Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nr4z6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-20T08:56:18.990Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The new mercantilism in international relations: The case of France's external monetary policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Henrik Schmiegelow
Affiliation:
Henrik Schmiegelow was a scholar of the German Office of Academic Exchange and of the Virginia Law School Graduate Program while doing his research for this article. He wishes to express his gratitude to these institutions for their grants. Michèle Schmiegelow is a consultant to the Centre d'Etudes Européennes of the University of Louvain, Belgium.
Michèle Schmiegelow
Affiliation:
Henrik Schmiegelow was a scholar of the German Office of Academic Exchange and of the Virginia Law School Graduate Program while doing his research for this article. He wishes to express his gratitude to these institutions for their grants. Michèle Schmiegelow is a consultant to the Centre d'Etudes Européennes of the University of Louvain, Belgium.
Get access

Extract

We argue that mercantilism is not an anachronism, but a pattern of interaction between economies functioning analytically as subsystems both of nations and societies. The relation between theory and policy in France's post-war monetary history suggests two concepts of mercantilist rationalization of external economic policy. Although verbalized in terms of liberal economic theory, French monetary policy served nationalist diplomacy (diplomatic mercantilism) and/or the specific societal politics of the domestic economy (political mercantilism). Diplomatic and political mercantilism are indices of indeterminacy of international economics. Societal politics and international economics are thresholds of feasibility for diplomatic mercantilism. But cumulative rationalization of feasible external economic policy in terms of both political and diplomatic mercantilism is not excluded. As a function both of national system maintenance and societal integration, mercantilism is more easily explained in terms of sociological functionalism than in terms of either international functionalism or Realism alone.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1975

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Mitrany, David, A Working Peace System (London: Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1943)Google Scholar; Haas, Ernst B., Beyond the Nation State: Functionalism and International Organization (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1964), p. 29Google Scholar; Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S. Jr, eds., “Transnational Relations and World Politics,” International Organization 25 (Summer 1971).Google Scholar

2 Heckscher, Eli F., Mercantilism, 2 vols., trans. Shapiro, Mendel, 2nd ed., edited by Söderlund, E. F. (London: Allen and Unwin, New York: MacMillan, 1955)Google Scholar; Coleman, D. C., ed., Revisions in Mercantilism (London: Methuen, 1969)Google Scholar; Schumpeter, Joseph A., History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press, 1959)Google Scholar; idem, Economic Doctrine and Method, trans. R.Aris(New York: Oxford University Press, 1967); Joan, Robinson, The New Mercantilism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1966)Google Scholar; John, Knapp, “Economics or Political Economy?,” Lloyds Bank Review, no. 107 (01 1973), p. 19.Google ScholarPubMed

3 Stanley, Hoffmann, “Weighing the Balance of Power,” Foreign Affairs 50 (07 1972), p. 632Google Scholar; idem, “La nation, pourquoi faire?” in J. C.Casanova et al., Mélanges en l'honneur de Raymond Aron, (Paris, Calmann-Lévy, 1971), p. 336. We wish to acknowledge, though, that in his critical comments on this paper, Stanley Hoffmann has stressed that his dismissal of mercantilism as obsolete is perfectly compatible with his firmly held view that, contrary to the “liberal” conception, governments continue and will continue to manipulate domestic and international economics in order to reach national ends. In his view, however, “the neo-mercantiism which is thus practiced develops in an environment of such tight interdependence that it really has rather little in common with the zero-sum game mercantilism of the 17th century.” Our own opinion, as developed in this essay, is that interdependence is one of the very conditions of mercantilist attitudes.

4 Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London and Basingstoke: MacMillan, 1936), p. 383.Google Scholar

5 Schumpeter, , History of Economic Analysis, p. 336Google Scholar. See also Robinson, p. 7; Knapp, pp. 39–43; Michèle, Schmiegelow, “L'Adhésion de la Roumanie au FMI et la théorie des relations internales”, Revue française de science politique 24 (02 1974), p. 113.Google Scholar

6 Keynes, pp. 333–72; Schumpeter, , History of Economic Analysis, p. 283Google Scholar, note 11; Heckscher, vol. 2, pp. 340–59; André, Piettre, Monnaie et économie internationale du 19ème siècle à nos jours (Paris: Editions Cujas, 1971), pp. 15, 80.Google Scholar

