Hostname: page-component-76dd75c94c-x59qb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T07:18:41.025Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Social Order and Political Authority

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

John Dickinson*
Affiliation:
Princeton University

Extract

No present political tendency is more marked than the extension of law to cover ever wider fields of conduct. Political scientists and constitutional lawyers have come to recognize that this tendency can be properly assessed only by examining how law operates in contrast and connection with other agencies of order such as custom, ethics, religion, and economic forces. When one wishes to understand the failure of such laws as the Sherman Anti-Trust Act or the Volstead Act to accomplish the results expected of them, or when one wishes to form a judgment of the effects to be anticipated from the operation of a minimumwage law or from the codification of international law, it is important to understand the relation to the other forces which are giving direction to human conduct. There are regularities and patterns of adjustment in human behavior due to other causes than law administered by government; and these regularities not only work at times toward the same, or some of the same, ends which it is sought to attain by law, but at times they form a highly resistant part of the material against which law must work. An effort will be made in this paper to present the problem of law and government as part and parcel of the whole wider problem of social order, beginning with an attempt to understand the nature and operation of what may be called the “non-political” agencies of order. The task is facilitated by the contributions which anthropology has made to our knowledge of primitive peoples, and by the light which psychology has shed on the springs of conduct. We no longer have to rely like Hobbes and Rousseau on a naive theory of human nature or upon a fancy-picture of savage life. The outstanding result of the newer contributions has been to emphasize the central significance of the principle of relativity in the social no less than the physical sciences.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1929

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 In a scientific treatment of social questions it is imperative that there should be a precise conception of law apart from social regulatives generally.” Goitein, H., Primitive Ordeal and Modern Law (London, 1923), p. 20Google Scholar. This caution is often disregarded by anthropologists and by recent jurists, who, in revolt against Austin, treat all forms of social regulation as “law.” See my article, The Law Behind Law,” Columbia Law Review, vol. 29, p. 137, note 81 (Feb., 1929)Google Scholar.

2 Dewey, , Human Nature and Conduct (N. Y., 1922), pp. 1415Google Scholar; Holt, E. B., The Freudian Wish (N. Y., 1915), pp. 5459CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The response is also affected by previous responses in the life of the individual and his ancestors. Gumplowicz, , Outlines of Sociology (Phila., 1899), pp. 159160Google Scholar; Ford, H. J., The Natural History of the State (Princeton, 1915), pp. 7780Google Scholar, and passim.

3 Dewey, , The Public and its Problems (N. Y., 1927), pp. 185193Google Scholar.

4 For attempts at scientific definitions see Dewey, , Human Nature and Conduct, pp. 164ff.Google Scholar; Small, Albion W., General Sociology (Chicago, 1905), pp. 426442Google Scholar.

5 E.g. Ratzenhofer's catalogue, Wesen und Zweck der Politik (Leipzig, 1893)Google Scholar, in Small, op. cit., p. 252.

6 McDougall, , Introduction to Social Psychology (Boston, 1918)Google Scholar, passim; Dewey, , Human Nature and Conduct, pp. 131169Google Scholar; Bernard, L. L., Instinct; A Study in Social Psychology (N. Y., 1924)Google Scholar.

7 Hobhouse, , Morals in Evolution (N. Y., 1921), p. 28Google Scholar.

8 A narrow form of economic determinism is represented by Carver's contention that all forms of interest-conflict spring from “economic scarcity.” Carver, T. N., Essays in Social Justice (Cambridge, 1915), p. 49CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 Ratzenhofer, op. cit., sec. 17; Small, op. cit., pp. 201–206;Cooley, C. H., Social Organization (N. Y., 1912), pp. 199 ff.Google Scholar

10 Carver, op. cit., pp. 89–90.

11 Willoughby, W. W., The Nature of the State (N. Y., 1896), pp. 30 ff.Google Scholar

12 Dewey, , Human Nature and Conduct, pp. 58, 63Google Scholar.

13 The doctrine of the historical jurists that custom has its roots in belief or conviction (my article, supra, note 1, p. 130, note 61) represents an antiquated psychology.

14 Hobhouse, op. cit., p. 12; Dewey, , Human Nature and Conduct, pp. 63, 75Google Scholar.

15 MacGahan, , Campaigning in the Oxus, p. 51Google Scholar, quoted in Ross, E. A., Social Psychology (N. Y., 1908), pp. 200201Google Scholar.

16 Malinowski, B., Argonauts of the Western Pacific, p. 159Google Scholar; Marett, R. R., Anthropology, pp. 183184Google Scholar.

17 Sumner, , Folkways (Boston, 1906), pp. 4, 28Google Scholar.

18 Lowie, , Primitive Society (N. Y., 1920), pp. 211213Google Scholar. See Speck, F. G., Publications of the American Sociological Society, vol. xii, 82 ff.Google Scholar

19 Howitt, A. W., Native Tribes of Southeast Australia (London, 1904), pp. 756–9Google Scholar. The location of individual huts in a camp was also prescribed by custom, as well as the sleeping-place of each individual inside the hut. Ibid., pp. 773–6.

