Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vfjqv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T00:14:59.524Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Knut Wicksell and Gustav Cassel on the Cumulative Process and the Price-Stabilizing Policy Rule

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

In economics as in anthropology, old artifacts spur continuing debates. A case in point is Knut Wicksell's 1898 analysis of the cumulative process of price inflation in pure credit, cashless economies. Some economists view Wicksell's model as a milestone in the evolution of quantity-theoretic monetary analysis inasmuch as it constitutes the seminal rigorous explanation of how loan-created stocks of bank money translate interest rate differentials into price level changes. Others, however, dispute this point and instead argue that money plays no role in determining price level changes in Wicksell's model.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2003

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Blaug, Mark. 1986. Great Economists before Keynes: An Introduction to the Lives & Works of One Hundred Great Economists of the Past. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Carlson, Benny. 1994. The State as a Monster: Gustav Cassel and Eli Heckscher on the Role and Growth of the State. Lanham, MD: University Press of America.Google Scholar
Cassel, Gustav. 1918. The Theory of Social Economy, 2nd edition. Revised. New York: Harcourt, Brace & Co., 1932.Google Scholar
Cassel, Gustav. Letter of May 10, 1926 to Bertil Ohlin.Google Scholar
Cassel, Gustav. 1928. “The Rate of Interest, the Bank Rate, and the Stabilization of Prices.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 42 (08): 511–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cottrell, Allin. 1989. “Price Expectations and Equilibrium When the Interest Rate is Pegged.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 36 (05): 125–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellis, Howard S. 1937. German Monetary Theory 1905–1933. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving, 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit, Interest and Crises, 2nd revised edition. New York: Macmillan, 1922. Reprinted NewYork: Agustus M. Kelley, 1963.Google Scholar
Gardlund, Torsten. 1958. The Life of Knut Wicksell. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell.Google Scholar
Giöbel-Lilja, Ingrid. 1948. Gustav Cassel: En livsskildring (Gustav Cassel: A Biography). Stockholm: Natur och Kultur.Google Scholar
Gustafsson, Bo. 1987. “Cassel, Gustav.” In Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, and Newman, Peter, eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Vol. 1. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Haavelmo, Trygve. 1978. “Wicksell on the Currency Theory vs. The Banking Principle.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 80 (2): 209–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hawtrey, R.G. 1919. Currency and Credit, 3rd edition. London: Longmans Group, 1927.Google Scholar
Hegeland, Hugo. 1951. The Quantity Theory of Money. Goteborg: Elanders Boktryckeri Aktiebolag.Google Scholar
Jonung, Lars. 1979. “Knut Wicksell and Gustav Cassel on Secular Movements in Prices.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 11 (05): 165–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, David. 1991. The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory: The Development of Neoclassical Monetary Economics, 1870–1914. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, David. 1992. “Monetarism—The Unfinished Business.” Cyprus Journal of Economics 5 (12): 6074. Reprinted in David Laidler, Money and Macroeconomics: The Selected Essays of David Laidler. Cheltenham, UK and Lyme, U.S.: Edward Elgar, 1997, pp. 354–68.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution: Studies of the Inter-war Literature on Money, the Cycle, and Unemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 2000. “Highlights of the Bullionist Controversy.” Research Report No. 13. Stockholm: Institutet For Ekonomisk Historisk Forskning.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, Axel. 1981. “The Wicksell Connection—Variations on a Theme.” In Information and Coordination: Essays in Macroeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lutz, Freidrich A. and Mints, Lloyd W., eds. 1951. Readings in Monetary Theory. Homewood IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc.Google Scholar
Marget, Arthur. 1938. The Theory of Prices: A Re-examination of the Central Problems of Monetary Theory, vol. 1. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig von. 1912. The Theory on Money and Credit, 2nd edition 1924. Translated by Batson, H.E., London: Jonathan Cape, 1934. Reprinted New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1953.Google Scholar
Myhrman, Johan. 1991. “The Monetary Economics of the Stockholm School.” In Jonung, Lars, ed., The Stockholm School of Economics Revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Myrdal, Gustav. 1945. “Gustav Cassel in Memoriam.” Ekonomisk Revy.Google Scholar
Niehans, Jürg. 1990. A History of Economic Theory: Classic Contributions, 1720–1980. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Ohlin, Bertil. 1936. “Introduction” to the English translation of Wicksell's Interest and Prices. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ohlin, Bertil. 1972. Ung man blir politiker (Young Man Becomes Politician). Stockholm: Bonniers.Google Scholar
Patinkin, Don. 1965. Money, Interest, and Prices, 2nd edition. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Seligman, Ben. 1962. Main Currents of Modern Economics: Economic Thought Since 1870. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Thornton, Henry. 1802. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain. Reprinted with and introduction by F. A. von Hayek. London: Allen & Unwin, 1939.Google Scholar
Trautwein, Hans-Michael. 1996. “Money, Equilibrium, and the Business Cycle: Hayek's Wicksellian Dichotomy.” History of Political Economy 28 (Spring): 2755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhr, Carl G. 1991. “Knut Wicksell, Neoclassicist and Iconoclast.” In Sandelin, Bo, ed., The History of Swedish Economic Thought. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1898a. “The Influence of the Rate of Interest on Commodity Prices.” Proceedings of the Swedish Association of Economics: 47–70. Reprinted in Erik Lindahl, ed., Knut Wicksell: Selected Papers on Economic Theory. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, pp. 67–89.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1898b. Interest and Prices. Translated by Kahn, R. F.. London: Macmillan. Reprinted New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1906. “Money.” In Lectures on Political Economy, vol. 2. Translated by Classen, E., edited by Robbins, Lionel. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Reprinted New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1978.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1925. “The Monetary Problem of the Scandinavian Countries.” Ekonomisk Tidskrift 27: 205– 22. Reprinted in Interest and Prices. London: Macmillan, 1936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1959. The Wicksellian Tradition in Swedish Macroeconomic Theory. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Michigan.Google Scholar