7 Knapp, p. 19; Robinson, , Freedom and Necessity: An Introduction to the Study of Society (London: Allen and Unwin, 1970), pp. 8393Google Scholar; idem, The New Mercantilism; Benjamin Cohen, ed., American Foreign Economic Policy: Essays and Comments (New York: Harper and Row, 1968), in particular Benjamin Cohen, “American Foreign Economic Policy: Some General Principles of Analysis,” p. 16; Schmiegelow, pp. 120–22; Gross, Herbert, “Die Renaissance des Merkantilismus: Neue Phase des Keynesianismus”, Handelsblatt (Düsseldorf), 1 02 1973, p. 25Google Scholar; Manfred, Schafer, “In Europa haben nationale Interessen den Vorrang”, Handelsblatt, 30 05 1974. p. 5.Google Scholar

8 Gunnar, Myrdal, The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory, trans. Streeten, Paul (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1954), pp. 123, 141, 195Google Scholar, and idem, Objectivity in Social Research, (New York: Pantheon Books, 1969), pp. 44, 109–11.

9 Hoffmann, , “Obstinate or Obsolete: The Fate of the Nation State and the Case of Western Europe”, Daedalus 95 (1966), p. 862.Google Scholar

10 Heilbroner, L., Between Capitalism and Socialism: Essays in Political Economics (New York: Vintage Books, 1970), pp. 331Google Scholar; Andrew, Shonfield, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (New York, Oxford, London: Oxford University Press, 1965, pp. 7180, 121–51, 171, 414Google Scholar; Amitai, Etezioni, “Toward a Keynesian Theory of Social Processes”, World Politics 22 (10 1969), pp. 139, 141–2Google Scholar; Schmiegelow, , “The Role of the State Elite in France” (Master's Thesis, University of Virginia, 1973)Google Scholar; Stephen, Cohen, Modern Capitalist Planning: The French Model (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1969)Google Scholar. See also Georges, Pompidou, “Entretien télévisé du Président Pompidou le 8 février 1973”, Le Monde (Paris), 9 02 1973, p. 2Google Scholar; August Graf, Kageneck, “Mitterand und Giscard streiten über den Weg zur Gerechtigkeit”, Die Welt (Hamburg) 17 02 1973, p. 2Google Scholar; and Giscard's first presidential message to the parliament: “La France veut devenir autre”, Le Monde, 1 June 1974, p. 2.

11 See, for example, Jacques, Rueff, “The West is Risking a Credit Collapse”, Fortune 64 (07 1961), p. 126Google Scholar; idem, Le péché monétaire de l'occident (Paris: Plon, 1971); and Valéry, Giscard d'Estaing, “The International Monetary Order”, in Mundell, Robert A. and Swoboda, Alexander A., eds., Monetary Problems of the International Economy, (Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press, 1969), p. 17.Google Scholar

12 Kindleberger, Charles P., “The Politics of International Money and World Language,” Essays in International Finance, (Princeton), no. 61 (08 1967), p. 11Google Scholar; Paul, Einzig, The Destiny of the Dollar (London and Basingstoke: MacMillan, 1972), pp. 137–43Google Scholar. As to the case for floating rates, see Milton, Friedman, “The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates,” in Friedman, Essays in Positive Economics, (Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 1953), pp. 157203Google Scholar. As evidenced by Friedman's reasoning, floating rates as well are defensible in terms of liberal economic theory. The “economic nationalism” of countries favoring floating rates can therefore only be rationalized in terms of the ends-means relationship between theory and policy in the particular circumstances of the economy concerned. It would go beyond the scope of this paper to do this in detail. However, the French case for fixed exchange rates and its modification after the floating of the franc in 1974 suggests ways of mercantilist rationalization of American and German policies as well, at least by implication. A good discussion of the relative value of the various choices for monetary reform in terms of American national interest in various hypothetical situations is provided by Aliber, Robert Z., “National Preferences and the Scope for International Monetary Reform,” Essays in International Finance (Princeton), no. 101 (11 1973)Google Scholar. For a discussion of the German advocacy of exchange rate flexibility—understandable only from the situation of a country combining persistent payments surpluses with a high political sensitivity towards inflation—see The German Council of Economic Experts, “Towards a New Basis for International Monetary Policy,” Princeton Studies in International Finance, no. 31 (October 1972), pp. 1, 7, 11.

