A Garbage Can Model of Organizational Choice. Administrative Science Quarterly 17, 1 (March): 125.Google Scholar
Cole, Wade H. 2012. Human Rights as Myth and Ceremony? Reevaluating the Effectiveness of Human Rights Treaties, 1981–2007. American Journal of Sociology 117, 4 (January): 11311171.Google Scholar
Cole, Wade H. 2017. World polity or world society? Delineating the statist and societal dimensions of the global institutional system. International Sociology 32 (1): 86104.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1990. The Emergence of Norms. In Hechter, Opp and Wippler 1990, 35–59.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1998. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Collier, Ruth Berins, and Collier, David. 1991. Shaping the political arena: critical junctures, the labor movement, and regime dynamics in Latin America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Collingwood, R.G. 1956. The Idea of History. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Colombero, Sylvain, and Boxenbaum, Eva. 2019. Authentication as Institutional Maintenance Work. Journal of Management Studies 56, 2 (March): 408440.Google Scholar
Colomy, Paul. 1998. Neofunctionalism and Neoinstitutionalism: Human Agency and Interest in Institutional Change. Sociological Forum 13, 2 (June): 265300.Google Scholar
Conran, James, and Thelen, Kathleen. 2016. Institutional Change. In Fioretos, Falleti, and Sheingate 2016a, 51–70.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 2012. Was the Glorious Revolution a Constitutional Watershed? Journal of Economic History 72 (3): 567600.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 2016. Marketing Sovereign Promises: Monopoly Brokerage and the Growth of the English State. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 2017. Political Institutions, Economic Liberty, and the Great Divergence. Journal of Economic History 77 (3): 724755.Google Scholar
Crouch, Colin. 2010. Complementarity. In Morgan et al. 2010a, 117–137.Google Scholar
Crouch, Colin, and Farrell, Henry. 2004. Breaking the Path of Institutional Development? Alternatives to the New Determinism. Rationality and Society 16 (1): 543.Google Scholar
Crouch, Colin, and Keune, Maarten. 2005. Changing Dominant Practice: Making Use of Institutional Diversity in Hungary and the United Kingdom. In Streeck and Thelen 2005a, 83–102.Google Scholar
Cyert, Richard M., and March, James G.. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Dacin, M. Tina, Goodstein, Jerry, and Richard Scott, W.. 2002. Institutional Theory and Institutional Change: Introduction to the Special Research Forum. Academy of Management Journal 45 (1): 4556.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1957. The Concept of Power. Behavioral Science 2: 201215.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1958. A Critique of the Ruling Elite Model. American Political Science Review 52: 463469.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Darden, Keith. 2008. The Integrity of Corrupt States: Graft as an Informal State Institution. Politics and Society 36 (1): 3559.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. 1985. Clio and the Economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review 75 (2): 332338.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. 1994. Why Are Institutions the “Carriers of History”? Path Dependence and the Evolution of Conventions, Organizations, and Institutions. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 5 (2): 205220.Google Scholar
David, Paul A. 2007. Path Dependence: A Foundational Concept for Historical Social Science. Cliometrica 1 (2): 91114.Google Scholar
Davidson, Donald. 1963. Actions, Reasons, and Causes. Journal of Philosophy 60 (3): 685700.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. 2003. The Theory of the Individual in Economics: Identity and Value. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Davis, Lance E., and North, Douglass C.. 1971. Institutional Change and American Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
De Certau, Michel, Julia, Dominique, and Revel, Jacques. 1975. Une politique de la langue – La Révolution Française et les patois: l’enquête de Grégoire. Paris: Gallimard.Google Scholar
De Moor, Tine. 2015. The Dilemma of the Commoners: Understanding the Use of Common-Pool Resources in Long-Term Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
De Soto, Hernando. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Succeeds in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
De Vaujany, François-Xavier, Adrot, Anouck, Boxenbaum, Eva, and Leca, Bernard, eds. 2019. Materiality in Institutions: Spaces, Embodiment and Technology in Management and Organization. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1969. Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint. Journal of Law and Economics 12 (1): 122.Google Scholar
DiAngelo, Robin. 2017. White Fragility: Why It’s So Hard for White People to Talk about Racism. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Krehbiel, Keith. 2003. Institutionalism as a Methodology. Journal of Theoretical Politics 15 (2): 123144.Google Scholar
Dille, Therese, and Söderlund, Jonas. 2011. Managing Inter-institutional Projects: The Significance of Isochronism, Timing Norms and Temporal Misfits. International Journal of Project Management 29: 480490.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J. 1988. Interest and Agency in Institutional Theory. In Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Culture and Environment, edited by Zucker, Lynne G., 322. New York: Ballinger.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Powell, Walter W.. 1983. The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields. American Sociological Review 48 (2): 147160.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Powell, Walter W.. 1991. Introduction. In The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, edited by Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J., 138. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Djelic, Marie-Laure. 2010. Institutional Perspectives: Working Towards Coherence, or Irreconcilable Diversity? In Morgan et al. 2010a, 15–40.Google Scholar
Domar, Evsey. 1946. Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment. Econometrica 14 (2): 137147.Google Scholar
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dover, Graham, and Lawrence, Thomas B.. 2010. Technology, Institutions, and Entropy: Understanding the Critical and Creative Role of Maintenance Work. In Technology and Organization: Essays in Honour of Joan Woodward, edited by Phillips, Nelson, Sewell, Graham, and Griffiths, Dorothy, 259264. Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.Google Scholar
Dowding, Keith. 2006. Three Dimensional Power: A Discussion of Steven Lukes’ Power – A Radical View. Policy Studies Review 4: 136145.Google Scholar
Downey, Liam, Lawrence, Elizabeth, Pyles, Micah, and Lee, Derek. 2020. Power, Hegemony, and World Society Theory: A Critical Evaluation. Socius 6: 122.Google Scholar
Dromi, Shai. 2020. Examining the Links between Beliefs and Institutional Emergence. Sociology Compass 14 (2): 113.Google Scholar
Drori, Gili S. 2003. Science in the Modern World Polity: Institutionalization and Globalization. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Drori, Gili S., and Preminger, Briana. 2018. Between Institutional Theory and Lefebvre: Sensemaking, Logics and Enactment of, and in, Space. In Organizational Space and beyond: The Significance of Henri Lefebvre for Organization Studies, edited by Kingma, Sytze F., Wasserman, Varda, and Dale, Karen, unpaginated e-book version. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dunn, Mary B., and Jones, Candace. 2010. Institutional Logics and Institutional Pluralism: The Contestation of Care and Science Logics in Medical Education, 1967–2005. Administrative Science Quarterly 55 (1): 114149.Google Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. 1938. The Rules of Sociological Method, 8th edition. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. 1966 [1895]. The Rules of Sociological Method, 8th edition. Translated by Solovay, Sarah A. and Mueller, John H.. Edited by Catlin, George E. G.. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Easterly, William. 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Eisenstadt, Shmuel N. 1968. Social Institutions. In International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, Volume 14, edited by Sills, David L., 409420. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Eisenstadt, Shmuel N. 1980. Cultural Orientations, Institutional Entrepreneurs and Social Change. American Journal of Sociology 85: 840869.Google Scholar
Elder, Charles, and Cobb, Roger. 1983. Participation in American Politics: The Dynamics of Agenda Building. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1984. Ulysses and the Sirens, revised edition. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1985. Making Sense of Marx. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Engels, Friedrich. 1972 [1884]. The Origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Ensminger, Jean. 1992. Making a Market: The Institutional Transformation of an African Society. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ensminger, Jean. 1998. Anthropology and the New Institutionalism. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 154 (4): 774789.Google Scholar
Ensminger, Jean, and Knight, Jack. 1997. Changing Social Norms: Common Property, Bridewealth, and Clan Exogamy. Current Anthropology 38: 124.Google Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Etzioni, Amitai. 1968. The Active Society: A Theory of Societal and Political Process. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Eyre, Dana P., and Suchman, Mark C.. 1996. Status, Norms and the Proliferation of Conventional Weapons: An Institutional Theory Approach. In The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics, edited by Katzenstein, Peter J., 79113. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Fairclough, Norman. 1989. Language and Power. Essex: Addison, Wesley Longman Limited.Google Scholar
Falleti, Tulia G. 2010. Infiltrating the State: The Evolution of Health Care Reforms in Brazil, 1964-1988. In Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, edited by Mahoney, James and Thelen, Kathleen, 3862. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Farrell, Henry, and Héritier, Adrienne. 2007. Introduction: Contested Competences in the European Union. West European Politics 30 (2): 227243.Google Scholar
Farrell, Henry. 2018. The Shared Challenges of Institutional Theories: Rational Choice, Historical Institutionalism, and Sociological Institutionalism. In Knowledge and Institutions [Knowledge and Space 13], edited by Glückler, Johannes, Suddaby, Roy, and Lenz, Regina, 2344. Cham, Switzerland: Springer.Google Scholar
Farrell, Theo. 2005. World Culture and Military Power. Security Studies 14 (3): 448488.Google Scholar
Fenoaltea, S. 1975. The Rise and Fall of a Theoretical Model. Journal of Economic History 35: 386409.Google Scholar
Fershtman, Chaim. 1989. Fixed Rules and Decision Rules: Time Consistency and Subgame Perfection. Economics Letters 30: 191194.Google Scholar
Field, Alexander James. 1979. On the Explanation of Rules Using Rational Choice Models. Journal of Economic Issues 13: 4972.Google Scholar
Field, Alexander James. 1981. The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with Special Reference to the North/Thomas Model of Pre-1500 Europe. Explorations in Economic History 18: 174198.Google Scholar
Field, Alexander James. 1984. Microeconomics, Norms, and Rationality. Economic Development and Cultural Change 32 (4): 683711.Google Scholar
Finnemore, Martha. 1993. International Organizations as Teachers of Norms: The United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization and Science Policy. International Organization 47 (4): 565597.Google Scholar
