Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-5g6vh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T12:11:05.673Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE GESELL CONNECTION DURING THE GREAT DEPRESSION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 June 2017

Rosario Patalano*
Affiliation:
University of Naples Federico II, Department of Law, Via Mezzocannone, 16, 80100, Naples, Italy; e-mail: rpatalan@unina.it.

Abstract

In the current recession, the proposal of negative nominal interest has received widespread attention, not only in the academic world. The negative interest rate issue was originally developed by Silvio Gesell (1862–1930), a German merchant, self-taught economist, and social reformer. In his main work, The Natural Economic Order, Gesell offered a theoretical basis for the practical implementation of the negative interest rate. This proposal, generally known as the “stamped money plan,” was favorably commented upon by two outstanding twentieth-century economists, Irving Fisher and John Maynard Keynes, and put into practice during the Great Depression. In this paper I propose a reading of Gesell’s theory of money from the point of view of quantity theory, giving prominence to elements of affinity with Fisher’s monetary theory. This re-examination entails revision of the opinion on the analytical contribution made by Gesell, who was generally tagged as a typical monetary crank, and proves that his place in the history of economic thought is less marginal than previously thought, reinforcing critical appreciation of him.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Abdullah, Adam. 2013. “The Gibson Paradox: Real Gold, Interest Rates and Prices.” International Business Research 6 (4): 3244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allais, Maurice. 1945. Economie et Intérêt. Présentation nouvelle des problèmes fondamentaux relatifs au rôle économique du taux de intérêt et de leur solutions. Paris: Imprimerie Nationale.Google Scholar
Allais, Maurice. 1968. “Irving Fisher.” In Sills, David L., ed., International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences. Volume 5. London and New York: The Macmillan Company and The Free Press, pp. 475485.Google Scholar
Allais, Maurice. 1977. L’impôt sur le capital et la réforme monétaire. Paris: Hermann.Google Scholar
Allen, William R. 1977. “Irving Fisher, F. D. R., and the Great Depression.” History of Political Economy 9 (Winter): 560587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allsbrook, Ogden O. Jr. 1986. “N. A. L. J. Johannsen: An Early Monetarist.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics / Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 142, 2 (June): 431437.Google Scholar
Assous, Michael. 2013. “Irving Fisher’s Debt Deflation Analysis: From the Purchasing Power of Money (1911) to the Debt-Deflation Theory of the Great Depression (1933).” Special issue on Irving Fisher, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20 (2): 305322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, William J. 1985. From New Era to New Deal. Herbert Hoover, the Economists and American Economic Policy. 1921–1933. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartsch, Günter. 1994. Die NWO-Bewegung Silvio Gesells, Geschichtlicher Grundriß 1891–1992/93. Lütjenburg: Gauke.Google Scholar
Bech, Morten L. and Malkhozov, Aytek. 2016. “How Have Central Banks Implemented Negative Policy Rate?” BIS Quarterly Review (March). http://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt1603e.htm. Accessed 8 April 2017.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in Propagation of the Great Depression.” American Economic Review 73, 3 (June): 257276.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2002. “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here.’’ Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke, November 21, 2002. http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002/20021121/default.htm. Accessed 8 April 2017.Google Scholar
Blanc, Jérôm. 1998. “Free Money for Social Progress: Theory and Practice of Gesell’s Accelerated Money.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 57, 4 (October): 469483.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanc, Jérôm. 2002. “Silvio Gesell socialiste proudhonien et réformateur monétaire.” Document de Travail n. 253. Centre Auguste et Léon Walras, Lyon.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael, and Filardo, Andrew. 2005. “Deflation and Monetary Policy in a Historical Perspective: Remembering the Past or Being Condemned to Repeat It?” Economic Policy 20, 44 (October): 801836.Google Scholar