13 See Aron, Raymond, Peace and War: A Theory of International Relations, trans. Richard, Howard and Fox, Anette Baker, (New York: Doubleday, 1966), p. 94Google Scholar; Hoffmann, , Contemporary Theory in International Relations (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1960)Google Scholar; Waltz, Kenneth N., Man, the State, and War (New York: Columbia University Press, 1959)Google Scholar; and Masters, Roger D., “World Politics as a Primitive Political System,” World Politics 16 (07 1964), p. 595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14 For discussion of mercantilism as a concept of integration, see Heckscher, vol. 1, p. 22; Robinson, , Freedom and Necessity, pp. 8893Google Scholar; and Myrdal, , Economic Nationalism and Internationalism (Melbourne: The Australian Institute of International Affairs, 1957), p. 33Google Scholar. As for the concept of an economy as a social system, see Talcott, Parsons and Smelser, Neil J., Economy and Society: A Study in the Integration of Economic and Social Theory (New York: The Free Press, 1965), pp. 14, 34–49Google Scholar; Harrod, Roy F., Towards a Dynamic Economics (London: MacMillan, 1948)Google Scholar; and Knapp, pp. 23, 25, 27, 31. An example of the new mercantilism in the Eastern World is described in Schmiegelow, “L'adhésion de la Roumanie au FMI et la théorie des relations internationales.” On the nationalism of the welfare state, see Myrdal, Economic Nationalism and Internationalism, pp. 14–15; idem, Beyond the Welfare State: Economic Planning and its International Implications(New Haven and London : Yale University Press, 1960); its Keynesian aspects are stressed by Knapp, pp. 40–41; Robinson, Freedom and Necessity, p. 88; Gross, “Die Renaissance des Merkantilismus: Neue Phase des Keynesian-ismus”; Henry, Paul-MarcLa statue du Commandeur,” Le Monde, 18 05 1974, p. 44Google Scholar. As to Keynes' personal liberalism, see Keynes, John Maynard, “Am I a Liberal?” in Alan, Bullock and Maurice, Shock, eds., The Liberal Tradition from Fox to Keynes (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1956), pp. 283–5Google Scholar. But one should also bear in mmd that in post-war Europe neo-Keynesian policies tended to be supported by political groups of Socialist or Social-Democrat orientation rather than by liberal forces. See Lutz, F. A., “Politische Uberzeugungen und nationalökonomische Theorie”, Ordo 9 (1957), p. 12Google Scholar, and Myrdal, , Economic Nationalism and Internationalism, p. 3.Google Scholar

15 Hanrieder, Wolfram F., “Compatibility and Consensus: A Proposal for the Conceptual Linkage of External and Internal Dimensions of Foreign Policy” in Hanrieder, , ed., Comparative Foreign Policy: Theoretical Essays, (New York: David McKay, 1971), pp. 253–64.Google Scholar

16 For discussion see Jacob, Viner, “Power versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries,” World Politics 1 (10 1948), p. 1Google Scholar. Benjamin Cohen has shown the contemporary relevance of that issue. See his “American Foreign Economic Policy: Some General Principles of Analysis,” in Benjamin Cohen ed., p. 16, note 9. See also Klaus, Knorr, Power and Wealth: The Political Economy of International Power, (New York: Basic Books, 1973)Google Scholar. There is a certain risk though, in treating power and wealth as fungible objects. See, e.g., Cohen, Stephen D., International Monetary Reform, 1964–69, The Political Dimension (New York: Praeger, 1970), p. 159; and Nye's criticism in his book review in Journal of Common Market Studies 11 (September 1972), p. 82.Google Scholar

17 Indeed, for de Gaulle, the former cavalry general, the economy allegedly remained something like a quarter-master general's department (“l'intendance”) of the nation. Whether or not he actually pronounced the apocryphal phrase: “l'intendance suivra,” and no matter how much personal effort he dedicated to economic and financial matters, what counted for this “heroic leader” was high politics. See Philippe, Bauchard, Bilan de la Ve République: l'économie au service du pouvoir (Paris: Calmann-Lévy, 1967), p. 7Google Scholar. For discussion of the relevance of de Gaulle's charismatic leadership in terms of integration theory see Haas, , “The Uniting of Europe and the Uniting of Latin America,” Journal of Common Market Studies 5 (19661967), p. 315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

18 Rueff, “The West is Risking a Credit Collapse”, pp. 126–7. See also Yeager, Leland B., International Monetary Relations, Theory, History and Policy (New York: Harper and Row, 1966), p. 466.Google Scholar

19 The Pinay-Rueff Plan is sketched by Pierre Viansson-Ponté, Bilan de la Ve République: les politiques (Paris: Calmann-Lévy, 1967), p. 95Google Scholar; and Bauchard, pp. 18–25. The plan was conceived according to Rueff's ideas, and Antoine Pinay, an equally renowned neo-classical economist, carried it out in his capacity as minister of finance.