Finnemore, Martha. 1996a. Norms, Culture, and World Politics: Insights from Sociology’s Institutionalism. International Organization 50 (2): 325347.Google Scholar
Finnemore, Martha. 1996b. National Interests in International Society. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Finnemore, Martha. 1999. Rules of War and Wars of Rules: The International Red Cross and the Restraint of State Violence. In Boli and Thomas 1999, 149–165.Google Scholar
Finnemore, Martha, and Sikkink, Kathryn. 2001. Taking Stock: The Constructivist Research Program in International Relations and Comparative Politics. Annual Review of Political Science 4: 391416.Google Scholar
Fioretos, Orfeo. 2011. Historical Institutionalism in International Relations. International Organization 65 (2): 367399.Google Scholar
Fioretos, Orfeo. 2016. Retrofitting Financial Globalization: The Politics of Intense Incrementalism after 2008. In Rixen, Viola, and Zürn 2016, 68–95.Google Scholar
Fioretos, Orfeo, ed. 2017. International Politics and Institutions in Time. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fioretos, Orfeo, Falleti, Tulia G., and Sheingate, Adam, eds. 2016a. Oxford Handbook of Historical Institutionalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fioretos, Orfeo, Falleti, Tulia G., and Sheingate, Adam. 2016b. Historical Institutionalism in Political Science. In Fioretos, Falleti, and Sheingate, 2016a, 3–28. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. 1997. Social Skill and Institutional Theory. American Behavioral Scientist 40 (4): 397405.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. 2001. The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First Century Capitalist Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. 2012. The “Old” New Institutionalism versus the “New” New Institutionalism. orgtheory.net, August 23, 2012, http://orgtheory.wordpress.com/2012/08/23/the-old-new-institutionalism-versus-the-new-new-institutionalism/.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil, and McAdam, Douglas. 2012. A Theory of Fields. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. 1970. The Order of Things: An Archaeology of the Human Sciences. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. 1980. Power/Knowledge: Selected Interviews and Other Writings 1972–1977. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. 1982. The Subject and Power. Critical Inquiry 8: 777795.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. 1995. Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison. Translated by Sheridan, Alan. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. 2008. The Birth of Biopolitics: Lectures at the College de France, 1978–1979. Edited by Senellart, Michel. Translated by Burchell, Graham. New York: Palgrave Macmillan/Picador.Google Scholar
Fox, Robin. 1977. The Inherent Rules of Violence. In Social Rules and Social Behavior, edited by Collett, Peter, 132149. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Frank, David John, Hironaka, Ann, and Schofer, Evan. 2000. The Nation-State and the Natural Environment over the Twentieth Century. American Sociological Review 65: 96116.Google Scholar
Frank, David John, and McEneaney, Elizabeth H.. 1999. The Individualization of Society and the Liberalization of State Policies on Same-Sex Sexual Relations, 1984–1995. Social Forces 77 (3): 911943.Google Scholar
Friedland, Robert, and Alford, Robert R.. 1991. Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions. In Powell and DiMaggio 1991, 232–263.Google Scholar
Friedland, Roger. 2017. The Value of Institutional Logics. In Krücken et al. 2017, 12–50.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis. 2014. Political Order and Political Decay: From the Industrial Revolution to the Globalization of Democracy. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Furnari, Santi. 2014. Interstitial Spaces: Micro-interaction Settings and the Genesis of New Practices between Institutional Fields. Academy of Management Review 39 (4): 439462.Google Scholar
Fürstenberg, Kai. 2016. Evolutionary Institutionalism: New Perspectives. Politics and the Life Sciences 35 (1): 4860.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1973. Power and the Useful Economist. American Economic Review 1: 111.Google Scholar
Gaventa, John. 1980. Power and Powerlessness: Quiescence and Rebellion in an Appalachian Valley. Urbana and Chicago: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Gawer, Annabelle, and Phillips, Nelson. 2013. Institutional Work as Logics Shift: The Case of Intel’s Transformation to Platform Leader. Organization Studies 34: 10351071.Google Scholar
Geertz, Clifford. 1980. Negara: The Theatre-State in Nineteenth-Century Bali. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gelderblom, Oscar. 2013. Cities of Commerce: The Institutional Foundations of International Trade in the Low Countries, 1250–1650. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gerken, Lüder, ed. 1995. Competition among Institutions. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gerschewski, Johannes. 2020. Explanations of Institutional Change: Reflecting on a “Missing Diagonal.” American Political Science Review, https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055420000751.Google Scholar
Giddens, Anthony. 1979. Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure and Contradiction in Social Analysis. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Gilpin, Robert. 1981. War and Change in World Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Andreas. 2014. Hermeneutic Institutionalism: Towards a New Synthesis. Qualitative Sociology 37 (2): 207241.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2004. Do Institutions Cause Growth? Journal of Economic Growth 9: 271303.Google Scholar
Goertz, Gary. 2006. Social Science Concepts: A User’s Guide. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Goffman, Erving. 1959. The Presentation of Self in Everyday Life. New York: Anchor Books/Doubleday.Google Scholar
Goffman, Erving. 1961. Asylums: Essays on the Social Situation of Mental Patients and Other Inmates. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Goffman, Erving. 1967. Interaction Ritual: Essays on Face-to-Face Behavior. New York: Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
Goldberg, Victor P. 1974. Institutional Change and the Quasi-invisible Hand. Journal of Law and Economics 17 (2): 461492.Google Scholar
Goldman, Alvin I. 1972. Toward a Theory of Social Power. Philosophical Studies 23 (4): 221268.Google Scholar
Goldman, Alvin I. 1974. On the Measurement of Power. Journal of Philosophy 71 (8): 231252.Google Scholar
Goldstone, Jack A. 2020. Urbanization, Citizenship, and Economic Growth in the Long Run. International Review of Social History 65 (1): 109124.Google Scholar
Goodin, Robert E. 1996. Institutions and Their Design. In The Theory of Institutional Design, edited by Goodin, Robert E., 153. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gopalakrishnan, Chennat. 2005. Water Allocation and Management in Hawaii: A Case of Institutional Entropy. In Water Institutions: Policies, Performance and Prospects, edited by Gopalakrishnan, Chennat, Biswas, Asit K., and Tortajada, Cecilia, 123. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Gordon, Joy. 2012. Invisible War: The US and the Iraq Sanctions. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gößling, Tobias. 2006. Homo Institutionalis: Institutionen und rationale Entscheidungen - eine Einführung. Bielefeld, Germany: Verlag für Druckgrafik Gieselmann.Google Scholar
Gould, S. J. 1987. Institution. In The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Institutions, edited by Bogdanor, Vernon, 290292. Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd.Google Scholar
Gould, S. J., and Eldredge, N.. 1977. Punctuated Equilibria: The Tempo and Mode of Evolution Reconsidered. Paleobiology 3: 115151.Google Scholar
Gould, S. J., and Lewontin, R. C.. 1979. The Spandrels of San Marco and the Panglossian Paradigm: A critique Of the Adaptationist Programme. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London, Series B, 205: 581598.Google Scholar
Grafstein, Robert. 1988. The Problem of Institutional Constraint. Journal of Politics 50 (3): 577599.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark. 1985. Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology 91 (3): 481510.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark. 1992. Economic Institutions as Social Constructions: A Framework for Analysis. Acta Sociologica 35: 311.Google Scholar
Granqvist, Nina, and Gustafsson, Robin. 2016. Temporal Institutional Work. Academy of Management Journal 59 (3): 10091035.Google Scholar
Green, Edward Jr., and Li, Yuan. 2011. Rhetorical Institutionalism: Language, Agency, and Structure in Institutional Theory since Alvesson 1993. Journal of Management Studies 48 (7): 16621697.Google Scholar
Greenwood, Royston, Oliver, Christine, Lawrence, Thomas B., and Meyer, Renate E., eds. 2017. The Sage Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism, 2nd edition. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Greenwood, Royston, Oliver, Christine, Sahlin, Kerstin, and Suddaby, Roy, eds. 2008a. The Sage Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Greenwood, Royston, Oliver, Christine, Sahlin, Kerstin, and Suddaby, Roy. 2008b. Introduction. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 1–46.Google Scholar
Greenwood, Royston, Díaz, Amalia Magán, Li, Stan Xiao, and José Céspedes, Lorente. 2010. The Multiplicity of Institutional Logics and the Heterogeneity of Organizational Responses. Organization Science 21 (2): 521539.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Kingston, Christopher. 2011. Institutions: Rules or Equilibria? In Political Economy of Institutions, Democracy and Voting, edited by Schofield, Norman and Caballero, Gonzalo, 1343. Heidelberg, Germany: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Laitin, David D.. 2004. A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change. American Political Science Review 98 (4): 633652.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner, Milgrom, Paul, and Weingast, Barry R.. 1994. Coordination, Commitment, and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild. Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 745777.Google Scholar
Grew, Raymond, ed. 1978. Crises of Political Development in Europe and the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Grewal, David Singh. 2008. Network Power: The Social Dynamics of Globalization. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Griffin, Larry J. 1992. Temporality, Events, and Explanation in Historical Sociology. Sociological Methods and Research 20 (4): 403427.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, John, Spithoven, Antoon, and van den Berg, Annette. 2010. Institutional Economics: An Introduction. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Grothe-Hammer, Michael, and Kohl, Sebastian. 2020. The Decline of Organizational Sociology? An Empirical Analysis of Research Trends in Leading Journals across Half a Century. Current Sociology 68 (4): 419442.Google Scholar
Gruber, Lloyd. 2000. Ruling the World: Power Politics and the Rise of Supranational Institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gruchy, Allan G. 1987. The Reconstruction of Economics : An Analysis of the Fundamentals of Institutional Economics. New York: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2010. The Best Laid Plans: The Impact of Informal Rules on Formal Institutions in Transitional Regimes. Studies in Comparative International Development 45 (3): 311333.Google Scholar
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2011. Time Will Tell? Temporality and the Analysis of Causal Mechanisms and Processes. Comparative Political Studies 44 (9): 12671297.Google Scholar