20 Rivers, W. H. R., Social Organization (N. Y., 1924), pp. 37–8Google Scholar; Lowie, op. cit., pp. 80–81. Rules of “avoidance” between certain relatives, e.g., son-in-law and mother-in-law, brother and sister, are very common. Howitt, op. cit., p. 296; Malinowski, op. cit., p. 71; Barton, R. F., “Ifugao Law,” University of California Publications in American Archaeology and Ethnology, vol. 15, pp. 90–1 (1919)Google Scholar; Lowie, op. cit., pp. 84–5, 97–102. “Communal labor is based on the duties of relatives-in-law.” Malinowski, op. cit., pp. 157–8, 160.

21 Hobhouse, op. cit., pp. 45–6.

22 See Kroeber, A. L., Anthropology (N. Y., 1923). pp. 216240, for the “diffusion” theoryGoogle Scholar.

23 Malinowski, op. cit., pp. 37, 41, 42, 53, 56; Danquak, J. B., Akan Laws and Customs (London, 1928), 1Google Scholar.

24 Willoughby, op. cit., pp. 144–6.

25 For the way in which interests which once gave rise to conflict silently dissolve before changes in the environment, see Lecky, , History of European Rationalism (N. Y., 1910), vol. i, pp. 35 ff.Google Scholar

26 Marett, op. cit., pp. 185 ff.; Sumner, op. cit., p. 17. For the survival of customs into a changed environment, see Mayo, Katherine, Mother India (N. Y., 1927)Google Scholar, passim.

27 Cf. Sorokin, P., Social Mobility (N. Y., 1927)Google Scholar, passim.

28 Tarde, G., Les Lois de l'Imilation (Paris, 6th ed., 1911), p. 10Google Scholar.

29 Because many such uniformities are less deeply rooted and change much more rapidly than customs, Tarde distinguishes them by calling them “fashions,” op. cit., p. 350.

30 Dewey, , The Public and its Problems, pp. 213 ff.Google Scholar

31 E.g. in the case of the so-called “levirate.” Lowie, op. cit., pp. 18–9.

32 Malinowski, op. cit., pp. 91–6.

33 Hartland, E. S., Primitive Paternity (London, 1910), vol. 2, pp. 101 ff.Google Scholar; Spencer, , Baldwin, , and Gillen, , Native Tribes of Central Australia (London, 1899), pp. 99100Google Scholar; Howitt, op. cit., p. 682; Hobhouse, op. cit., p. 136. See Malinowski, , The Family Among the Australian Aborigines (London, 1913)Google Scholar, for customary regulation of sexual irregularities, e.g., by the institution of “pirrauru marriage.” “The majority of fights and quarrels are about women.” Ibid., p. 125.

34 Lowie, op. cit., pp. 209–215. For emphasis on the peaceful character of life among the lower hunting peoples, see Perry, W. J., “The Peaceable Habits of Primitive Communities,” Hibbert Journal (Oct., 1917), 28 ff.Google Scholar; among the town-agricultural peoples, Veblen, Thorstein, The Instinct of Workmanship (N. Y., 1914), 100–102, 120129Google Scholar.

35 Malinowski, , Crime and Custom in Savage Society (London, 1926)Google Scholar, passim; Argonauts of the Western Pacific, p. 115.

36 Hobhouse thinks this true even for “instincts”, which are intermediate between physiological reflexes and habits. Op. cit., pp. 4–6. For “plasticity of instincts,” see Malinowski, , Sex and Repression in Savage Society (N. Y., 1927), pp. 225–8Google Scholar.

37 McDougall, op. cit., chap. 15.

38 Maine, , Early Law and Custom, p. 264Google Scholar.

39 Thorndike, E. L., Educational Psychology: The Original Nature of Man (N. Y., 1919), pp. 108122CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

40 What Malinowski calls the “reciprocity of services.” Crime and Custom pp. 22–7.

41 Rivers, op. cit., p. 168. For ridicule as a social sanction, and the peculiar institution of “joking relatives,” see Lowie, op. cit., p. 100; Hartland, , Primitive Law, p. 162Google Scholar.

42 Howitt, op. cit., pp. 296–300; Frazer, , Golden Bough (one vol. ed., N. Y., 1925), pp. 1148Google Scholar; Malinowski, , Argonauts, pp. 59–60, 73, 116Google Scholar.

43 Howitt, op. cit., p. 316.

44 Ibid., pp. 530–2, 638–9; Spencer and Gillen, op. cit., chaps, vii-ix; Hambly, W. D., Origins of Education among Primitive Peoples (London, 1926), pp. 186199Google Scholar.