Brown, Vernon L. 1941. “Scrip and Other Forms of Emergency Currency Issued in the United States During the Great Depression.” Two volumes. Master’s thesis. Graduate School of Business Administration, New York University, New York.Google Scholar
Buiter, Willem H. 2009. “Negative Nominal Interest Rates: Three Ways to Overcome the Zero Lower Bound.” The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 20, 3 (December): 213238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buiter, Willem H. and Panigirtzoglou, Nikolaos. 2003. “Overcoming the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates with Negative Interest on Currency: Gesell’s Solution.” The Economic Journal 113, 490 (October): 723746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cahiers de Decta . 1987. Séminaire Silvio Gesell. Faculté Des Sciences Économiques, Université De Bordeaux I.Google Scholar
Chick, Victoria, 1987. “Silvio Gesell.” In Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, and Newman, Peter, eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Volume II. London: Macmillan, p. 520.Google Scholar
Cohrssen, Hans R. L. 1932. “Wara.” The New Republic, (August 10): 338339.Google Scholar
Cohrssen, Hans R. L. 1933. “Stamp Scrip Adapted to an Emergency Situation in Reading, Pennsylvania.” In Fisher, Irving, Stamp scrip. Assisted by Cohrssen, Hans R. L. and Fisher, H. W.. New York: Adelphi, appendix IV.Google Scholar
Cohrssen, Hans R. L. 1989. “The Stamp Scrip Movement in the USA.” In Suhr, Dieter, The Capitalistic Cost-Benefit Structure of Money—An Analysis of Money’s Structural Nonneutrality and its Effects on the Economy. Berlin and New York: Springer Verlag, pp. 116119. http://www.sozialoekonomie.info/Info_Foreign_Languages/English_6/english_6.html. Accessed 8 April 2017.Google Scholar
Cohrssen, Hans R. L. 1991. “Working for Irving Fisher.” Cato Journal 10 (3): 825833.Google Scholar
Comelli, Martino. 2012. “The Surprising Origins and Legacy of Irving Fisher’s Crankish Ideas.” Working paper. Available on-line: mrtno.com/doc/fisher.pdf. Accessed 8 April 2017.Google Scholar
Cot, Annie L. 2013. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions: On Irving Fisher’s Use of Medical Metaphors.” Oeconomia 32: 263286.Google Scholar
Daly, Herman E. 1980. “The Economic Thought of Frederick Soddy.” History of Political Economy 2, 4 (Winter): 469488.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darity, William Jr. 1995. “Keynes’ Political Philosophy: The Gesell Connection.” Eastern Economic Journal 21 (Winter): 2741.Google Scholar
della Paolera, Gerardo, and Taylor, Alan M.. 2001. Straining at the Anchor: The Argentine Currency Board and the Search for Macroeconomic Stability, 1880–1935. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dillard, Dudley D. 1940. “Proudhon, Gesell and Keynes. An Investigation of Some ‘Anti-Marxian Socialists’ Antécédents of Keynes’ General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.” PhD dissertation. University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Dillard, Dudley D. 1942a. “Silvio Gesell’s Monetary Theory of Social Reform.” The American Economic Review 32, 2 (Part 1): 348352.Google Scholar
Dillard, Dudley D. 1942b. “Keynes and Proudhon.” The Journal of Economic History 2, 1 (May): 6376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 1991. “Cranks, Heretics and Macroeconomics in the 1930s.” History of Economic Review 16: 1130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 1994. “Irving Fisher’s Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions.” Review of Social Economy 52 (1): 92107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Douglas, Clifford Hugh. 1924. Social Credit. Edinburgh: Cecil Palmer.Google Scholar
Dow, Sheila. 2016. “The Political Economy of Monetary Reform.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 40: 13631376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Draghi, Mario. 2016. “Introductory statement to the press conference.” 10 March 2016. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2016/html/is160310.en.html. Accessed 8 April 2017.Google Scholar
Echevers, Peter H. 2014. J. Silvio Gesell—Die Revolution des Geldsystems. Verlag: LULU Press Entreprise.Google Scholar
Elliott, John E., and Preparata, Guido Giacomo. 2004. “Free Economics: The Vision of Reformer Silvio Gesell.” Festschrift in honor of John O’Brien, International Journal of Social Economics 31, 10 (September): 923954.Google Scholar