Gustafsson, Bo. 1987. The Rise and Economic Behaviour of Medieval Craft Guilds: An Economic-Theoretical Interpretation. Scandinavian Economic History Review 35 (1): 140.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S. 2005. Policy Drift: The Hidden Politics of US Welfare State Retrenchment. In Streeck and Thelen 2005a, 40–82.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 1989. The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 2010. Historical Institutionalism in Rationalist and Sociological Perspective. In Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency and Power, edited by Mahoney, James and Thelen, Kathleen, 204224. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 2016. Politics as a Process Structured in Space and Time. In Fioretos, Falleti, and Sheingate 2016a, 31–50.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Soskice, David, eds. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Soskice, David. 2003. Varieties of Capitalism and Institutional Change: A Response to Three Critics. Comparative European Politics 1: 241250.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Thelen, Kathleen. 2009. Institutional Change in Varieties of Capitalism. Socio-Economic Review 7: 734.Google Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Taylor, Rosemary C. R.. 1996. Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms. Political Studies 44: 936957.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1968. Institution. In Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, edited by Seligman, Edwin R. A., 8489. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hampel, Christian E., Lawrence, Thomas B., and Tracey, Paul. 2017. Institutional Work: Taking Stock and Making It Matter. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 558–590.Google Scholar
Hanrieder, Tine. 2015a. International Organization in Time: Fragmentation and Reform. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Harari, Yuval Noah. 2015. Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind. New York: Harper and Collins.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1968. The Tragedy of the Commons. Science 162 (3859): 12431248.Google Scholar
Hardy, Cynthia, and Clegg, Stewart. 2006. Some Dare Call It Power. In The Sage Handbook of Organization Studies, edited by Clegg, Stewart, Hardy, Cynthia, Lawrence, Thomas B., and Nord, Walter R., 754775. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Hardy, Cynthia, and Maguire, Steve. 2008. Institutional Entrepreneurship. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 198–217.Google Scholar
Hargrave, Timothy J., and Van de Ven, Andrew H.. 2009. Institutional Work as the Creative Embrace of Contradiction. In Lawrence, Suddaby and Leca 2009a, 120–140.Google Scholar
Hariri, Jacob Gerner. 2012. The Autocratic Legacy of Early Statehood. American Political Science Review 106 (3): 471494.Google Scholar
Harris, Abram L. 1932. Types of Institutionalism. Journal of Political Economy 40 (6): 721749.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 1990. Is “Bounded Rationality” an Important Element of a Theory of Institutions? Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146 (4): 696702.Google Scholar
Harvey, David. 2018. The Limits to Capital. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Hawley, Willis D., and Wirt, Frederick M., eds. 1974. The Search for Community Power, 2nd edition. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Hay, Colin. 2006. Constructivist Institutionalism. In Rhodes, Binder, and Rockman 2006, 56–74.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich. 2011 [1960]. The Constitution of Liberty: The Definitive Edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hechter, Michael. 1990. The Emergence of Cooperative Social Institutions. In Hechter, Opp, and Wippler 1990, 13–33.Google Scholar
Hechter, Michael, and Kanazawa, Satoshi. 1997. Sociological Rational Choice Theory. Annual Review of Sociology 23: 191214.Google Scholar
Hechter, Michael, Opp, Karl-Dieter, and Wippler, Reinhard, eds. 1990. Social Institutions: Their Emergence, Maintenance and Effects. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Heclo, Hugh. 2008. On Thinking Institutionally. London: Paradigm Publishers.Google Scholar
Hegel, G. F. W. 1953. Reason in History. Indianapolis and New York: Bobbs-Merrill Co.Google Scholar
Helmke, Gretchen, and Levitsky, Steven. 2004. Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda. Perspectives on Politics 2 (4): 725740.Google Scholar
Henrich, Joseph. 2020. The WEIRDest People in the World: How the West Became Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Herbst, Jeffrey. 2000. States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Higonnet, Patrice L.-R. 1980. The Politics of Linguistic Terrorism and Grammatical Hegemony during the French Revolution. Social History 5 (1): 4169.Google Scholar
Hindriks, Frank, and Guala, Francesco. 2019. The Functions of Institutions: Etiology and Teleology. Synthèse, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11229–019-02188-8.Google Scholar
Hinings, C. R., and Tolbert, Pamela S.. 2008. Organizational Institutionalism and Sociology: A Reflection. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 473–490.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Paul M. 1997. Sociology without Social Structure: Neoinstitutional Theory Meets Brave New World. American Journal of Sociology 102 (6): 17021723.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Paul M., and Bermiss, Sekou. 2009. Institutional “Dirty” Work: Preserving Institutions through Strategic Decoupling. In Lawrence, Suddaby, and Leca 2009a, 262–283.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Paul M., and Lounsbury, Michael. 1997. Ending the Family Quarrel: Toward a Reconciliation of “Old” and “New” Institutionalism. American Behavioral Scientist 40 (4): 406418.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Paul, and Lounsbury, Michael. 2015. Toward a More Critical and “Powerful” Institutionalism. Journal of Management Inquiry 24 (1): 9699.Google Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas. 1988 [1651]. Leviathan. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1998. The Approach of Institutional Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 166192.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2006. What Are Institutions? Journal of Economic Issues 40 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Holland, Paul W. 1986. Statistics and Causal Inference. Journal of the American Statistical Association 81 (396): 945960.Google Scholar
Hom, Andrew R. 2018. Timing Is Everything: Toward a Better Understanding of Time and International Politics. International Studies Quarterly 62 (1): 6979.Google Scholar
Hom, Andrew R. 2020. International Relations and the Problem of Time. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hughes, Everett C. 1942. The Study of Social Institutions. Social Forces 20 (3): 307310.Google Scholar
Hunter, Floyd. 1953. Community Power Structure: A Study of Decision Makers. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, Leonid. 1945. The Theory of Economic Behavior. American Economic Review 35 (5): 909925.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, G. John. 2001. After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint and the Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Immergut, Ellen M. 1998. The Theoretical Core of the New Institutionalism. Politics and Society 26 (1): 534.Google Scholar
Ingram, Paul, and Clay, Karen. 2000. The Choice-within-Constraints New Institutionalism and Implications for Sociology. Annual Review of Sociology 26: 525546.Google Scholar
Ingram, Paul, Jeffrey, Robinson, and Busch, Marc. 2005. The Intergovernmental Network of World Trade: IGO Connectedness, Governance, and Embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology 11 (3): 824858.Google Scholar
Jackson, Gregory. 2005. Contested Boundaries: Ambiguity and Creativity in the Evolution of German Codetermination. In Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, edited by Streeck, Wolfgang and Thelen, Kathleen, 229254. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Jackson, Robert H. 1990. Quasi-states: Sovereignty, International Relations, and the Third World. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jackson, Robert H., and Rosberg, Carl G.. 1982. Why Africa’s Weak States Persist: The Empirical and the Juridical in Statehood. World Politics 35 (1): 124.Google Scholar
Jepperson, Ronald L. 1991. Institutions, Institutional Effects, and Institutionalism. In Powell and DiMaggio 1991, 143–163.Google Scholar
Jepperson, Ronald L. 2002. The Development and Application of Sociological Neoinstitutionalism. In New Directions in Contemporary Sociology, edited by Berger, Joseph and Zelditch, Morris Jr., 229266. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Jessop, Bob. 1982. The Capitalist State: Marxist Theories and Methods. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, Bryan D. 2016. A Radical Idea Tamed: The Work of Roger Cobb and Charles Elder. In Handbook of Public Agenda-Setting, edited by Zahariadis, Nikolaos, 2534. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Jones, Bryan D., and Baumgartner, Frank R.. 2005. The Politics of Attention. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Jones, Bryan D., and Baumgartner, Frank R.. 2012. From There to Here: Punctuated Equilibrium to the General Punctuation Thesis to a Theory of Government Information Processing. Policy Studies Journal 40 (1): 119.Google Scholar
Jones, Candace, Meyer, Renate E., Jancsary, Dennis, and Höllerer, Marks A.. 2017. The Material and Visual Basis of Institutions. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 621–646.Google Scholar
Jones, Bryan D., Sulkin, Tracy, and Larsen, Heather A.. 2003. Policy Punctuations in American Political Institutions. American Political Science Review 97 (1): 151169.Google Scholar
Jordheim, Helge. 2014. Introduction: Multiple Times and the Work of Synchronization. History and Theory 53 (4): 498518.Google Scholar
Jupille, Joseph. 2004. Procedural Politics: Issues, Influence and Institutional Choice in the European Union. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jupille, Joseph, and Caporaso, James A.. 2009. Domesticating Discourses: European Law, English Judges and Political Institutions. European Political Science Review 1 (2): 205228.Google Scholar
Jupille, Joseph, Mattli, Walter, and Snidal, Duncan. 2013. Institutional Choice and Global Commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kato, Junko. 1996. Institutions and Rationality in Politics: Three Varieties of Neo-institutionalists. British Journal of Political Science 26 (4): 553582.Google Scholar
Katz, Michael L., and Shapiro, Carl. 1985. Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility. American Economic Review 75 (3): 424440.Google Scholar
Katznelson, Ira, and Weingast, Barry R., eds. 2005a. Preferences and Situations: Points of Intersection between Historical and Rational Choice Institutionalism. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Katznelson, Ira, and Weingast, Barry R.. 2005b. Intersections between Historical and Rational Choice Institutionalism. In Preferences and Situations: Points of Intersection between Historical and Rational Choice Institutionalism, edited by Katznelson, Ira and Weingast, Barry R., 124. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Kaysen, Carl. 1946–1947. A Revolution in Economic Theory? Review of Economic Studies 14 (1): 115.Google Scholar
Keating, Barry, and Keating, Maryann. 1975. Institutional Entropy. Public Choice 21: 105106.Google Scholar