20 Bauchard, , Les technocrates et le pouvoir, (Paris: Arthaud, 1966), p. 309Google Scholar; Claude, Gruson, Origines et espoirs de Ia planification française (Paris: Dunod, 1968), pp. 3847Google Scholar; Jean-Francois, Kesler, “Les anciens élèves de l'Ecole Nationale d'Administration,” Revue française de science politique 14 (1964), p. 263Google Scholar. The Monnet Plans are analyzed in Cohen, Stephen, Modern Capitalist Planning: the French Model, p. 81Google Scholar; Jesse, Pitts, “Change in Bourgeois France,” in Hoffmann, , et al. , In Search of France (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1963), p. 269Google Scholar; Jean, Fourastié, La planification économique en France (Paris: P.U.F., 1963), p. 19Google Scholar. As to the Sixth Plan, see Loi No. 70–588 du 9 juillet 1970 portant approbation d'un rapport sur les principales options qui commandent la préparation du VIe Plan, Journal Officiel de la République Française 10 juiflet 1970, esp. Annex, pp. 1–50. See also Le conseil des ministres approuve le texte définitif du VIe Plan (1971–1975),” Le Monde, 29 04 1971, p. 1.Google Scholar

21 See, for example, Moulin, Club JeanQue faire de la révolution de mai? (Paris: Seuil, 1968), pp. 1718Google Scholar; and Maurice, Roy, “A la Pinay,” L'Express (Paris), 17–23 05 1971, p. 15.Google Scholar

22 See Valéry Giscard d'Estaing, p. 17.

23 Bauchard, , L'économie au service du pouvoir, pp. 53, 60–61. For a discussion of Debré's role in French politicsGoogle Scholar see Williams, Philip M. and Martin, Harrison, Politics and Society in de Gaulle's Republic (Garden City: Doubleday, 1971), pp. 3548Google Scholar, 102. His Gaullist orthodoxy is best illustrated by himself in his Une certaine idée de la France (Paris: Fayard, 1972).Google Scholar

24 See Philippe, Simonot, “Les banques centrales pourrount réévaluer leur or pour gager leurs emprunts et payer leurs dettes,” Le Monde, 13 06 1974, pp. 1 and 39.Google Scholar

25 “Dix ans après,” Le Monde, 23 11 1968, p. 1.Google Scholar

26 Club Jean Moulin, p. 17.

27 See Rüdiger, Hopp, Schwankungen des wirtschaftlichen Wachstums in Westdeutschland 1949–1967 (Mejsenheim: Ham, 1969), p. 51.Google Scholar

28 The shift from Ludwig Erhard's neo-liberal policy to Karl Schiller's neo-Keynesian policy after the 1967 recession in Germany is discussed by Heiko, Körner, “The Social Dimension of Political Economy,” Law and State (Tübingen) 6 (1972), pp. 130, 138, note 1.Google Scholar

29 Pierre, Viansson-Ponté, “Le régime dévalué,” Le Monde, 23 11, 1968, p. 1.Google Scholar

30 Le Monde, 26 November 1968, p. 2. See also Jacques, Fauvet, “Le monde entier a cru à la dévaluation,” Le Monde, 26 11 1968, p. 1.Google Scholar

31 Peter, Coffey, “A Note on Monetary Cooperation,” Journal of Common Market Studies 8 (1970), p. 337.Google Scholar

32 Viansson-Ponté, , “La méthode Pompidou,” Le Monde, 26 02 1971, p. 1.Google Scholar

33 de Foucault, Bertrand Fessard, “Une certaine idée de la France: M. Michel Debré ou l'ardeur militante du gaullisme,” Le Monde, 3 11 1972, p. 9Google Scholar. Debré is not the only “trustee” of Gaullism. See Fontaine, , “Waiting for Lenin,” The Manchester Guardian Weekly/Le Monde, 16 12 1972, p. 13Google Scholar. But among the disciples of de Gaulle, Debré is the only one who stands out as an economic thinker. See Bauchard, L'économie au service du pouvoir, p. 58.