Ellis, Howard S. 1934. German Monetary Theory, 1905–1933. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elvins, Sarah. 2005. “Scrip Money and Slump Cures: Iowa’s Experiments with Alternative Currency During the Great Depression.” The Annals of Iowa 64, 3 (Summer): 221245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elvins, Sarah. 2012. “Selling Scrip to America: Ideology, Self-help and the Experiments of the Great Depression.” In Blanc, Jèrome, ed., “Thirty Years of Community and Complementary Currencies: A Review of Impacts, Potential and Challenges.” Special issue, International Journal of Community Currency Research 16: 1421.Google Scholar
Ferreira, Nathalie. 2010. “De la réforme du système monétaire à la monnaie sociale: l’apport théorique de P. J. Proudhon (1809–1865).” L’Actualité économique 86 (2): 205225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, Stanley. 2016. “Monetary Policy, Financial Stability, and the Zero Lower Bound.” Remarks by Stanley Fischer, Vice-Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, San Francisco, California, January 3, 2016. http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/fischer20160103a.pdf. Accessed 8 April 2017.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit Interest and Crises. New York: The Macmillan Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1920. Stabilizing the Dollar. New York: The Macmillan Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1930. The Theory of Interest. New York: The Macmillan Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1932. Booms and Depressions. Some First Principles. New York: Adelphi.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933a. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions.” Econometrica 1: 337357. Also published in Revue de l’Institut International de Statistique 1934 (1): 48–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933b. Stamp scrip. Assisted by Cohrssen, Hans R. L. and Fisher, H. W.. New York: Adelphi.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1934a. Mastering the Crisis, with Additional Chapters on Stamp Scrip. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1934b. After Reflation, What? Herbert Wescott, contributor. Second edition. New York: Adelphi.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1934c. “Reflation and Stabilization.” In “Banking and Transportation Problems,” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 171 (January 1934): 127131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1935. Stabilized Money. A History of the Movement. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1997. Correspondence and Other Commentary on Economic Policy 1930–1947 . In Barber, William J., ed., The Works of Irving Fisher. Volume XIV. London: Pickering and Chatto.Google Scholar
Forbonnais, François Véron Duverger de. 1755. Élémens du Commerce. Amsterdam: chez François Changuion.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Schwartz, Anna J.. 1976. “From Gibson to Fisher.” Explorations in Economic Research 3 (2): 288291.Google Scholar
Gaitskell Hugh, T. N. 1933. “Four Monetary Heretics.” In Cole, George D. H., ed., What Everybody Wants to Know About Money. London: Gollancz, pp. 280335.Google Scholar
Galbraith, , Kenneth, John. 1977. The Age of Uncertainty. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Garvy, George. 1975. “Keynes and the Economic Activists of Pre-Hitler Germany.” The Journal of Political Economy 83 (2): 391405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gatch, Loren. 2004. “This Is Not United States Currency: Oklahoma’s Emergency Scrip Issues During the Banking Crisis of 1933.” Chronicles of Oklahoma 82: 168199.Google Scholar
Gatch, Loren. 2006. “Local Scrip in the USA During the 1930s: Lessons for Today?” Paper presented at the Conference on Monetary Regionalization: Local Currencies as Catalysts for Endogenous Regional Development. Bauhaus-University Weimar, Germany, September 28–29, 2006. http://community-currency.info/wp-content/uploads/2014/12/local_scrip_in_the_usa-gatch.pdf. Accessed 9 April 2017.Google Scholar
Gatch, Loren. 2008. “Local Money in the United States during the Great Depression.” Essays in Economic & Business History XXVI: 4762.Google Scholar
Gatch, Loren. 2009. “The Professor and a Paper Panacea: Irving Fisher and the Stamp Scrip Movement of 1932–1934.” Paper Money XLVIII, 260 (March–April): 125142.Google Scholar
Gatch, Loren. 2012. “Tax Anticipation Scrip as a Form of Local Currency in the USA during the 1930s.” In Blanc, Jèrom, ed., “Thirty Years of Community and Complementary Currencies: A Review of Impacts, Potential and Challenges.” Special issue, International Journal of Community Currency Research 16: 2235.Google Scholar