Kendi, Ibram X. 2016. Stamped from the Beginning: The Definitive History of Racist Ideas in America. New York: Nation Books.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kiser, Larry L., and Ostrom, Elinor. 1982. The Three Worlds of Action: A Metatheoretical Synthesis of Institutional Approaches. In Strategies of Political Inquiry, edited by Ostrom, Elinor, 179219. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Kittrie, Orde F. 2016. Lawfare: Law as a Weapon of War. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 2000. Suboptimality and Social Institutions: The Relationship between Cognition and Context. In Cognition, Rationality and Institutions, edited by Streit, Manfred E., Mummert, Uwe, and Kiwit, Daniel, 1117. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack, and Sened, Itai, eds. 1995. Explaining Social Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Koelble, Thomas A. 1995. The New Institutionalism in Political Science and Sociology. Comparative Politics 27 (2): 231243.Google Scholar
Koestler, Arthur. 1978 [1964]. The Act of Creation. London: Picador/Pan Books, Ltd.Google Scholar
Komesar, Neil K. 1994. Imperfect Alternatives: Choosing Institutions in Law, Economics and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Koremenos, Barbara. 2016. The Continent of International Law: Explaining Agreement Design. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Koremenos, Barbara, Lipson, Charles, and Snidal, Duncan. 2004. The Rational Design of International Institutions. In The Rational Design of International Institutions, edited by Koremenos, Barbara, Lipson, Charles, and Snidal, Duncan, 139. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Koselleck, Reinhart. 2018. Sediments of Time: On Possible Histories. Translated by Franzel, Sean and Hoffmann, Stefan-Ludwig. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Kraatz, Matthew S. 2020. Boundaries, Bridges and Brands: A Comment on Alvesson, Hallett and Spicer’s “Uninhibited Institutionalisms.” Journal of Management Inquiry 29 (3): 254261.Google Scholar
Kraatz, Matthew S., and Block, Emily S. 2008. Organizational Implications of Institutional Pluralism. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 243–275.Google Scholar
Kraatz, Matthew S., and Block, Emily S. 2017. Institutional Pluralism Revisited. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 532–557.Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1978. Defending the National Interest: Raw Materials Investments and US Foreign Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1982. Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables. International Organization 36 (2): 185205.Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1984. Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics. Comparative Politics 16 (2): 223246.Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1985. Structural Conflict: The Third World against Global Liberalism. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1991. Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier. World Politics 43: 336366.Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1999. Sovereignty: Organized Hypocrisy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Krauthammer, Charles. 1990/1991. The Unipolar Moment. Foreign Affairs 70 (1): 2333.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith, Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. Why Are Congressional Committees Powerful? American Political Science Review 81 (3): 929945.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M. 1990a. Corporate Culture and Economic Theory. In Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, edited by Alt, James E. and Shepsle, Kenneth A., 90143. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M. 1990b. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kreps, David M., and Wilson, Robert. 1982. Sequential Equilibria. Econometrica 50 (4): 863894.Google Scholar
Krücken, Georg, and Drori, Gili S., eds. 2009. World Society: The Writings of John W. Meyer. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Krücken, Georg, Mazza, Carmelo, Meyer, Renate E., and Walgenbach, Peter, eds. 2017. New Themes in Institutional Analysis: Topics and Issues from European Research. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Kula, Witold. 1986. Measures and Men. Translated by Szreter, R.. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2004. Why the Middle East is Economically Underdeveloped: Historical Mechanisms of Institutional Stagnation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (3): 7190.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2018. Islam and Economic Performance: Historical and Contemporary Links. Journal of Economic Literature 56 (4): 12921359.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2020. Zakat: Islam’s Missed Opportunity to Limit Predatory Taxation. Public Choice 182: 395416.Google Scholar
Kydland, Finn E., and Prescott, Edward C.. 1977. Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans. Journal of Political Economy 85 (3): 473491.Google Scholar
Lakatos, Imre. 1970. Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes. In Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, edited by Lakatos, Imre and Musgrave, Alan, 91196. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lake, David. 1999. Entangling Relations: American Foreign Policy in Its Century. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Langlois, Richard N. 1986. The New Institutional Economics: An Introductory Essay. In Economics as a Process: Essays in the New Institutional Economics, edited by Langlois, Richard N., 125. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lawrence, Thomas B. 2008. Power, Institutions and Organizations. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 170–197.Google Scholar
Lawrence, Thomas B., and Buchanan, Sean. 2017. Power, Institutions and Organizations. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 477–506.Google Scholar
Lawrence, Thomas B., Suddaby, Roy, and Leca, Bernard, eds. 2009a. Institutional Work: Actors and Agency in Institutional Studies of Organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lawrence, Thomas B., Suddaby, Roy, and Leca, Bernard. 2009b. Introduction: Theorizing and Studying Institutional Work. In Lawrence, Suddaby, and Leca 2009a, 1–28.Google Scholar
Lawson, Kay. 1985. The Human Polity: An Introduction to Political Science. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lévi-Strauss, Claude. 1962. The Savage Mind. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, Michael. 2014. Flash Boys: A Wall Street Revolt. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Li, Xue, and Hicks, Alexander. 2016. World Polity Matters: Another Look at the Rise of the Nation-State across the World, 1816 to 2001. American Sociological Review 81 (3): 596607.Google Scholar
Lieberman, Evan S. 2001. Causal Inference in Historical Institutional Analysis: A Specification of Periodization Strategies. Comparative Political Studies 34: 10111035.Google Scholar
Lipset, Seymour Martin, and Rokkan, Stein. 1967. Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction. In Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives, edited by Lipset, Seymour Martin and Rokkan, Stein, 162. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Lok, Jaco. 2020. Theorizing the ‘I’ in Institutional Theory: Moving Forward through Theoretical Fragmentation, Not Integration. In The Oxford Handbook of Identities in Organizations, edited by Brown, Andrew D., 732749. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lounsbury, Michael, and Crumley, Ellen. 2007. New Practice Creation: An Institutional Perspective on Innovation. Organization Studies 28 (7): 9931012.Google Scholar
Lowndes, Vivien, and Roberts, Mark. 2013. Why Institutions Matter: The New Institutionalism in Political Science. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lowndes, Vivien. 1996. Varieties of New Institutionalism: A Critical Appraisal. Public Administration 74 (2): 181197.Google Scholar
Lukes, Steven. 2005 [1974]. Power: A Radical View. London, England: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lukes, Steven. 1986. Power. New York : New York University Press.Google Scholar
Mackay, Fiona, and Waylen, Georgina. 2009. Feminist Institutionalism. Politics and Gender 5 (2): 237280.Google Scholar
Mackay, Fiona, Kenny, Meryl, and Chappell, Louise. 2010. New Institutionalism through a Gender Lens: Towards a Feminist Institutionalism? International Political Science Review 31 (5): 573588.Google Scholar
Maguire, Steve, Hardy, Cynthia, and Lawrence, Thomas B.. 2004. Institutional Entrepreneurship in Emerging Fields: HIV/Aids Treatment Advocacy in Canada. The Academy of Management Journal 47 (5): 657679.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2000. Path Dependence in Historical Sociology. Theory and Society 29 (4): 507548.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2004. Comparative-Historical Methodology. Annual Review of Sociology 30: 81101.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2010. Colonialism and Postcolonial Development: Spanish America in Comparative Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James, and Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, eds. 2003. Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James, and Schensul, Daniel. 2006. Historical Context and Path Dependence. In The Oxford Handbook of Contextual Political Analysis, edited by Goodin, Robert E. and Tilly, Charles, 454471. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James, and Thelen, Kathleen, eds. 2010a. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency and Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James, and Thelen, Kathleen. 2010b. A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change. In Mahoney and Thelen 2010a, 1–37.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James, and Thelen, Kathleen, eds. 2015. Advances in Comparative-Historical Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mandel, Ernest. 1998. Late Capitalism. London: Verso.Google Scholar
Mann, Michael. 1986. The Sources of Social Power, Volume 1, A History of Power from the Beginning to A.D. 1760. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Manulak, Michael W. 2020. A Bird in the Hand: Temporal Focal Points and Change in International Institutions. Review of International Organizations 15: 127.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Simon, Herbert A.. 1958. Organizations. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1976. Ambiguity and Choice in Organizations. Bergen: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1984. The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life. American Political Science Review 78 (3): 734749.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1989. Rediscovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1996. Institutional Perspectives on Political Institutions. Governance 9 (3): 247264.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 1998. The Institutional Dynamics of International Political Orders. International Organization 52 (4): 943970.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P.. 2006. Elaborating the “New Institutionalism.” In Rhodes, Binder, and Rockman 2006, 3–20.Google Scholar
March, James G., Schulz, Martin, and Zhou, Xueguang. 2000. The Dynamics of Rules: Change in Written Organizational Codes. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Simon, Herbert A.. 1993. Organizations, 2nd edition. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 1992. Interests, Power, and Multilateralism. International Organization 46 (4): 765792.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 1993. Credibility, Costs, and Institutions: Cooperation on Economic Sanctions. World Politics 45: 406432.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 2000. Democratic Commitments: Legislatures and International Cooperation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl, and Engels, Friedrich. 1983 [1848]. The Communist Manifesto. Middlesex: Pelican.Google Scholar
Matthews, Donald R. 1960. U.S. Senators and Their World. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Matthews, R. C. O. 1986. The Economics of Institutions and the Sources of Growth. Economic Journal 96 (384): 903918.Google Scholar