45 Sumner, op. cit., pp. 3–4.

46 Bertrand Russell, Principles of Reconstruction; Ibid., Prospects of Industrial Civilization; G. D. H. Cole, Social Theory; M. P. Follett, The New State; Warbasse, J. P., Coöperative Democracy (N. Y., 1927)Google Scholar; Veblen, Thorstein, The Nature of Peace (N. Y., 1917)Google Scholar. This view regards itself as underlying the movement for "self-government in industry,” e.g., through voluntary “standardization, as a substitute for legislative control by the state.” See various papers by Agnew, P. G., “How Business is Policing Itself,” Nation's Business, December, 1925Google Scholar; Can Industry Make its own Law?”, Association Management, December, 1926Google Scholar, etc.

47 William Godwin, Enquiry Concerning Political Justice, book v, chaps. 22–24; Kropotkin, Mutual Aid as a Factor of Evolution; Ibid., Anarchism, its Philosophy and Ideal; L. Tolstoy, The Kingdom of God is Within You; Eltzbacher, Anarchism.

48 For “taking the wall” and “keeping the wall,” see Boswell's, Life of Johnson (ed. Glover, , London, 1901), vol. i, p. 61Google Scholar.

49 Dewey, , Human Nature and Conduct, p. 75Google Scholar.

50 Sumner, op. cit., p. 28.

51 Dewey, and Tufts, , Ethics (N. Y., 1908), pp. 51–91, 428434Google Scholar.

52 Hobhouse, op. cit., pp. 419.

53 Godwin, op. cit. (3rd ed., London, 1798), vol. i, p. 398. See my Statesman's Book of John of Salisbury (N. Y., 1927), pp. lxxviilxxxGoogle Scholar. Cf. Spencer, Herbert, “The Evanescence of Evil,” in Social Statics (N. Y., 1892), pp. 2832Google Scholar.

54 Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics (8th ed., London, 1920), pp. 29–37, 770784Google Scholar.

55 Carey, Henry C., Principles of Political Economy (Phila., 18371840)Google Scholar; Bastiat, , Harmonies Économiques (Paris, 1850)Google Scholar. Cf. Herbert Spencer, Social Statics and Man versus the State.

56 Cairnes, J. E., Logical Method of Political Economy (2nd ed, London, 1875), pp. 107 ff.Google Scholar; Walker, F. A., Political Economy (N. Y., 1888), pp. 1117Google Scholar; Marshall, op. cit., p. 36.

57 Clay, Henry, Economics for the General Reader (N. Y., 1920), pp. 440443Google Scholar; Governor's Advisory Commission, Cloak, Suit, and Skirt Industry of New York City, Report of an Investigation, by Dickinson, John and Kolchin, Morris (1925), pp. 143155Google Scholar; Hamilton, Walton H. and Wright, Helen R., The Case of Bituminous Coal (N. Y.. 1925), pp. 19–94, 200210Google Scholar.

58 Small, op. cit., pp. 201, 281, quoting Gierke, , Deutsche Genossenschaftsrecht, vol. i, p. 2Google Scholar.

59 Barton, R. K.. Ifugao Law (supra, note 20), pp. 9–10, 94–9Google Scholar.

59a E.g., The Bryan “Peace Commission” treaties and the Central American treaties of 1922–3, all setting up permanent commissions of inquiry and conciliation. See Buell, R. L., International Relations (N. Y., 1925), 590593Google Scholar.

60 Cohen, Julius H., An American Labor Policy (N. Y., 1920)Google Scholar; Sharp, Malcolm P., “Due Process of Law,” in Industrial Government, by Commons, J. R. and others (N. Y., 1921), pp. 193235Google Scholar.

61 Cohen, op. cit., pp. 78–88.

62 Adams, C. F., Railroads and their Problems (N. Y., 1878), p. 191Google Scholar. See also Johnson, E. R., American Railway Transportation (N. Y., 1906), p. 227Google Scholar; Ripley, W. Z., Railway Problems (Boston, 1913), pp. 134 ff.Google Scholar

63 Cohen, Julius H., Law and Order in Industry (N. Y., 1916)Google Scholar.

64 Levine, Louis, The Women's Garment Worker (N. Y., 1924), pp. 233319Google Scholar.

65 Cf. Dewey, , The Public and its Problems, pp. 39 ff.Google Scholar

66 Barton, op. cit., pp. 75–77.

67 Ibid., p. 17.

68 It is to be noted that the efforts toward industrial “standardization,” referred to above, note 46, as representing the idea of “self-government in industry,” call for the organization, and depend upon the continued functioning, of a central organ within the industry, accompanying a more or less authoritative and impartial position, in the form of a committee to formulate rules and preside over their application. Agnew, P. G., “The National Safety Code Program,” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, January, 1926Google Scholar. It is also to be noted that in most instances the impulse for the formation of such committees emanated from an outside source, the federal government.