Gesell, Silvio. 1891a. Die Reformation im Münzwesen als Brücke zum sozialen Staat. Buenos Aires: Selbstverlag.Google Scholar
Gesell, Silvio. 1891b. Nervus rerum—Fortsetzung zur Reformation im Münzwesen. Buenos Aires: Selbstverlag.Google Scholar
Gesell, Silvio. 1906. Die Verwirklichung des Rechts auf den vollen Arbeitsertrag durch die Geld- und Bodenreform. Les Hauts Geneveys, Leipzig: Selbstverlag.Google Scholar
Gesell, Silvio. 1909. La plétora monetaria de 1909 y la anemia monetaria de 1898. Buones Aires: n.p.Google Scholar
Gesell, Silvio. 1916. Die natürliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland und Freigeld. Les Hauts Geneveys, Leipzig: Selbstverlag.Google Scholar
Gesell, Silvio. 1958. The Natural Economic Order. Translated by P. Pye. Revised edition. London: Peter Owen Ltd. Original publication in 1916; revision of the first English translation based on the sixth German edition, 1929. http://www.silvio-gesell.de/html/the_natural_economic_order.html. Accessed 9 April 2017.Google Scholar
Gibson, Alfred Herbert. 1923. “The Future of High Class Investment Values.” Bankers,’ Insurance Managers’ and Agents’ Magazine (January): 1523.Google Scholar
Gibson, Alfred Herbert. 1926. “The Road to Economic Recovery: Some Reflections.” Bankers,’ Insurance Managers’ and Agents’ Magazine (November): 595612.Google Scholar
Godschalk, Hugo. 2012. “Does Demurrage Matter for Complementary Currencies?” International Journal of Community Currency Research 16 (Section D): 5869.Google Scholar
Goetz von, Peter. 2005. “Debt-Deflation: Concepts and a Stylized Model.” Bank for International Settlements Working Papers, No. 176, April.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodfriend, Marvin. 2000. “Overcoming the Zero Bound on Interest Rate Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 32, 4, part 2 (November): 10071035.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, Frank D. 1932. The Abolition of Unemployment. Princeton, NJ: Kennikat Press.Google Scholar
Greco, Thomas H. Jr. 2001. Money. Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender. White River Junction, VT: Chelsea Green Publishing.Google Scholar
Hagemann, Harald. 2013. “The Impact of Fisher’s Purchasing Power of Money in the German Language Area.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20 (2): 323348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagemann, Harald, and Rühl, Christof. 1990. “Nicholas Johannsen and Keynes’s Finance Motive.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics / Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 146, 3 (September): 445469.Google Scholar
Hawtrey, Ralph George. 1919. Currency and Credit. London: Longman, Green and Co.Google Scholar
Herland, Michel. 1987. “L’utopie monétaire de S. Gesell: un cas d’hétérodoxie entre Wicksell et Keynes.” Séminaire Silvio Gesell, Les Cahiers de Decta III 1: 99120.Google Scholar
Herland, Michel. 1992. “L’utopie monétaire de S. Gesell: un cas d’hétérodoxie entre Wicksell et Keynes.” In Arena, Richard and Torre, Dominique, eds., Keynes et les nouveaux keynésiens. Paris: PUF et CNRS, pp. 293306.Google Scholar
Hubert, Eva-Maria. 2004. Tauschringe und Marktwirtschaft: Eine ökonomische Analyse lokaler Komplementärökonomien. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphrey, Thomas M. 2004. “Classical Deflation Theory.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 90–91 (Winter): 1132.Google Scholar
Ilgmann, Cordelius. 2009. “Silvio Gesell: ‘A Strange, Unduly Neglected Prophet’? A Reappraisal of a Forgotten Pioneer of Monetary Theory.” CAWM Discussion Paper No 23. Centre for Applied Economic Research, Münster, Germany.Google Scholar
Ilgmann, Cordelius, and Menner, Martin. 2011. “Negative Nominal Interest Rates: History and Current Proposals.” CAWM Discussion Paper No. 43. Centre for Applied Economic Research, Münster, Germany.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jevons, William Stanley. 1875. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. Twenty-second edition. London: Kegan-Trench-Trübner.Google Scholar
Jobst, Andreas, and Lin, Huidan. 2016. “Negative Interest Rate Policy (NIRP): Implications for Monetary Transmission and Bank Profitability in the Euro Area.” IMF Working Paper, WP/16/172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johannsen, Nicholas. 1908. A Neglected Point in Connection with Crises. New York: The Bankers Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Johannsen, Nicholas. 1913. Die Steuer der zukunft und ihre Einwirkung auf geschäftliche Depressionen und volkwirtschaftliche Verhältnisse. Berlin: Puttkammer & Mühlbrecht.Google Scholar