McAdams, Richard H., and Nadler, Janice. 2008. Coordinating in the Shadow of the Law: Two Contextualized Tests of the Focal Point Theory of Legal Compliance. Law and Society Review 42 (4): 865898.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre. 1976. English Open Fields as Behavior towards Risk. Research in Economic History 1: 124170.Google Scholar
McDonald, Terrence J. 1995. Institutionalism and Institutions in the Stream of History. Polity 28, 1 (Fall): 129133.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control. Journal of Economic Theory 12 (3): 472482.Google Scholar
McNeely, Connie L. 1995. Constructing the Nation-State: International Organization and Prescriptive Action. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
McPhee, Peter. 2016. Liberty or Death: the French Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mead, George Herbert. 1934 [2015]. Mind, Self and Society: The Definitive Edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John J. 1994/1995. The False Promise of International Institutions. International Security 19 (3): 549.Google Scholar
Menaldo, Victor. 2012. The Middle East and North Africa’s Resilient Monarchs. Journal of Politics 74 (3): 707722.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1950. Principles of Economics. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1985 [1963/1883]. Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences with Special Reference to Economics. With a new introduction by Lawrence B. White. Edited by Schneider, Louis. Translated by Nock, Francis J.. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert K. 1957. Social Theory and Social Structure, revised edition. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert K. 1968. Social Theory and Social Structure, 1968, enlarged edition. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, Heinz-Dieter, and Rowan, Brian, eds. 2006. The New Institutionalism in Education. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W. 1995. Foreword. In McNeely 1995, ix–xiv.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W. 2000. Globalization: Sources and Effects on Nation States and Societies. International Sociology 15 (2): 233248.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W. 2008. Reflections on Institutional Theories of Organizations. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 790–811.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W. 2010. World Society, Institutional Theories, and the Actor. Annual Review of Sociology 36: 120.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., Boli, John, Thomas, George M., and Ramirez, Francisco O.. 1997a. World Society and the Nation-State. American Journal of Sociology 103 (1): 144181.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., and Hannan, Michael T., eds. 1979. National Development and the World System: Educational, Economic, and Political Change, 1950–1970. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., Frank, David John, Hironaka, Ann, Schofer, Evan, and Tuma, Nancy Brandon. 1997b. The Structuring of a World Environmental Regime, 1870–1990. International Organization 51 (4): 623651.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., Kamens, David, and Benavot, Aaron, with Cha, Yun-Kyung and Wong, Suk-Ying. 1992. School Knowledge for the Masses: World Models and National Primary Curricular Categories in the Twentieth Century. London: Falmer Press.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., Ramirez, Francisco O., and Soysal, Yasemin. 1992. World Expansion of Mass Education, 1870–1980. Sociology of Education 65 (2): 128149.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., and Rowan, Brian. 1977. Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony. American Journal of Sociology 83 (2): 340363.Google Scholar
Micelotta, Evelyn, Lounsbury, Michael, and Greenwood, Royston. 2017. Pathways of Institutional Change: An Integrative Review and Research Agenda. Journal of Management 43 (6): 18851910.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1990. The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs. Economics and Politics 2 (1): 123.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John. 1990. Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity. In Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, edited by Alt, James E. and Shepsle, Kenneth A., 5789. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Miliband, Ralph. 1969. The State in Capitalist Society. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Miliband, Ralph. 1970. The Capitalist State: Reply to Nicos Poulantzas. New Left Review 59 (January–February): 5360.Google Scholar
Miliband, Ralph. 1973. Poulantzas and the Capitalist State. New Left Review 82 (November–December): 8392.Google Scholar
Miller, Gary J. 2000. Rational Choice and Dysfunctional Institutions. Governance 13 (4): 535547.Google Scholar
Miller, Gary J. 2011. Credible Commitment. In International Encyclopedia of Political Science, edited by Badie, Bertrand, Berg-Schlosser, Dirk, and Morlino, Leonardo, 487489. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Mills, C. Wright. 1956. The Power Elite. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1998. Rationalizing Politics: The Emerging Synthesis of International, American, and Comparative Politics. International Organization 52 (4): 759786.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1984. The New Economics of Organization. American Journal of Political Science 28 (4): 739777.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1990. Political Institutions: The Neglected Side of the Story. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6 (Special Issue): 213266.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1991. Politics and the Theory of Organization. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7 (Special Issue): 106129.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1995. The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy. In Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and beyond, expanded edition, edited by Williamson, Oliver E., 116153. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 2005. Power and Political Institutions. Perspectives on Politics 3 (2): 215233.Google Scholar
Monroe, Kristen Renwick, ed. 2005. Perestroika! The Raucous Rebellion in Political Science. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Moon, David S. 2013. “Tissue on the Bones”: Towards the Development of a Post-structuralist Institutionalism. Politics 33 (2): 112123.Google Scholar
Moore, Barrington Jr. 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Morand, David A. 1996. Dominance, Deference, and Egalitarianism in Organizational Interaction: A Sociolinguistic Analysis of Power and Politeness. Organization Science 7 (5): 544556.Google Scholar
Morand, David A. 2000. Language and Power: An Empirical Analysis of Linguistic Strategies Used in Superior–Subordinate Communication. Journal of Organizational Behavior 21: 235248.Google Scholar
Morgan, Glenn, Campbell, John L., Crouch, Colin, Pedersen, Ove Kaj, and Whitley, Richard, eds. 2010a. The Oxford Handbook of Comparative Institutional Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, Glenn, Campbell, John L., Crouch, Colin, Pedersen, Ove Kaj, and Whitley, Richard. 2010b. Introduction. In Morgan et al. 2010a, 1–11.Google Scholar
Morriss, Peter. 2002. Power: A Philosophical Analysis, 2nd edition. Manchester and New York: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Morse, Chandler. 1961. The Functional Imperatives. In The Social Theories of Talcott Parsons: A Critical Examination, edited by Black, Max, 100152. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Munir, Kamal A. 2015. A Loss of Power in Institutional Theory. Journal of Management Inquiry 24 (1): 9092.Google Scholar
Müßig (née Seif), Ulrike. 2008. Constitutional Conflicts in Seventeenth-Century England. Tjdschrift voor Rechtsgeschiedenis 76: 2747.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 1999. Nash Equilibrium and the History of Economic Theory. Journal of Economic Literature 37 (3): 10671082.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 2009a. Fundamental Theory of Institutions: A Lecture in Honor of Leo Hurwicz. Review of Economic Design 13: 5975.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 2009b. Learning from Schelling’s Strategy of Conflict. Journal of Economic Literature 47 (4): 11091125.Google Scholar
Nagel, Ernest. 1955. On the Statement “The Whole Is More than the Sum of Its Parts.” In The Language of Social Research: A Reader in the Methodology of Social Research, edited by Lazarsfeld, Paul F. and Rosenberg, Morris, 519527. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Nagel, Ernest. 1961. The Structure of Science. New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. Jr. 1951. Non-cooperative Games. Annals of Mathematics 54 (2): 289295.Google Scholar
Neale, Walter C. 1987. Institutions. Journal of Economic Issues 21 (3): 11771206.Google Scholar
Nedzhvetskaya, Nataliya, and Fligstein, Neil. 2020. The Evolving Role of Organizational Theory within Economic Sociology. Sociology Compass 14 (3): 112.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor. 1998. Sources of the New Institutionalism. In Brinton and Nee 1998, 1–16.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor. 2005. The New Institutionalisms in Economics and Sociology. In The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 2nd edition, edited by Swedberg, Richard and Smelser, Neil J., 4974. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nee, Victor, and Strang, David. 1998. The Emergence and Diffusion of Institutional Forms. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 154 (4): 706715.Google Scholar
Nordlinger, Eric A. 1981. On the Autonomy of the Democratic State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England. Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803832.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Thomas, Robert Paul. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nye, Joseph S. 1974. UNCTAD: Poor Nations’ Pressure Group. In The Anatomy of Influence: Decision Making in International Organization, edited by Cox, Robert W. and Jacobson, Harold K., 334370. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Oberschall, Anthony, and Leifer, Eric M.. 1986. Efficiency and Social Institutions: Uses and Misuses of Economic Reasoning in Sociology. Annual Review of Sociology 12: 233253.Google Scholar
Ocasio, William, and Gai, Shelby L.. 2020. Institutions: Everywhere but Not Everything. Journal of Management Inquiry 29 (3): 262271.Google Scholar
Ocasio, William, Thornton, Patricia H., and Lounsbury, Michael. 2017. Advances to the Institutional Logics Perspective. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 509–531.Google Scholar
Offe, Claus. 2006. Political Institutions and Social Power: Conceptual Explorations. In Rethinking Political Institutions: The Art of the State, edited by Shapiro, Ian, Skowronek, Stephen, and Galvin, Daniel, 931. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2004. Guilds, Efficiency, and Social Capital: Evidence from German Proto-industry. Economic History Review 57 (2): 286333.Google Scholar
Ogilvie, Sheilagh. 2007. ‘Whatever Is, Is Right’? Economic Institutions in Pre-industrial Europe. Economic History Review 60 (4): 649684.Google Scholar
Oleinik, Anton. 2011. Market as Weapon: Domination by Virtue of Constellation of Interests. Forum for Social Economics 40: 157177.Google Scholar
Olsen, Johan P. 2009. Change and Continuity: An Institutional Approach to Institutions of Democratic Governance. European Political Science Review 1 (1): 332.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr.. 1963. Rapid Growth as a Destabilizing Force. Journal of Economic History 23 (4): 529552.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr.. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. Jr. 1993. Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. American Political Science Review 87 (3): 567576.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., and Kähkönen, Satu, eds. 2000. A Not So Dismal Science: A Broader View of Economies and Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Orren, Karen. 1991. Belated Feudalism: Labor, the Law, and Liberal Development in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Orren, Karen and Skowronek, Stephen. 1994. Beyond the Iconography of Order: Notes for a New Institutionalism. In The Dynamics of American Politics, edited by Dodd, L. C. and Jillson, C., 311330. Boulder: Westview.Google Scholar