34 See Interview de Michel Debré, Ministre de la Défense,” L'Express, 172301 1971.Google Scholar

35 Changement et continuité en diplomatie”, Le Monde, 7 06 1974, p. 1.Google Scholar

36 Kesler, pp. 247–8; Michel, Debré, “Naissance et perspectives d'une institution,” Promotions (Paris), no. 35 (1955), p. 27Google Scholar; idem, Une certaine idée de la France, p. 184; Henry, Parris, “Twenty years of l'Ecole Nationale d'Administration,” Public Administration no. 43 (1965), pp. 395411Google Scholar; Kesler, pp. 243–67; Bernard, Gournay, “Un groupe dirigeant de la société française: Les grandes fonctionnaires,” Revue française de science politique 14 (1964), pp. 215–41Google Scholar; Maurice, Parodi, L'èconomie et la société française de 1945 à 1970, (Paris: Armand Cohn, 1971), pp. 340–44Google Scholar; Jacques, Mandrin, L'Enarchie ou les mandarins de la société bourgeoise (Paris: La Table Ronde de Combat, 1967)Google Scholar; Schmiegelow, , “The Role of the State Elite in France,” pp. 1324, 63–92Google Scholar; André, Passeron, “Les collaborateurs du Premier Minjstre,” Le Monde, 7 04 1973Google Scholar; idem, “Un gouvernement présidentiel,” Le Monde, 30 05 1974, p. 2. The fact that “Enarchs” are again holding the key positions in Giscard's first government was one of the important topics of the debate on Chirac's policy declaration in the National Assembly. See Le débat: la déclaration gouvernmentale de M. Chirac,” Le Monde 7 06 1974, p. 8Google Scholar. As regards “Enarchist” semantics see Mandrin, pp. 23, 45, 87; Pierre, Gilbert, Dictionnaire des mots nouveaux (Paris: Hachette-Tchou, 1971)Google Scholar; and the Dictionnaire Larousse from the 1971 edition on.

37 Yves Cannac: L'un des pères de la Nouvelle Société,” Le Monde, 25 05 1974, p. 8.Google Scholar

38 Edmund, Stillman et al. , L'envol de la France dans les années 80, Introduction par Herman Kahn, (Paris: Hachette, 1973), pp. 116–22, 172–77.Google Scholar

39 See note 20. As to the inflationary repercussions of the French policy of growth see Gruson, p. 40; Vasconcellos, A. S. and Riker, B. F., “An Evaluation of French National Planning: 1949–1964,” Journal of Common Market Studies 8 (1970), p. 226CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Regarding the general significance of the “Keynesian Revolution” see Adolph, Lowe, On Economic Knowledge: Toward a Science of Political Economics (New York and Evanston: Harper & Row, 1965), p. 217Google Scholar; Parsons and Smelser, p. 246; and Knapp, pp. 33, 41. How the French technocracy embraced Keynesian theory is described by Pierre, Lalumière, L'inspection des finances (Paris: P.U.F. 1959), p. 180Google Scholar; Kesler, p. 263; Gruson, p. 40; and Schmiegelow, , “The Role of the State Elite in France,” pp. 4244.Google Scholar

40 Haas, , The Uniting of Europe (Stanford: Stanford University. Press, 1958), p. 454Google Scholar. The quotation is from Hart, Henry M. and Sacks, Albert M., The Legal Process: Basic Problems in the Making and Application of Law (Cambridge, Mass.: Tentative Edition, 1958), p. 111.Google Scholar

41 Raymond, Aron, Les étapes de la pensée sociologique (Paris: N.R.F.-Gillimard, 1969), p. 90Google Scholar. For critical discussions of the “organizing” or “constructivist” school of political theory, see Popper, Karl R., The Open Society and its Enemies, 5th ed., vol. 2 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1966), pp. 131–33Google Scholar; Hayek, F. A., Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1967), pp. 8295Google Scholar; and Ralf, Dahrendorf, Essays in the Theory of Society, (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1968) pp. 215–31.Google Scholar

42 Kesler, p. 263; Schmiegelow, , “The Role of the State Elite in France,” pp. 2835, 42–44Google Scholar; Parodi, p. 343. See also the debate on Chirac's policy declaration in Le Monde, 7 June 1974, p. 8; and Gilbert: “L'Enarchisme consiste à déguiser la politique en technique.”