Joyce, Michael, Miles, David, Scott, Andrew, and Vayanos, Dimitri. “Quantitative Easing and Unconventional Monetary Policy—An Introduction.” The Economic Journal 122 (564): 271288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalecki, Michael. 1944. “Professor Pigou on the ‘Classical Stationary State’: A Comment.” The Economic Journal 54: 131132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1930] 1971. A Treatise on Money. In Keynes, John Maynard, Collected Writings. Volumes V and VI. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1937. “The General Theory of Employment.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 51, 2 (February): 209233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles. 1978. Manias, Panics, and Crashes. A History of Financial Crises. New York: Basic Books.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Lawrence R. 1947. The Keynesian Revolution. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Knapp, Georg Friedrich. 1905. Die Staatliche Theorie des Geldes. München-Leipzig: Duncker und Humblot. English translation, The State Theory of Money. London: Macmillan, 1924.Google Scholar
Lahn, J. J. O. [Pen-name of Johannsen, Nicolas August Ludwig Jacob.] 1903a. Depressions-Perioden und ihre einheitliche Ursache. Brooklyn, NY: n.p.Google Scholar
Lahn, J. J. O. [Pen-name of Johannsen, Nicolas August Ludwig Jacob.]. 1903b. Der Kreislauf des Geldes und Mechanismus des Sozial-Lebens. Berlin: Puttkammer & Mühlbrecht.Google Scholar
Laidler, David E. D. 1991. The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory. New York and London: Philip Allan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lanteri, Alessandro. 2010. “The Economic Ethics of Ezra Pound.” Working Paper No. 25/2010 International Centre for Economic Research Working Paper Series. Torino, Italy.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lanteri, Alessandro. 2011. “Douglas, Gesell, and the Economic Ethics of Ezra Pound.” History of Economic Ideas XIX: 147168.Google Scholar
Lederer, Emil. 1931. Wege aus der Krise. Ein Vortrag von E. Lederer. Tübingen: Mohr.Google Scholar
Lederer, Emil. 1932. Planwirtschaft. Tübingen: Mohr.Google Scholar
Lietaer, Bernard A. 1999. The Future of Money: Creating New Wealth, Work and a Wiser World. Post Falls: Century Publishing.Google Scholar
Lietaer, Bernard A. 2001. Community Currencies: A New Tool for the 21st Century. http://www.transaction.net/money/cc/cc01.html. Accessed 11 April 2017.Google Scholar
Löhr, Dirk. 2010. “Zero Growth and Zero Interest Rate: The Revival of an Old Idea.” Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Economic Degrowth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Equity, Barcelona, 26–29 March 2010.Google Scholar
Löhr, Dirk. 2012. “The Euthanasia of the Rentiers. A Way Toward a Steady-State Economy.” Ecological Economics 84 (December): 232239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Löhr, Dirk. 2014. “The Hidden Rent-Seeking Capacity of Corporations.” International Journal of Social Economics 41 (9): 820836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Locke, John. 1696. Several Papers Relating to Money. London: A. and J. Churchill.Google Scholar
Lucarelli, Stefano, and Gobbi, Lucio. 2013. “Local Clearing Unions as Stabilizers of Local Economic Systems: A Stock Flow Consistent Perspective.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 40: 13971420.Google Scholar
Mankiw Gregory, N. 2009. “It May Be Time for the Fed to Go Negative.” New York Times, April 19, 2009.Google Scholar
Mankiw, , Gregory, N. 2015. “Contribution to the Session on Secular Stagnation.” Conference of the Allied Social Science Association, Boston, 3 January 2015.Google Scholar
McAndrews, James. 2015. “Negative Nominal Central Bank Policy Rates—Where Is the Lower Bound?” Speech delivered at the University of Wisconsin, Madison, 8 May 2015. http://www.bis.org/review/r150512a.htm. Accessed 4 May 2017.Google Scholar
McGrattan, Ellen R., and Prescott, Edward C.. 2004. “The 1929 Stock Market: Irving Fisher Was Right.” International Economic Review 45, 4 (November): 9911009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, Carl. [1871] 2007. Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre. Wien: Braunmüller. English translation, Principles of Economics. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2007.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. [1871] 1883. Untersuchungen über die Methode der Sozialwissenschaften, und der der politischen Ökonomie insbesondere. Leipzig: Dunker und Humblot.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1871. Principles of Political Economy, with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy. Seventh edition. London: Parker.Google Scholar
