Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-23T06:22:01.540Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

John Neville Keynes: The Social Philosophy of a Late Victorian Economist

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

John Neville Keynes (1852–1949) is best known for fathering one of the most influential economists of our time, John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946). Yet in his own day he was a formidable logician1 and economist himself. Although overshadowed by his colleague Alfred Marshall, his Scope and Method of Political Economy (1891) is still considered a minor classic and read by specialists in the history of economic thought. Maynard Keynes's biographers have portrayed Neville as having a powerful influence on him, even if they have failed to detail the impact of the father's logic and economics on his famous son.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Beddington, D. W. 1982. The Nonconformist Conscience: Chapel and Politics 1870–1914, George Allen Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Binfield, Clyde. 1977. So Down to Prayer: Studies in English Nonconformity 1780–1920, Rowman and Littlefield, Totowa.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1994. “Recent Biographies of KeynesJournal of Economic Literature, 32, 09, 1204–15.Google Scholar
Cashdollar, Charles D. 1989. The Transformation of Theology 1830–1890, Princeton University Press, Princeton.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Everitt, Alan. 1972. The Pattern of Rural Dissent: The Nineteenth Century, Leicester University Press, Leicester.Google Scholar
Freeden, Michael. 1978. The New Liberalism, Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Alan D. 1976. Religion and Society in Industrial England: Church, Chapel and Social Change 1740–1914, Longman, London and New York.Google Scholar
Harrod, R. F. 1951. The Life of John Maynard Keynes, Harcourt Brace, New York.Google Scholar
Hession, Charles H. 1984. John Maynard Keynes, Macmillan Publishing, New York.Google Scholar
Johnson, Elizabeth S. and Johnson, Harry G.. “The Social and Intellectual Orgins of The General TheoryHistory of Political Economy 6, Fall 1974, 261–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Neville. Journals 1864–1917, Manuscript Reading Room, Cambridge University Library, England.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Neville. 1884. Studies and Exercises in Formal Logic, Macmillan, London.Google Scholar
Koss, Stephen. 1975. Nonconformity in Modern British Politics, Archon Books, Hampdon.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. Keynes-Marshall Correspondence, Alfred Marshall Library, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Moggridge, D. E. 1992. Maynard Keynes, An Economist's Biography, Routledge, London and New York.Google Scholar
Palgrave, Inglis. 1923, 1926. Dictionary of Political Economy, 1–3, Macmillan, London.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, Robert. 1983. John Maynard Keynes: A Biography, 1, Hopes Betrayed 1883–1920, Macmillan, London.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, Robert. 1994. John Maynard Keynes: A Biography, 2, The Economist as Saviour, Viking-Penguin, New York.Google Scholar
Strachey, Lytton. 1918. Eminent Victorians, Modern Library, New York.Google Scholar
Turner, Frank M. 1993. Contesting Cultural Authority: Essays in Victorian Intellectual Life, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wohl, Anthony S., ed. 1978. The Victorian Family: Structure and Stresses, St. Martin's Press, New York.Google Scholar
Young, G. M. 1936. Portrait of an Age: Victorian England, annotated edition by Clark, G. K., Oxford University Press, 1977.Google Scholar