43 Kesler, p. 248. That Mendesian reformism can have “nationalist” repercussions as well is, of course, the point which we try to make in this paper.

44 For details see Schmiegelow, “The Role of the State Elite in France,” pp. 20–22; 32–33; 92–106. As regards “European” socialization through interpenetration and secondment, see Lawrence Schemmann and Werner Feld, “The European Economic Community and National Civil Servants of the Member States,” International Organization 26 (Winter 1972), p. 132.

45 See also McCracken, Paul W., “Elevating the Transatlantic Dialogue,” Wall Street Journal, 05 24, 1973, p. 8Google Scholar; Paul, Fabra, “Une liberté d'inaction,” Le Monde, 22 01 1974Google Scholar; and Schäfer “In Europa haben national Interessen den Vorrang,” p. 5.

46 Yeager, pp. 161–67; Kindleberger, , International Economics, pp. 253–70Google Scholar. For a discussion of trade elasticities as variables of integration and interdependence, see Tollison, Robert D. and Willet, Thomas D., “International Integration and the Interdependence of Economic Variables,” International Organization 27 (Spring 1973), pp. 261–2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

47 McCracken, p. 8; Schafer, p. 5; and Einzig, , The Destiny of the Dollar, pp. 136–43.Google Scholar

48 See the German Council of Economic Experts, “Toward a New Basis for International Monetary Policy,” pp. 1, 7, 11Google Scholar; Karl, Schiller, “Konvertibilität-Liquidität-Parität: Zum Problemwandel der Währungspolitik in der Nachkriegszeit” in Gerhard Schröder et al., Festschrift für Ludwig Erhard zum 75. Gerburtstag (Frankfurt, Berlin and Vienna: Propyläenverlag, 1972), pp. 208–22Google Scholar. Alfred Müller-Armack et al., Stabilität in Europa: Strategien und Institutionen für eine europäische Stabilitätsgemeinschaft (Düsseldorf and Vienna: Econ Verlag, 1971), pp. 89 ff, are particularly critical of Giscard's model of policy. Regarding the ideological underpinnings of the German position, vis-à-vis the French “Planwirtschaft” see Alwin, Münchmeyer, “Soziale Marktwirtschaft: Ein Modell für Europa” in Schröder et al., pp. 324–36Google Scholar. For an introduction to the German economic system, see Reinhard, Blum, Soziale Marktwirtschaft: Wirtschaftspolitik zwischen Neoliberalismus und Ordoliberalismus (Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), 1969)Google Scholar. See also Shonfield, p. 239.

49 Deutsche, Bundesbank, Report for the Year 1972, p. 25Google Scholar; Heiko, Körner, “Ungelöste Probleme der aussenwirtschaftlichen Absicherung,” Jahrbuch für Sozialwissenschaften 20 (1969), p. 235Google Scholar; Horst, Friedrich, “Instrumente der aussenwirtschaftlichen Absicherung,” Wirtschaftsdienst (Hamburg) no. 3 (1973), p. 151.Google Scholar

50 See, about inflationary repercussions, Deutsche Bundesbank, p. 12; and, about deflationary repercussions, Klaus, Rose, Theorie der Aussenwirtschaft, (München: Franz Vahlen, 1972), p. 188.Google Scholar

51 Unending Crises,” Intereconomics (Hamburg) no. 4 (1973), p. 100.Google Scholar

52 Lasswell, Harold D. and Abraham, Kaplan, Power and Society: A Framework for Political Inquiry (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1950), pp. 22, 79–80.Google Scholar

53 See, in particular, Kindleberger, , “The Euro-Dollar and the Internationalization of U.S. Monetary Policy,” Banca Nazionale Del Lavoro Quarterly Review 88 (1969), p. 8Google Scholar. Robert A. Mundell has attempted to solve the dilemma through a mix of fiscal and monetary policy. See his The Appropriate Use of Fiscal and Monetary Policy for Internal and External Stability,” IMF Staff Papers 9 (03 1962), pp. 7076CrossRefGoogle Scholar. But his propositions have remained highly controversial. See Yeager, pp. 109–13. Moreover, Mundell's policy mix is debatable for practical reasons because of the legal and political inelasticity of restrictive fiscal policy, at least in most Western European countries.