Minozzi, Pietro, and Parisi, Umberto. 2012. “The Integration of the Stamped Money Issue into the General Equilibrium Models.” http://sdocument.ish-lyon.cnrs.fr/cc-conf/conferences.ish-lyon.cnrs.fr/index.php/cc-conf/2011/paper/viewFile/51/24.pdf. Accessed 4 May 2017.Google Scholar
Minsky, Hyman. 1982. “Debt-Deflation Processes in Today’s Institutional Environment.” Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review 143: 375393.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. [1924] 1980. Theorie des Geldes und der Umlaufmittel. München und Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. English translation, The Theory of Money and Credit. Indianapolis: Liberty, 1980.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Ralph A. and Shafer, Neil. 1984. Standard Catalog of Depression Scrip in the United States. Quarto: Krause Publications, Inc.Google Scholar
Mitchener, Kris James, and Weidenmier, Marc D.. 2006. “The Baring Crisis and the Great Latin American Meltdown of the 1890s.” NBER Working Papers 13403. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/papers/w13403. Accessed 11 April 2017.Google Scholar
Onken, Werner. 1982. “Ein vergessenes Kapitel der Wirtschaftsgeschichte. Schwanenkirchen,Wörgl und andere Freigeldexperimente.” Zeitschrift für Sozialökonomie 58–59: 320.Google Scholar
Onken, Werner. 2000. “A Market Economy without Capitalism.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 59, 4 (October): 609622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palley, Thomas I. 2016. “Why Negative Interest Rate Policy (NIRP) Is Ineffective and Dangerous.” Real-World Economics Review 76: 515.Google Scholar
Parker, Andrew. 1982. “Ezra Pound and the ‘Economy’ of Anti-Semitism.” In “Engagements: Postmodernism, Marxism, Politics,” Boundary 2, 11 (1–2): 103128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patalano, Rosario, and Pavanelli, Giovanni. 2013. “A Neglected Quantitativist: Silvio Gesell’s Theory of Money and Interest.” Paper presented at XII Aispe Conference, Florence, 21–23 February 2013.Google Scholar
Patinkin, Don. 1948. “Price Flexibility and Full Employment.” The American Economic Review 38 (4 September): 543564.Google Scholar
Patinkin, Don. 1993. “Irving Fisher and His Compensated Dollar Plan.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 79, 3 (Summer): 134.Google Scholar
Pavanelli, Giovanni. [2001] 2004. “The Great Depression in Irving Fisher’s Thought.” Quaderni del Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche e Finanziarie. Università degli Studi di Torino, Torino. Reprinted in Garens, Ingo, Caspari, Volker, and Schefold, Bertram, eds., Political Events and Economic Ideas. Cheltenham: Eward Elgar Publishing, pp. 289305.Google Scholar
Pavanelli, Giovanni. 2002. “Gesell, Fisher, Keynes and the Stamped Money Plan during the Thirties.” Paper presented at Eshet Conference, Rethymno, Greece, 14–17 March 2002.Google Scholar
Pigou, Arthur Cecil. 1943. “The Classical Stationary State.” The Economic Journal 53 (212): 343351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preparata, Guido Giacomo. 2002. “On the Art of Innuendo: J. M. Keynes’ Plagiarism of Silvio Gesell’s Monetary Economics.” In Zarembka, Paul, ed., “Confronting 9–11, Ideologies of Race, and Eminent Economists” Special issue, Research in Political Economy 20: 217253.Google Scholar
Proudhon, Pierre-Joseph. 1840. Qu’est-ce que la propriété ? ou Recherches sur le principe du droit et du gouvernement. Paris: Brocard.Google Scholar
Reeve, Joseph E. 1943. Monetary Reform Movements—A Survey of Recent Plans and Panaceas. Introduction by Thorp, Willard L.. Washington: American Council on Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Rist, Charles. 1955. “La pensée économique de Proudhon.” Revue d’histoire économique et sociale 33 (2): 129165.Google Scholar