Orren, Karen, and Skowronek, Stephen. 2004. The Search for American Political Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1986. An Agenda for the Study of Institutions. Public Choice 48 (1): 325.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1995. New Horizons in Institutional Analysis. American Political Science Review 89 (1): 174178.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1998. A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action. American Political Science Review 92 (1): 122.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2005. Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2014. Do Institutions for Collective Action Evolve? Journal of Bioeconomics 16: 330.Google Scholar
Padgett, John F., and Powell, Walter W., eds. 2012a. The Emergence of Organizations and Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Padgett, John F., and Powell, Walter W.. 2012b. The Problem of Emergence. In Padgett and Powell 2012a, 1–32.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott. 1990 [1934]. Prolegomena to a Theory of Social Institutions. American Sociological Review 55 (3): 319333.Google Scholar
Parsons, Talcott, and Shils, Edward A., eds. 1951. Toward a General Theory of Action. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Press.Google Scholar
Pepinsky, Thomas. 2014. The Institutional Turn in Comparative Authoritarianism. British Journal of Political Science 44: 631653.Google Scholar
Pérez-Nordtvedt, Liliana, Tyge Payne, G., Short, Jeremy C., and Kedia, Ben L.. 2008. An Entrainment-Based Model of Temporal Organizational Fit, Misfit, and Performance. Organization Science 19 (5): 785801.Google Scholar
Perkins, Al. 1970. The Nose Book. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Perovic, Sanja. 2012. The Calendar in Revolutionary France: Perceptions of Time in Literature, Culture, Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Perrow, Charles. 1985. Review Essay: Overboard with Myth and Symbols. American Journal of Sociology 91 (1): 151155.Google Scholar
Perrow, Charles. 1986. Economic Theories of Organization. Theory and Society 15 (1/2): 1145.Google Scholar
Peters, B. Guy. 2011. Institutional Theory in Political Science: The New Institutionalism, 3rd edition. London: Continuum.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions and Social Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2006. Public Policies as Institutions. In Rethinking Political Institutions: the Art of the State, edited by Shapiro, Ian, Skowronek, Stephen, and Galvin, Daniel, 114131. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2015. Power and Path Dependence. In Mahoney and Thelen 2015a, 123–146.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2016. Power in Historical Institutionalism. In The Oxford Handbook of Historical Institutionalism, edited by Fioretos, Orfeo, Falleti, Tulia G., and Sheingate, Adam, 124141. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul, and Skocpol, Theda. 2002. Historical Institutionalism in Contemporary Political Science. In Political Science: The State of the Discipline, edited by Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V., 693721. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Pinch, Trevor. 2008. Technology and Institutions: Living in a Material World. Theory and Society 37: 461483.Google Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. 1989 [1971]. Politics, Language and Time: Essays on Political Thought and History. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Polsby, Nelson W. 1963. Community Power and Political Theory. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Poulantzas, Nicos. 1969. The Problem of the Capitalist State. New Left Review 58 (November–December): 6778.Google Scholar
Poulantzas, Nicos. 1976. The Capitalist State: A Reply to Miliband and Laclau. New Left Review 95 (January–February): 6383.Google Scholar
Poulantzas, Nicos. 1978. State, Power, Socialism. London: New Left Books.Google Scholar
Poulsen, Lauge N. Skovgaard. 2015. Bounded Rationality and Economic Diplomacy: The Politics of Investment Treaties in Developing Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Powell, Walter W., and Colyvas, Jeanette. 2008. Microfoundations of Institutional Theory. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 276–298.Google Scholar
Powell, Walter W., and DiMaggio, Paul J., eds. 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Powell, Walter W., and Oberg, Achim. 2017. Networks and Institutions. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 446–476.Google Scholar
Powell, Walter W., Packalen, Kelley, and Wittington, Kjersten. 2012. Organizational and Institutional Genesis: The Emergence of High-Tech Clusters in the Life Sciences. In Padgett and Powell 2012a, 434–465.Google Scholar
Price, Richard. 1995. A Genealogy of the Chemical Weapons Taboo. International Organization 49 (1): 73103.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2004a. Institutions Matter? Government and Opposition 39 (4): 527540.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2004b. The Last Instance: Are Institutions the Primary Cause of Economic Development? (I). Archives Européennes de Sociologie 45 (2): 165188.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2004c. Economic History and Political Science. The Political Economist 12 (2): 111.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2015. Endogenous Change of Institutions. In Routledge Handbook of Comparative Political Institutions, edited by Gandhi, Jennifer and Ruiz-Rufino, Rubén, 4355. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Radcliffe-Brown, A. R. 1940. On Social Structure. Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland 70 (1): 112.Google Scholar
Radnitzky, Gerard, and Bernholz, Peter. 1987. Economic Imperialism: The Economic Method Applied outside the Field of Economics. New York: Paragon House Publishers.Google Scholar
Ramirez, Francisco O., and Weiss, Jane. 1979. The Political Incorporation of Women. In Meyer and Hannan 1979, 238–249.Google Scholar
Ramirez, Francisco O., Soysal, Yasemin, and Shanahan, Suzanne. 1997. The Changing Logic of Political Citizenship: Cross-national Acquisition of Women’s Suffrage Rights, 1890 to 1990. American Sociological Review 62 (5): 735745.Google Scholar
Raustiala, Kal, and Victor, David G.. 2004. The Regime Complex for Plant Genetic Resources. International Organization 58 (2): 277309.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1955. Two Concepts of Rules. Philosophical Review 64 (1): 332.Google Scholar
Reay, Trish, and Hinings, C. R. (Bob). 2009. Managing the Rivalry of Competing Institutional Logics. Organization Studies 30 (6): 629652.Google Scholar
Reay, Trish, Zilber, Tammar B., Langley, Ann, and Tsoukas, Haridimos. 2019. Introduction: Institutions and Organizations. In Institutions and Organizations: A Process View, edited by Reay, Trish, Zilber, Tammar B., Langley, Ann, and Tsoukas, Haridimos, 111. Oxford Scholarship Online. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Reeves, Richard V. 2017. Dream Hoarders: How the American Upper Middle Class Is Leaving Everyone Else in the Dust, Why That Is a Problem, and What to Do about It. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Reichenbach, Hans. 1958. The Philosophy of Space and Time. New York: Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Rhodes, R. A. W., Binder, Sarah A., and Rockman, Bert A., eds. 2006. The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rifkin, Mark. 2017. Beyond Settler Time: Temporal Sovereignty and Indigenous Self-determination. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. 1980. Implications from the Disequilibrium of Majority Rule for the Study of Institutions. American Political Science Review 74 (2): 432446.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. 1983. Political Theory and the Art of Heresthetics. In Political Science: The State of the Discipline, edited by Finifter, Ada W., 4767. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. 1984. The Heresthetics of Constitution-Making: The Presidency in 1787, with Comments on Determinism and Rational Choice. American Political Science Review 78 (1): 116.Google Scholar
Rixen, Thomas, and Viola, Lora A.. 2014. Putting Path Dependence in Its Place: Toward a Taxonomy of Institutional Change. Journal of Theoretical Politics 26 (3): 123.Google Scholar
Rixen, Thomas, Viola, Lora Anne, and Zürn, Michael, eds. 2016. Historical Institutionalism and International Relations: Explaining Institutional Development in World Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1952. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, 2nd edition. London: Macmillan and Company.Google Scholar
Roberts, Peter W. 2008. Charting Progress at the Nexus of Institutional Theory and Economics. In Greenwood et al. 2008a, 560–572.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Roland, Gérard. 2004. Understanding Institutional Change: Fast-Moving and Slow-Moving Institutions. Studies in Comparative International Development 38 (4): 109131.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1978. Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo. Public Choice 33 (4): 2743.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1979. Bureaucrats versus Voters: On the Political Economy of Resource Allocation by Direct Democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 93 (4): 563587.Google Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1989. Tying the King’s Hands: Credible Commitments and Royal Fiscal Policy during the Old Regime. Rationality and Society 1 (2): 240258.Google Scholar
Rothstein, Robert L. 1979. Global Bargaining: UNCTAD and the Quest for a New International Economic Order. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rothstein, Robert L. 1984. Regime-Creation by a Coalition of the Weak: Lessons from the NIEO and the Integrated Program for Commodities. International Studies Quarterly 28 (3): 307328.Google Scholar
Rovelli, Carlo. 2018. The Order of Time. New York: Riverhead Books.Google Scholar
Rowe, Nicholas. 1989. Rules and Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Rowlinson, Michael, and Hassard, John S.. 2014. Historical Neo-institutionalism or Neo-institutionalist History? Historical Research in Management and Organization Studies. Management and Organizational History 8 (2): 111126.Google Scholar
Rudolph, Lloyd I., and Rudolph, Susanne H.. 1967. The Modernity of Tradition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1982. International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order. International Organization 36 (2): 379415.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1994. Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ruttan, Vernon W., and Hayami, Yujiro. 1984. Toward a Theory of Induced Institutional Innovation. Journal of Development Studies 20 (4): 203223.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J., ed. 1979. The Economy as a System of Power: Papers from the Journal of Economic Issues. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Larry. 2016. Game Theory in Economics and Beyond. Journal of Economic Perspectives 30 (4): 107130.Google Scholar
Sanders, Elizabeth. 2006. Historical Institutionalism. In Rhodes, Binder, and Rockman 2006, 39–55.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E. 1960. The Semisovereign People: A Realist’s View of Democracy in America. New York: Holt, Rhinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1978. Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: W. W. Norton and Co.Google Scholar