54 Pompidou made the statement in his press conference of September 21, 1972. See Le Monde, 22 09 1972, p. 2.Google Scholar

55 Fabra, , “La dislocation,” Le Monde, 11 05, 1971, p. 1Google Scholar. See also Simonot, , “La France et le prix de l'or,” Le Monde. 29 04 1971. p. 1.Google Scholar

56 Münchmeyer, pp. 324–36.

57 For discussions of the diplomatic background see Robert, Gilpin, “The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations,” in Keohane, and Nye, , eds., pp. 414–15Google Scholar; and Hansen, Roger D., “European Integration: Forward March, Parade Rest, or Dismissed?”, International Organization 27 (Spring 1973), pp. 248–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

58 Fabra, , “Money: Experiment in Realism,” The Manchester Guardian Weekly/Le Monde, 17 03 1973, p. 15Google Scholar, and La réforme du système monétaire: une nouvelle ère?,” Le Monde, 29 03, 1973Google Scholar. Regarding Helmut Schmidt's personal policy preferences see “Wirtschaftspolitik des kommenden Kanzlers,” Handelsblatt, 8 05 1974Google Scholar. See also, on the situation of March 1973, Hans, Mayrzedt and Otto von, Platen, “Vorschläge zur Stärkung des Europäischen Währungsblocks,” Wirtschaftsdienst, (Hamburg) no. 8 (1973), p. 424Google Scholar; “Unending crises,” Intereconomics, p. 101.Google Scholar

59 See Fabra, , “Une liberté d'inaction,” Le Monde, 22 01 1974Google Scholar, and Bert, Hagelstein, “Die grosse Umverteilung,” Handelsblatt, 22 01 1974, p. 3.Google Scholar

60 Simonot, , “Les banques centrales pourront réévaluer leur or pour gager leurs emprunts et payer leur dettes,” Le Monde, 13 06 1974, p. 1Google Scholar. See also Peter, Jenkins, “Summit Talks Save Europe,” The Guardian Weekly (Manchester), 25 05 1974, p. 7Google Scholar. About Debré's most significant approval see André, Fontaine, “Every Man for Himself,” The Guardian Weekly/Le Monde, 2 02 1974, p. 13.Google Scholar

61 Gilbert, Mathieu, “Une révision du budget pour accompagner l'opération?,” Le Monde, 22 01 1974, p. 1Google Scholar; Mehr französische Exporte gegen das drohende Defizit: Abwertung soll Preisvorteile im Ausland sichern,” Handelsblatt, 22 01 1974, p. 4Google Scholar. See also Mathieu, , “Une opération en deux temps,” Le Monde, 4 06 1974, p. 5Google Scholar. The term “snake” refers to the reduced fluctuations between the European currencies since March 1972. In a first step toward the creation of a single European currency, the Six at that time agreed to reduce, by one half, the 4.5 percent margin of fluctuation considered normal in a system of fixed exchange rates. See Hansen, p. 243. About the relation between French and German prices, see Mathieu, , “Une opération en deux temps,” p. 5.Google Scholar

62 See André, Laurens, “MM. Giscard d'Estaing et Mitterand contestent mutuellement leur capacité à maintenir la croissance tout eni répartissant plus équitablement ses fruits,” Le Monde, 12–13 05 1974, pp. 1, 8.Google Scholar

63 After having won the 1974 presidential elections, Giscard could, of course, consider taking unpopular anti-inflationary measures without too much immediate political risk. See Mathieu, , “Une opération en deux temps?,” p. 5Google Scholar. And the “Inflation Cooling Plan” adopted on the 12 June 1974 was even inspired, to a certain extent, by the German model of policy of price stability. But the scope of these measures is again limited by the particular conditions of France's political economy. See Mathieu, , “A l'écoute de Bonn,” Le Monde, 14 06 1974, pp. 1, 3.Google Scholar