Rothbard, William Newton. 1972. America’s Great Depression. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Rühl, Christof. 2000. “Nicholas August Ludwig Jacob Johannsen.” In Arestis, Philip and Sawyer, Malcolm, eds., A Biographical Dictionary of Dissenting Economists. Second edition. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 327335.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas J. 1973. “Interest Rates and Prices in the Long Run: A Study of the Gibson Paradox.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 5 (1): 385449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmid, Werner. 1954. Silvio Gesell: Die Lebensgeschichte eines Pioniers. Bern: Verl, Freiwirtschaftl, Schriften.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph Alois. [1954] 2006. History of Economic Analysis. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seccareccia, Mario. 1987. “La notion gésellienne de préférence pour la liquidité et sa généralisation dans les travaux de Keynes, Soddy et Johannsen.” Séminaire Silvio Gesell, Les Cahiers de Decta III 1: 7896.Google Scholar
Seccareccia, Mario. 1988. “Systeme monetaire et loi d’entropie: la notion gesellienne de preference pour la liquidite.” Economies et societies 22: 5771.Google Scholar
Seccareccia, Mario. 1997. “Early Twentieth-Century Heterodox Monetary Thought, on Money.” In Cohen, Avi J., Hagemann, Harald, and Smithin, John, eds., Financial Institutions and Macroeconomics. New York: Springer Science Business Media, pp. 125139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shackle, George L. S. 1971. Discussion Paper in Monetary Theory and Monetary Policy in the 1970s. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Soddy, Frederick. 1931. Money versus Man, A Statement of the World Problem from the Standpoint of the New Economics. London: Elkin Mathews & Marrot.Google Scholar
Sonnenfels, Joseph F. von. 1769. Handlungswissenschaft. Wien: V. Trattnern.Google Scholar
Suhr, Dieter. 1989. The Capitalistic Cost-Benefit Structure of Money—An Analysis of Money’s Structural Nonneutrality and its Effects on the Economy. Berlin and New York: Springer Verlag. http://www.sozialoekonomie.info/Info_Foreign_Languages/English_6/english_6.html. Accessed 11 April 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tobin, James. 1975. “Keynesian Models of Recession and Depression.” American Economic Review 65 (2): 195202.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1980. “Real Balance Effects Reconsidered.” In Tobin, James, Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 119.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1983. “Okun on Macroeconomic Policy: A Final Comment.” In Tobin, James, ed., Macroeconomics, Prices, and Quantities. Washington: Brookings Institution, pp. 297300.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1874. Éléments d’Économie Politique Pure. Lausanne: L. Corbaz & cie.Google Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1898. Théorie de la monnaie . In Walras, Léon, Etudes d’Economie Politique appliquée. Paris: chez Pichon, pp. 65192.Google Scholar
Warner, Jonathan. 2005. “Charles Zylstra and Stamped Scrip. How a Dutch Immigrant Sought a Solution to the Great Depression.” Paper given at conference, Dutch Immigrants on the Plains, Dordt College, Sioux Center Iowa, 2005. http://www.aadas.nl/conferences/proceedings/charles-zylstra-and-stamped-scrip-how-dutch-immigrant-sought-solution-great-. Accessed 11 April 2017.Google Scholar
Warner, Jonathan. 2008. “The Anaheim Scrip Plan.” Southern California Quarterly 90 (3): 307325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warner, Jonathan. 2010. “Stamp Scrip in the Great Depression—Lessons for Community Currency for Today?” International Journal of Community Currency Research. https://ijccr.files.wordpress.com/2012/05/ijccrvol142010a29-45warner.pdf. Accessed 4 May 2017.Google Scholar
Warner, Jonathan. 2012. “Iowa Stamp Scrip: Economic Experimentation in Iowa Communities during the Great Depression.” The Annals of Iowa 71, 1 (Winter): 138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Johan Gustaf Knut. [1898] 1977. Geldzins und Güterpreise. Jena: Verlag von Gustav Fischer.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Johan Gustaf Knut. 1907. “The Influence of the Rate of Interest on Prices.” The Economic Journal 17: 213220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Johan Gustaf Knut. [1934] 1950. Lectures on Political Economy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Widdig, Bernd. 2001. Culture and Inflation in Weimar Germany. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Wise, Leonard. 1945. Silvio Gesell: An Introduction to Gesellian Economics. Holborn: Publishing & Distg. Company.Google Scholar
Wray, Randall L. 2006. “Keynes’s Approach To Money: An Assessment After 70 Years.” Working Paper No. 438, The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Annandale-on-Hudson, New York.Google Scholar