Schickler, Eric. 2001. Disjointed Pluralism: Institutional Innovation and the Development of the U.S. Congress. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schmidt, Vivien A. 2008. Discursive Institutionalism: The Explanatory Power of Ideas and Discourse. Annual Review of Political Science 11: 303326.Google Scholar
Schneiberg, Marc, and Clemens, Elisabeth S.. 2006. The Typical Tools for the Job: Research Strategies in Institutional Analysis. Sociological Theory 24 (3): 195227.Google Scholar
Schofer, Evan, Hironaka, Ann, Frank, David John, and Longhofer, Wesley. 2012. Sociological Institutionalism and World Society. In Wiley Blackwell Companion to Political Sociology, edited by Amenta, Edwin, Nash, Kate, and Scott, Alan, 5769. London: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Schotter, Andrew. 1981. The Economic Theory of Social Institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schotter, Andrew. 1986. The Evolution of Rules. In Economics as a Process: Essays in the New Institutional Economics, edited by Schotter, Andrew, 117133. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schwartz, Barry. 1977. Waiting, Exchange, and Power: The Distribution of Time in Social Systems. American Journal of Sociology 79 (4): 841870.Google Scholar
Scott, James C. 1985. Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 2001. Institutions and Organizations, 2nd edition. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 2014. Institutions and Organizations: Ideas, Interests and Identities, 4th edition. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Searle, John R. 2009. Making the Social World: the Structure of Human Civilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Selten, Reinhard. 1975. Reexamination of the Perfectness Concept for Equilibrium Points in Extensive Games. International Journal of Game Theory 4 (1): 2555.Google Scholar
Selznick, Phillip. 1996. Institutionalism “Old” and “New.” Administrative Science Quarterly 41 (2): 270277.Google Scholar
Seo, Myeong-Gu, and Douglas Creed, W. E.. 2002. Institutional Contradictions, Praxis, and Institutional Change: A Dialectical Perspective. The Academy of Management Review 27 (2): 222247.Google Scholar
Setterfield, Mark. 1993. A Model of Institutional Hysteresis. Journal of Economic Issues 27 (3): 755774.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. 1992. A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency and Transformation. American Journal of Sociology 98 (1): 129.Google Scholar
Sewell, William H. Jr. 1996. Three Temporalities: Toward an Eventful Sociology. In The Historic Turn in the Human Sciences, edited by McDonald, Terrence J., 245280. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Sheingate, Adam. 2010. Rethinking Rules: Creativity and Constraint in the US House of Representatives. In Mahoney and Thelen 2010a, 168–203.Google Scholar
Sheingate, Adam. 2014. Institutional Dynamics and American Political Development. Annual Review of Political Science 17: 461477.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models. American Journal of Political Science 23 (1): 2759.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1986. Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions. In Political Science: The Science of Politics, edited by Weisberg, Herbert F., 5181. New York: Agathon Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1989. Studying Institutions: Some Lessons from the Rational Choice Approach. Journal of Theoretical Politics 1 (2): 131147.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1991. Discretion, Institutions, and the Problem of Government Commitment. In Social Theory for a Changing Society, edited by Bourdieu, Pierre and Coleman, James S., 245263. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 2006. Old Questions and New Answers about Institutions: The Riker Objection Revisited. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, edited by Weingast, Barry R. and Wittman, Donald, 10311049. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 2014. The Rules of the Game: What Rules? Which Game? In Institutions, Property Rights, and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North, edited by Galiani, Sebastian and Sened, Itai, 6683. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power. American Political Science Review 81 (1): 85104.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1994. Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions. Legislative Studies Quarterly 19 (2): 149179.Google Scholar
Shubik, Martin, ed. 1964. Game Theory and Related Approaches to Social Behavior: Selections. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Shubik, Martin. 1975. The General Equilibrium Model Is Incomplete and Not Adequate for the Reconciliation of Micro and Macroeconomic Theory. Kyklos 28 (3): 545573.Google Scholar
Shvetsova, Olga. 2003. Endogenous Selection of Institutions and Their Exogenous Effects. Constitutional Political Economy 14: 191212.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1947. Administrative Behavior. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1957a. Administrative Behavior, 2nd edition. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1957b. Models of Man: Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting. New York: John Wiley and Songs.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1962. The Architecture of Complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 106 (6): 467482.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1982 [1958]. The Role of Expectations in an Adaptive or Behavioristic Model. In Models of Bounded Rationality, Volume 2, Behavioral Economics and Business Organization, edited by Simon, Herbert A., 380399. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1982. The Sciences of the Artificial, 2nd edition. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 2002. Near Decomposability and the Speed of Evolution. Industrial and Corporate Change 11 (3): 587599.Google Scholar
Sjöstrand, Sven-Erik. 1992. On the Rationale behind “Irrational” Institutions. Journal of Economic Issues 26 (2): 10071040.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1979. States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1995. Why I Am an Historical Institutionalist. Polity 28 (1): 103106.Google Scholar
Skowronek, Stephen. 1982. Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Administrative Capacities, 1877–1920. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Slater, Dan. 2010. Altering Authoritarianism: Institutional Complexity and Autocratic Agency in Indonesia. In Mahoney and Thelen 2010a, 132–167.Google Scholar
Slater, Dan, and Simmons, Erica. 2010. Informative Regress: Critical Antecedents in Comparative Politics. Comparative Political Studies 43 (7): 886917.Google Scholar
Snidal, Duncan. 1995. The Politics of Scope: Endogenous Actors, Heterogeneity, and Institutions. In Local Commons and Global Interdependence: Heterogeneity and Cooperation in Two Domains, edited by Keohane, Robert O. and Ostrom, Elinor, 4770. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Soifer, Hillel David. 2012. The Causal Logic of Critical Junctures. Comparative Political Studies 45 (12): 15721597.Google Scholar
Soifer, Hillel David. 2016. The Development of State Capacity. In Fioretos, Falleti, and Sheingate 2016a, 181–194.Google Scholar
Sokoloff, Kenneth L., and Engerman, Stanley L.. 2000. Institutions, Factor Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 217232.Google Scholar
Solingen, Etel, and Wan, Wilfred. 2016. Critical Junctures, Developmental Pathways, and Incremental Change in Security Institutions. In Fioretos, Falleti, and Sheingate 2016a, 553–571.Google Scholar
Sorokin, Pitirim A. 1943. Sociocultural Causality, Space, Time: A Study of the Referential Principles of Sociology and Social Science. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Spruyt, Hendrik. 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors: An Analysis of Systems Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Stacey, Jeffrey, and Rittberger, Berthold. 2003. Dynamics of Formal and Informal Institutional Change in the EU. Journal of European Public Policy 10 (6): 858883.Google Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2003. Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic State: France and Great Britain 1688–1789. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2014. Was Weber Right? The Role of Urban Autonomy in Europe’s Rise. American Political Science Review 108 (2): 337354.Google Scholar
Stasavage, David. 2020. The Decline and Rise of Democracy: A Global History from Antiquity to Today. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Steele, Christopher W. J., Toubiana, Madeline, and Greenwood, Royston. 2020. Why Worry? Celebrating and Reformulating “Integrative Institutionalism.” Research in the Sociology of Organizations 65b (Microfoundations of Institutions): 353369.Google Scholar
Stefes, Christoph H. 2019. Historical Institutionalism and Societal Transformations. In The Handbook of Political, Social, and Economic Transformation, edited by Merkel, Wolfgang, Kollmorgen, Raj, and Wagener, Hans-Jürgen, 95105. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Steinmo, Sven. 2008. Historical Institutionalism. In Approaches and Methodologies in the Social Sciences: A Pluralist Perspective, edited by Porta, Donatella Della and Keating, Michael, 118138. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen, and Longstreth, Frank, eds. 1992. Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur. 1965. Social Structure and Organizations. In Handbook of Organizations, edited by March, James G., 142193. Chicago: Rand McNally.Google Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur. 1968. Constructing Social Theories. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur. 1997. On the Virtues of the Old Institutionalism. Annual Review of Sociology 23: 118.Google Scholar
Stolper, Wolfgang, and Samuelson, Paul. 1941. Protection and Real Wages. Review of Economic Studies 9 (1): 127.Google Scholar
Stone, Clarence. 1989. Regime Politics: Governing Atlanta, 1946–1988. Lawrence: University of Kansas Press.Google Scholar
Stone, Randall W. 2011. Controlling Institutions: International Organizations and the Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Strang, David, and Chang, Patricia Mei Yin. 1993. The International Labor Organization and the Welfare State: Institutional Effects on National Welfare Spending, 1960–1980. International Organization 47 (2): 235262.Google Scholar
Strang, David, and Meyer, John W.. 1993. Institutional Conditions for Diffusion. Theory and Society 22 (4): 487511.Google Scholar
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Thelen, Kathleen, eds. 2005a. Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Thelen, Kathleen. 2005b. Introduction: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. In Streeck and Thelen 2005a, 1–39.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1989. Spontaneous Order. Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (4): 8597.Google Scholar
Sussman, Nathan, and Yafeh, Yishay. 2006. Institutional Reforms, Financial Development and Sovereign Debt: Britain 1690–1790. Journal of Economic History 66 (4): 906935.Google Scholar