64 This has repeatedly been a theme of OECD recommendations to Germany. They stressed that Germany could contribute to international payments equilibrium in permitting domestic inflation to develop according to international standards. See Kindleberger, , “Germany's Persistent Balance of Payments Disequilibrium,” in Baldwin, Robert E. ed., Trade, Growth and the Balance of Payments (Chicago: Rand, McNally, 1966), p. 231Google Scholar. As far as “world patterns” of inflation are concerned, see Henry, “La statue du commandeur,” p. 44. That these world patterns are far from being so harmonious as to achieve international payments equilibrium is a point made by Myrdal, Economic Nationalism and Internationalism, p. 14; Einzig, , The Destiny of the Dollar, pp. 142–3Google Scholar; and, as regards the situation of 1974, Jenkins, , “Survival of the Fittest,” The Guardian Weekly, 8 06 1974, p. 15.Google Scholar

65 Mathieu, , “Une operation en deux temps,” p. 5Google Scholar; and Währungsschlange prähistorisch”, Handelsblatt, 4 05 1974, p. 2.Google Scholar

66 Hoffmann, , “The European Process at Atlantic Cross Purposes,” Journal of Common Market Studies 3 (1965), p. 89Google Scholar. To be sure, Hoffmann seemed to use the discontinuity concept mainly to contend Haas' and Schmitter's neo-functionalist concept of a continuum from economics to politics. In his comments to this paper he stresses that a discontinuity in the ideal types of “low” and “high” politics does not mean a complete dichotomy in practice. Thus he qualified the discontinuity concept in his “Weighing the Balance of Power,” p. 632. Yet his proposition that mercantilism is an anachronism is certainly related to this concept.

67 See, for example, Gilpin, “The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations”; Waltz, “The Myth of National Interdependence” in , Kindleberger, The International Corporation: A Symposium, (Cambridge, Mass.: The M.I.T. Press, 1970), pp. 205–26Google Scholar. For policy-oriented studies, see Cohen, Benjamin, American Foreign Economic PolicyGoogle Scholar; and Cooper, Richard N., “Trade Policy is Foreign Policy,” Foreign Policy 8 (Winter 19721973), p. 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

68 See Rosenau, James N., “Pre-theories and Theories of Foreign Policy,” in Farrell, R. Barry ed., Approaches to Comparative and International Politics, (Evanston: Northwestern University Press, 1966), p. 53Google Scholar; and Hanrieder, pp. 256–64. Indeed, the emergence of the new mercantilism countervails, in the issue areas of international economics, the emergence of what Rosenau calls the “penetrated” system.

69 Benjamin, Cohen, “American Foreign Economic Policy: Some General Principles of Analysis,” p. 16.Google Scholar

70 Haas, , Beyond the Nation State, p. 50.Google Scholar

71 Parsons and Smelser, pp. 19, 39–51, 102. We wish to state, though, that our propositions are without any implications as regards the specific positions taken by Parsons and Smelser in terms of economic theory. A particular analytical dimension is opened to sociological functionalism by Lowe's methodology for a “political economics.” See Lowe, pp. 4, 143; and Heilbroner, pp. 165–92.

72 Haas, , Beyond the Nation State, p. 47Google Scholar. See also idem, “The Study of Regional Integration: Reflections on the Joy and Anguish of Pre-theorizing,” in Leon N.Lindberg and Stuart A.Scheingold eds., “Regional Integration: Theory and Research,” International Organization 24 (Autumn 1970), p. 627; Lasswell, Harold D., Politics: Who Gets What, When, How (New York: McGraw Hill, 1936)Google Scholar; and Keohane, and Nye, , Eds., “Transnational Relations and World Politics,” p. 346.Google Scholar

73 The argument, here, is methodologically analogous to the one which Modelski has used to describe concrete international systems in terms of two analytical systems. See George, Modelski, “Agraria and Industria: Two Models of the International System,” World Politics 14 (1961), p. 120.Google Scholar

74 For discussion of the problem of content in functionalist paradigms, see Kaiser, Ronn D., “Toward the Copernican Phase of Regional Integration Theory,” Journal of Common Market Studies 10 (03 1973), pp. 208–15.Google Scholar

75 See Gerhard, Niemeyer, Law without Force: The Function of Politics in International Law, (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1941)Google Scholar; and Haas, , Beyond the Nation State, pp. 42–6.Google Scholar

76 Popper, , Conjectures and Refutations: The Growth of Scientific Knowledge (New York and Evanston: Harper and Row, 1965), p. 37Google Scholar, and idem, The Poverty of Historicism (New York and Evanston: Harper and Row, 1964), p. 3.