Sutcliffe, Robert. 1971. Industry and Underdevelopment. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Swedberg, Richard. 2006. The Tool Kit of Economic Sociology. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, edited by Weingast, Barry R. and Wittman, Donald, 937950. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Tannenwald, Nina. 1999. The Nuclear Taboo: The United States and the Normative Basis of Nuclear Non-use. International Organization 53 (3): 433468.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics. Annual Review of Political Science 2: 369404.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2003. How Institutions Evolve: Insights from Comparative Historical Analysis. In Mahoney and Rueschemeyer 2003, 208–240.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 2009. Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. British Journal of Industrial Relations 47 (3): 471498.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen, and Mahoney, James. 2015. Comparative-Historical Analysis in Contemporary Political Science. In Mahoney and Thelen 2015, 3–36.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen, and Steinmo, Sven. 1992. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics. In Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, edited by Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen, and Longstreth, Frank, 132. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Thomas, George, John, W. Meyer, Francisco O. Ramirez, and Boli, John, eds. 1987. Institutional Structure: Constituting State, Society and the Individual. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Thompson, John B. 1991. Editor’s Introduction. In Bourdieu 1991, 1–34.Google Scholar
Thomson, Janice E. 1994. Mercenaries, Pirates, and Sovereigns: State-Building and Extraterritorial Violence in Early Modern Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Thornborrow, Joanna. 2013. Power Talk: Language and Interaction in Institutional Discourse. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Thornton, Patricia H. 2002. The Rise of the Corporation in a Craft Industry: Conflict and Conformity in Institutional Logics. Academy of Management Journal 45 (1): 81101.Google Scholar
Thornton, Patricia H. 2004. Markets from Culture: Institutional Logics and Organizational Decisions in Higher-Education Publishing. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Thornton, Patricia H., Ocasio, William, and Lounsbury, Michael. 2012. The Institutional Logics Perspective: A New Approach to Culture, Structure and Process. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1975. Reflections on the History of European State-Making. In The Formation of National States in Western Europe, edited by Tilly, Charles, 383. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tolbert, Pamela S., and Zucker, Lynn G.. 1996. The Institutionalization of Institutional Theory. In Handbook of Organizational Studies, edited by Clegg, S. R., Hardy, C., and Nord, W. R., 175190. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Trank, Christine Quinn, and Washington, Marvin. 2009. Maintaining an Institution in a Contested Organizational Field: The Work of the AACSB and Its Constituents. In Thomas, Suddaby and Leca 2009a, 236–261.Google Scholar
Trimberger, Ellen Kay. 1978. Revolution from Above: Military Bureaucrats and Development in Japan, Turkey, Egypt, and Peru. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books.Google Scholar
Tsai, Kellee S. 2006. Adaptive Informal Institutions and Endogenous Institutional Change in China. World Politics 59 (1): 116141.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 1990. Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Tucker, Robert C., ed. 1978. The Marx-Engels Reader, 2nd edition. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Turk, Austin T. 1976. Law as a Weapon in Social Conflict. Social Problems 23 (3): 276291.Google Scholar
Ullman-Margalit, Edna. 1978. Invisible Hand Explanations. Synthèse 39: 263291.Google Scholar
Van der Lecq, Fieke. 1996. Conventions and Institutions in Coordination Problems. De Economist 144 (3): 397428.Google Scholar
Van der Voet, Joris. 2014. Three Times around Institutional Theory: The Coherence, Connection and Contribution of Three Recent Books. Organization 21 (1): 126132.Google Scholar
VandeZande, Daniel L. 2010. Coercive Power and the Demise of the Star Chamber. American Journal of Legal History 50 (3): 326349.Google Scholar
Vican, Shawna, Friedman, Asia, and Andreasen, Robin. 2020. Metrics, Money, and Managerialism: Faculty Experiences of Competing Logics in Higher Education. Journal of Higher Education 91 (1): 139164.Google Scholar
Voigt, Stefan. 2013. How (Not) to Measure Institutions. Journal of Institutional Economics 9 (1): 126.Google Scholar
Voigt, Stefan. 2019. Institutions. In The Handbook of Political, Social, and Economic Transformation, edited by Merkel, Wolfgang, Kollmorgen, Raj, and Wagener, Hans-Jürgen, 3041. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, John, and Morgenstern, Oskar. 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wallander, Celeste A. 2000. Institutional Assets and Adaptability: NATO after the Cold War. International Organization 54 (4): 705735.Google Scholar
Wallis, John H. 1989. Towards a Positive Economic Theory of Institutional Change. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 145 (1): 98112.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth N. 1979. Theory of International Politics. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley.Google Scholar
Warner, Carolyn M., Kilinç, Ramazan, Hale, Christopher W., and Cohen, Adam B.. 2018. Generating Generosity in Catholicism and Islam: Beliefs, Institutions, and Public Goods Provision. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Eugen. 1976. Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural France, 1870–1914. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Katja. 2000. Hierarchy amidst Anarchy: Transaction Costs and Institutional Choice. Albany, NY: SUNY Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Max. 1978 [1922]. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology. Edited by Roth, Guenther and Wittich, Klaus. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Weik, Elke. 2015. A Return to the Enduring Features of Institutions: A Process Ontology of Reproduction and Endurance. Philosophy of the Social Sciences 45 (3): 291314.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1995. The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11 (1): 131.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 2002. Rational-Choice Institutionalism. In Political Science: The State of the Discipline, edited by Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V., 660692. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, William J.. 1988. The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets. Journal of Political Economy 96 (1): 132163.Google Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. 1998. On Constitution and Causation in International Relations. Review of International Studies 24: 101117.Google Scholar
Wendt, Alexander. 1999. Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wendt, Claus, ed. 2017. Max Weber and Institutional Theory. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Westenholz, Ann, Pedersen, Jesper Strandgaard, and Dobbin, Frank. 2006. Introduction: Institutions in the Making: Identity, Power, and the Emergence of New Organizational Forms. American Behavioral Scientist 49 (7): 889896.Google Scholar
Weyland, Kurt. 2008. Toward a New Theory of Institutional Change. World Politics 60 (2): 281314.Google Scholar
Whitehead, Alfred North. 1911. An Introduction to Mathematics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wildavsky, Aaron. 1987. Choosing Preferences by Constructing Institutions: A Cultural Theory of Preference Formation. American Political Science Review 81 (1): 321.Google Scholar
Wilfahrt, Martha. 2021. Precolonial Legacies in Postcolonial Politics: Representation and Redistribution in Decentralized West Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wilkerson, Isabel. 2020. Caste: The Origins of Our Discontents. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1980. The Organization of Work: A Comparative Institutional Assessment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1: 538.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1981. The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach. American Journal of Sociology 87 (3): 548577.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1983. Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange. American Economic Review 73 (4): 519540.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1984. The Economics of Governance: Framework and Implications. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140 (1): 195223.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1988. The Logic of Economic Organization. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4 (1): 6593.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1991. Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly 36 (2): 269296.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1993. Contested Exchange versus the Governance of Contractual Relations. Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (1): 103108.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Willmott, Hugh. 2011. “Institutional Work” for What? Problems and Prospects of Institutional Theory. Journal of Management Inquiry 20 (1): 6772.Google Scholar
Wimmer, Andreas, and Feinstein, Yuval. 2010. The Rise of the Nation-State across the World, 1816 to 2001. American Sociological Review 75 (5): 764790.Google Scholar
Wimmer, Andreas, and Feinstein, Yuval. 2016. Still No Robust Evidence for World Polity Theory. American Sociological Review 81 (3): 608615.Google Scholar
Woolley, John T. 2000. Using Media-Based Data in Studies of Politics. American Journal of Political Science 44 (1): 156173.Google Scholar
Wooten, Melissa, and Hoffman, Andrew J.. 2017. Organizational Fields: Past, Present and Future. In Greenwood et al. 2017, 55–74.Google Scholar
Wrong, Dennis H. 1988 [1979]. Power: Its Forms, Bases, and Uses. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Yarbrough, Beth V., and Yarbrough, Robert M.. 1992. Cooperation and Governance in International Trade: The Strategic Organizational Approach. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ylikoski, Petri. 2013. Causal and Constitutive Explanation Compared. Erkenntnis 78, supplement 2: 277297.Google Scholar
Zahle, Julie. 2019. Limits to Levels in the Methodological Individualism–Holism Debate. Synthèse, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11229–019-02469-2.Google Scholar
Zelikow, Philip. 1996. The Masque of International Institutions. Survival 38 (1): 618.Google Scholar
Zerubavel, Eviatar. 1977. The French Republican Calendar: A Case Study in the Sociology of Time. American Sociological Review 42 (6): 868877.Google Scholar
Zerubavel, Eviatar. 1982. The Standardization of Time: A Socio-Historical Perspective. American Journal of Sociology 88 (1): 123.Google Scholar
Zerubavel, Eviatar. 1989. The Seven Day Circle: The History and Meaning of the Week, reprint edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Zerubavel, Eviatar. 2018. Taken for Granted: The Remarkable Power of the Unremarkable. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Zietsma, Charlene, and McKnight, Brent. 2009. Building the Iron Cage: Institutional Creation Work in the Context of Competing Proto-institutions. In Lawrence et al. 2009a, 143–177.Google Scholar
Zietsma, Charlene, and Lawrence, Thomas B.. 2010. Institutional Work in the Transformation of an Organizational Field: The Interplay of Boundary Work and Practice Work. Administrative Science Quarterly 55 (2): 189221.Google Scholar
Zijderveld, Anton C. 2000. The Institutional Imperative: The Interface of Institutions and Networks. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.Google Scholar
Zilber, Tammar B. 2009. Institutional Maintenance as Narrative Acts. In Lawrence et al. 2009a, 205–235.Google Scholar
Zilber, Tammar B. 2013. Institutional Logics and Institutional Work: Should They Be Agreed? Research in the Sociology of Organizations 39A: 7796.Google Scholar
Zucker, Lynne G. 1977. The Role of Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence. American Sociological Review 42 (5): 726743.Google Scholar
Zucker, Lynne G., ed. 1988. Institutional Patterns and Organizations: Culture and Environment. New York: Ballinger.Google Scholar
Zürn, Michael. 2016. Historical Institutionalism and International Relations: Strange Bedfellows? In Rixen, Viola, and Zürn 2016, 199–228.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×